More Guns, Less Crime: Understanding Crime and Gun Control Laws.
Shughart, William F., II
By John R. Lott, Jr. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998.
Pp. x, 225. $23.00.
People who call themselves economists without committing a fraud on
the profession regard the first law of demand as the first principle of
economizing behavior. Confronted with an obvious empirical application
of it, neoclassical economists, at least those whom have managed to
avoid falling into the everything-is-possible game theory trap,
instinctively want to gather data and estimate the magnitude of the
theory's prediction. Is the inverse relationship between the price
of something and the amount of it individuals choose to consume
statistically significant when other relevant factors are held constant?
And, if so, how large is the ceteris paribus own-price effect? Although
the size and significance of the empirical results might be the subject
of considerable econometric debate, no economist worthy of the label
would obstinately question the direction of the relationship. When the
price of something goes up, less of it will be consumed. The only issue
worthy of scholarly controversy is, how much less?
Early last year, John Lott and David Mustard (1997) published a
lengthy study, concluding from extensive empirical evidence that
criminals respond in ways predicted by models of rational behavior to
changes in the cost of committing crimes. Specifically, they examined
the impact of so-called non-discretionary (or "shall-issue")
gun laws allowing private citizens to carry weapons concealed about
their persons. Prior to the enactment of these laws, by now on the books
in 31 states altogether (most of which have adopted them since 1985),
local law enforcement officials exercised considerable discretion in
decisions to issue concealed handgun permits. Shall-issue laws
essentially eliminate that discretion, requiring concealed-weapons
permits to be granted to all applicants who pay the required fee and
meet other minimal qualifications, including age restrictions, absence
of a criminal record, and no history of mental illness.
Lott and Mustard, reasoning that making it easier for private
citizens to arm themselves would increase criminals' expected costs
of confronting their prey (who might or might not be carrying concealed
weapons), hypothesized that shall-issue laws would produce reductions in
crime rates, especially violent crimes, such as murder, rape, and
robbery, where retaliation by a possibly armed victim poses the greatest
threat to the perpetrator. Because the hypothesized reductions in
violent crime rates in shall-issue states might be offset to some extent
by substitution effects leading to increases in nonviolent crimes (e.g.,
against property) in those same jurisdictions as well as to increases in
violent crimes in jurisdictions having more restrictive gun laws as
criminals rationally shifted their predatory activities across borders,
the overall impact of the change in gun law regimes is an empirical
question. Employing a county-level data set consisting of some 54,000
observations (3,000-plus counties over an 18-year time span), Lott and
Mustard reported a variety of statistical results supporting the
conclusion that criminals respond to shall-issue laws in the ways
predicted by the first law of demand.
However, even before the paper was published thanks to the authors
posting the manuscript on the Internet and making their data available
to anyone who requested it, Lott became the target of a vicious
publicity campaign attacking his scholarship and assassinating his
character. Enemies of a plain reading of the constitutional guarantee of
the right to bear arms accused him of being an intellectually dishonest
shill whose research was bought and paid for by progun pressure groups.
The basis for this scurrilous charge? Lott is the John M. Olin Visiting
Law and Economics Fellow at the University of Chicago, a position funded
by the John M. Olin Foundation. Although it is true that the Olin
Corporation, which is the source of the Olin family fortune, is a
manufacturer of ammunition (but not of guns, as the critics initially
claimed), the Olin Foundation is, in the words of its president William
E. Simon, "as independent of the Olin Corp. as the Ford Foundation
is of the Ford Motor Co." (letter to the editor, Wall Street
Journal, September 4, 1996).
The personal (and, to those who know him, completely unfounded)
attacks on Lott's integrity were made with such ferocity and in so
many media outlets nationwide that one can conclude only that Lott was,
with apologies to our gracious First Lady, the target of a vast
left-wing conspiracy to discredit his politically incorrect findings. In
More Guns, Less Crime, Lott responds to the critics with the same
careful attention to detail and with the same willingness to debate the
issues on their scientific merits that has characterized his demeanor
throughout this tempestuous affair. Confident in his own work and
genuinely intellectually curious about the causes of crime and the
consequences of gun ownership, Lott has eagerly entered the lion's
den to debate the evidence. He has appeared on panels at meetings of the
Public Choice Society and the American Economic Association (Bronars and
Lott 1998), gone on C-SPAN and National Public Radio, and continued to
answer his detractors in print (Lott 1998).
With such a large data set to be mined and with so many factors to
be controlled for in estimating the marginal impact of concealed-handgun
laws on crime rates, Lott and Mustard's paper triggered a healthy
econometric argument that is far from settled. Issues relating to the
sensitivity of the results to the inclusion of certain observations
(Black and Nagin 1998) and to the specification of the regression model
(Dezhbakhsh and Rubin 1998) have led some researchers to conclude that
shall-issue laws play a less significant role in deterring violent crime
than Lott claims. Other researchers have found that although the direct
effects of the laws the hypothesized reductions in murder, rape, and
robbery rates - appear to be empirically robust, the indirect effects on
nonviolent crimes might not be (Bartley and Cohen 1998).
