Do Business Cycles Affect State Appropriations to Higher Education?
Humphreys, Brad R.
Brad R. Humphreys [*]
Spending on higher education constitutes an important and
increasing portion of state government spending and a major source of
operating funds at public institutions of higher education. Anecdotal
evidence suggests that state appropriations are subject to cyclical variation. An analysis of state appropriations to higher education,
enrollment in two- and four-year public colleges and universities, and
state-specific measures of the business cycle for all 50 states over the
period 1969-1994 shows that state appropriations to higher education are
highly sensitive to changes in the business cycle. A 1% change in real
per capita income was, on average, associated with a 1.39% change in
real state appropriations per full-time equivalent student enrolled.
This implied decline in state government funding, coupled with the
increase in enrollment in higher education during recessions reported by
Betts and McFarland (1995), suggest that public institutions of higher
education may experience fiscal stress during econom ic downturns. These
results also suggest that state legislators and education policymakers
should reconsider their higher education funding policies during
recessions in order to allow public colleges and universities to provide
dislocated workers with access to quality education and training during
these periods.
1. Introduction and Motivation
Business cycles affect higher education in a number of important
ways. Anecdotal evidence from college admissions officers and
administrators, as well as empirical evidence on the behavior of
students and institutions of higher education, suggest that enrollment
in higher education is countercylical. For example, Betts and McFarland
(1995) recently showed that enrollments in community colleges are highly
responsive to changes in local labor market conditions. These authors
found a 1% increase in the unemployment rate among all adults associated
with a 4% increase in enrollment at community colleges in a large panel
of community colleges across the United States. Leslie and Ramey (1986)
found a similar relationship between economic conditions and enrollment
using data aggregated to the regional level.
This paper examines the relationship between state appropriations
to higher education and state-specific measures of business cycle
conditions in order to better understand the effects of the business
cycle on government funding of higher education. [1] I further
investigate the relationship between the business cycle and state
government appropriations to higher education reported by Betts and
McFarland (1995) and Leslie and Ramey (1986). Both of these studies
aggregated state and local government appropriations to higher education
to the regional and national level. While data aggregated to the
regional and national levels are readily available, decisions about
government funding to higher education are made at the state and local
levels, and these decisions may be affected more by local economic
conditions than by aggregate economic conditions. If the timing of
turning points in the business cycle varies across states, then
aggregating government appropriations data across states may obscure
important sta te-specific phenomena.
Most research has focused on the effects of economic conditions on
demand for higher education. One notable exception is Leslie and Ramey
(1986), who examined the relationship between enrollment, business
cycles, and state appropriations to higher education using regional
appropriations and enrollment data and a national measure of business
cycle conditions. That study found a procyclical relationship between
the NBER coincident index and regional-level government appropriations
to higher education. For one region, the estimated elasticity of
appropriations with respect to changes in the coincident index was
three, suggesting that a 1% change in the NBER coincident index was
associated with a 3% change in appropriations to higher education in
that region. This study also highlighted the complex relationship
between state funding for higher education, enrollment, and business
cycle conditions by documenting a statistically significant relationship
between enrollment and state appropriations at the regional le vel,
although they found that the appropriations--enrollment relationship
weakened after 1977.
Betts and McFarland (1995) also describe, in an informal way using
aggregate data, a procyclical relationship between the business cycle
and funding for higher education. These authors report that aggregate
state and local government appropriations to higher education fell in
the years 1971, 1975, 1980-1982 as well as in several years in the early
1990s; all of these years are either coincident with, or immediately
following, years when the NBER Dating Committee has identified a
cyclical downturn in the economy. The transmission mechanism linking
business cycles and government appropriations to higher education during
recessionary periods seems clear: recessions reduce tax revenues; state
and local governments, most of which operate under legally required
balanced budget restrictions, reduce appropriations to institutions of
higher education, as well as other types of expenditures, in order to
balance their budgets.
Betts and McFarland point out that these cyclical patterns of
government support for higher education may place tremendous financial
pressure on institutions of higher education during economic downturns,
because the cuts in government funding happen at the same time
enrollments are increasing. These financial crises affect community
colleges because the open admissions policies of these institutions make
them attractive to unemployed workers displaced by the recession. Public
four-year institutions of higher education may also be adversely
affected because these institutions typically rely on government
appropriations to offset a large fraction of their operating and general
expenditures.
An alternative explanation for rising enrollments and declining
government appropriations discussed by Betts and McFarland is increasing
returns to scale. If institutions of higher education operate at levels
of enrollment where there are economies of scale, then these
institutions could lower average operating costs by increasing
enrollments that could in turn lead to lower government appropriations.
In the case of community colleges, Betts and McFarland report that
interviews with community college presidents revealed that these
institutions operate at or above capacity nearly all of the time and
that increases in enrollments were typically associated with increases
in average operating costs. In the case of four-year colleges, the
existing empirical evidence suggests that most institutions of higher
education operate at enrollment levels where there are constant returns
to scale, indicating that increases in enrollment would not lead to
decreases in average operating costs, although there is a great deal of
disagreement in this extensive literature. However, recent research in
Getz, Sigfried, and Zhang (1991) and Koshal and Koshal (1999) find no
evidence of increasing returns to scale in institutions of higher
education. This evidence makes it unlikely that increasing returns to
scale can explain the behavior of government appropriations to higher
education during periods of rising enrollments.
The results presented in this paper suggest that state
appropriations to higher education are quite sensitive to business
cycles. The estimated elasticity of state appropriations per Mi-time
equivalent (FTE) student is 1.39, suggesting that a 1% change in real
personal income per capita is associated with a 1.39% change in real
appropriations per FTE. Further, after accounting for the
countercyclical behavior of enrollments, it appears that real
appropriations fall more during recessionary years than they rise during
expansionary years.
2. Empirical Methodology and Data
The financing of higher education takes place in a complex, dynamic
setting. Institutions of higher education raise revenues from tuition
and fees, grants from all levels of government, research support from
public and private grantors, and other sources. Revenues generated from
tuition and fees depend on enrollment, which in turn depends on complex
decisions made by households. Government appropriations to higher
education are determined by legislators and bureaucrats who have complex
objectives and agendas.
Considerable variation exists in the process by which states
determine the funding of public higher education. The National
Association of State Budget Officers (1996) surveyed states in order to
document this process. Based on the results of this survey, the
processes by which states decide on appropriations to higher education
appear to be idiosyncratic. Few patterns emerge. Eleven states reported
operating on a biennial budget cycle, and initial budget requests
originated from a variety of sources. Institutions made the initial
budget request in 12 states; higher education regulatory bodies like
boards of regents or boards of higher education made the initial budget
request in 15 states; state budget offices made the initial budget
request in five states; the governor made the initial budget request in
six states. The remaining states were not included in the survey. In
each case, the budgeting process involved oversight by many other areas
of state government. Several states reported that the governor ex
ercised line-item veto power over appropriations to higher education.
"Formula-based funding" represents one commonly reported
feature of the budgeting process. [2] Initiated in Texas shortly after
the second World War, funding formulas were used in 16 states in 1964.
By 1992, 33 states reported using some sort of funding formula as part
of the budget process. However, this increase in the use of formulas has
not been a process of steady conversion. Eight states that used formulas
in the 1980s had discontinued their use by 1996. Some other states, like
Louisiana and Pennsylvania, appear to have used them intermittently over
the past 20 years.
Despite the name, funding formulas rarely, if ever, completely
determine total appropriations to higher education in a state. No state
uses a single formula, or a formula with a single variable like
enrollment. McKeown (1996) identified eight different functional areas
in higher education funding formulas used by states: instruction,
research, service, academic support, student services, instructional
support, scholarships and fellowships, and plant operation. The base
units in these formulas vary considerably and credit hours appear more
commonly than enrollments. Many of these functional areas use formulas
based on factors like the level, type, or mission of the campus, the
number of faculty, and the square footage or acreage of the campus.
Most importantly, funding formulas appear to serve as a starting
point for the process by which appropriations to higher education are
determined. The results of funding formulas are subject to adjustment by
many other areas of state government, including governors, legislative
committees, and higher education regulatory boards. The primary goal of
these formulas seems to be the allocation of state appropriations among
the institutions of higher education and not a method of determining the
total size of appropriations to higher education from year to year.