Many of these technical issues are explored in More Guns, Less
Crime. However, the book also addresses a wide range of topics related
to its main theme, including the demographics of crime and gun
ownership, the roles played by arrest rates and conviction rates in
deterring criminal activity, the impact of handgun availability on
suicide rates and accidental deaths, and the effects of prepurchase
waiting periods and background checks on crime rates.
Chapter 1 introduces the analysis. There, Lott recounts some vivid
stories illustrating how law-abiding private citizens have successfully
fended off criminal attacks by brandishing concealed weapons and reports
some statistical evidence placing handgun violence in perspective. Two
of the widely accepted "facts" about the relationship between
guns and crime are quickly laid to rest. One is that gun accidents make
many children the innocent victims of America's gun culture.
According to Lott, 1,400 accidental deaths involved guns in 1995.
However, only 200 of these accidents involved children less than 14
years of age. Although tragic, this number is far less than the 2,900
children killed in motor vehicle accidents the same year. As a matter of
fact, "more children die in bicycle accidents each year than die
from all types of firearm accidents" (p. 9). The other truism is
that most murderers "know" their victims, implying that easy
access to guns often turns simple domestic arguments into deadly
encounters. However, as Lott points out, the FBI's definition of
"acquaintance" includes fellow gang members as well as the
customers of drug pushers, hookers, and cab drivers. I have wanted to
shoot a few cabbies myself, but I would not say that I knew any of them.
Some of the book's provocative findings in this regard are
that women and blacks seem to gain the most from concealed-weapons laws;
that the largest reductions in violent crimes follow the adoption of
shall-issue laws in high-crime urban areas, where gun laws tend to be
the most restrictive and where opponents fight hardest to keep
nondiscretionary concealed-weapons laws off the books; that criminals
are dissuaded more by the probability of being arrested than by the
probability of being convicted; and that waiting periods and background
checks have little, if any, crime-deterring benefits.
In colonial America, all able-bodied men were required to own
firearms and risked fines if they failed to muster in response to the
tocsin calling the militia to assemble. In late-twentieth-century
America, rooted in a hitherto unexamined belief that more guns lead to
more crime, political elites lobby tirelessly to disarm law-abiding
private citizens. Lott has now tested the conventional wisdom of the
instrumental immorality of guns and found it wanting. Given that even
the most lavishly funded police force cannot protect every law-abiding
citizen against the depredations of those who operate outside the law,
increasing the cost to criminals of confronting their victims by
allowing the carrying of concealed weapons appears, on Lott's
evidence, to be an effective crime-fighting strategy. To the extent that
self-defense is a substitute for police defense, of course, we might
expect local and federal law enforcement officials to oppose shall-issue
laws. Although that substitution effect might help explain some of the
hostility to more permissive gun law regimes, it is beyond the scope of
More Guns, Less Crime, as is the issue of private gun ownership as a
counterweight to government abuses.
More Guns, Less Crime is controversial and thought provoking. One
need not agree with all its empirical findings or accept all its
conclusions to appreciate the extent to which Lott has raised the level
of the debate. Opponents of private gun ownership, who have gotten away
with small samples and with the simple analytical demands of the medical
journals in which many of their studies have appeared, must meet higher
standards of scholarship from now on. More Guns, Less Crime is not the
last word on the subject, nor does Lott make it out to be. Anyone who is
interested in the important public policy issues it addresses - and who
is willing to keep an open mind - will profit from reading it.
References
Bartley, William Alan, and Mark A. Cohen. 1998. The effect of
concealed weapons laws: An extreme bound analysis. Economic Inquiry
36(April):258-65.
Black, Dan A., and Daniel S. Nagin. 1998. Do right-to-carry laws
deter violent crime? Journal of Legal Studies 27(January):209-19.
Bronars. Stephen G., and John R. Lott, Jr. 1998. Criminal
deterrence, geographic spillovers, and the right to carry concealed
handguns. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 88(May):475-9.
Dezhbakhsh, Hashem, and Paul H. Rubin. 1998. Lives saved or lives
lost? The effects of concealed-handgun laws on crime. American Economic
Review Papers and Proceedings 88(May):468-74.
Lott, John R., Jr. 1998. The concealed-handgun debate. Journal of
Legal Studies 27(January):221-43.
Lott, John R., Jr., and David B. Mustard. 1997. Crime, deterrence,
and right-to-carry concealed handguns. Journal of Legal Studies
26(January):1-68.
William E Shughart II University of Mississippi