The frequent changes in the use, composition, and weights of
formulas suggests that state government officials have discretionary
power over total appropriations to higher education. Some evidence
suggests that cuts in appropriations to public higher education made
during recessions are mainly discretionary. Lewis and Farris (1995)
report that in fiscal years 1991-1993 between 42% and 55% of all public
institutions of higher education experienced cuts in their operating
budgets after these budgets had been approved. The overwhelming reason
given for these cuts was the effect of recession on government
appropriations. The idiosyncratic and everchanging nature of the process
by which state governments determine appropriations to higher education
suggests that these factors would be difficult, if not impossible, to
formally incorporate into an empirical model.
The decisions made by households, higher education administrators,
and government decision makers are interrelated and affected to one
degree or another by the business cycle. Given the complex, interrelated
nature of the behavior of these agents, I adopt a relatively simple
reduced form econometric model to analyze the relationship between
government appropriations to higher education and the business cycle.
This reduced form empirical model is
[A.sub.i,t] = [[gamma].sub.i] + [beta][X.sub.i,t] +
[[epsilon].sub.i,t] (1)
where [A.sub.i,t] is a measure of government appropriations to
higher education in state i during year t, [[gamma].sub.i] is a vector
of state-specific factors that affect government appropriations to
higher education and do not change over time, [X.sub.i,t] is a vector of
variables that can explain variation in appropriations to higher
education, including variables that reflect the state of the business
cycle, in state i during year t, and [[epsilon].sub.i,t] is an
unobservable equation error associated with state i during year t.
[X.sub.i,t] in general can include variables that do not vary across
states but vary over time as well as lagged values of variables that
reflect the current state of the business cycle. [beta] is a vector of
parameters to be estimated.
The changing nature of the funding process used by states and the
discretionary power exercised by state legislators and bureaucrats
suggests that a reduced form empirical model is appropriate for this
analysis. The parameters estimated from a reduced form model reflect the
net effect on appropriations of all decisions made by legislators,
bureaucrats, and regulatory bodies over the five business cycles in the
sample. Some structural detail will be lost by adopting a reduced form
empirical model, but a clear picture of the net effect of the many and
various decisions made about the funding of higher education in the
states will emerge.
[[gamma].sub.i] captures state-specific factors that affect
government appropriations to higher education and do not change over
time. Several studies have examined the relationship between government
appropriations and the economy using cross-sectional data. Clotfelter
(1976) examined the effect of out-migration of recent college graduates,
the ability of governments to raise tax revenues, and general economic
conditions like wages and per-capita income on both expenditure by
public institutions of higher education and government aid to higher
education. Clotfelter found increased enrollment in higher education and
higher per-capita income associated with larger appropriations per
capita to higher education, although the variation in income in this
study may not be due to business cycle effects as the data are cross
sectional. Quigley and Rubinfeld (1993) undertook a study of the effects
of political and economic factors on appropriations, expenditure and
enrollment in public higher education using data fro m 1985. This study
identified a variety of state-specific institutional, political, and
social factors that affect the level of public support for higher
education and the mix of public and private provision of higher
education in states, including geographic location, institutional
factors captured by the order of statehood, the availability of private
higher education in each state, and the quality of public higher
education in each state. These studies suggest that state-specific
factors have an important effect on funding and provision of public
higher education at the state level and suggest that controlling for
these differences across states is important in this empirical analysis.
Leslie and Ramey (1986) used contemporaneous observations of an
aggregate measure of business cycle conditions, the coincident index of
economic indicators, to explain observed variation in government
appropriations to higher education in eight regions of the United
States. The coincident index accurately reflects current business cycle
conditions for the entire economy, but it may not reflect the current
business cycle conditions in each state at a particular time, and it may
not accurately reflect the impact of business cycle conditions on tax
revenues in each state. This index is constructed from a number of
macroeconomic series and reflects changes in personal income,
production, employment, and sales in the national economy; business
cycle conditions in individual regions of the country are reflected in
this index only to the extent that there is homogeneity among regions of
the United States in terms of business cycle fluctuations and that these
regional effects are contemporaneously correlated.
Hoenack (1983) and Hoenack and Pierro (1990) developed structural
models of the legislative demand, household demand, and institutional
supply of higher education and tested these models using detailed
time-series data from Minnesota. In these papers, state appropriations
per voter are affected by the level of state and federal financial aid
per high school graduate in Minnesota, the marginal cost of enrollments
in higher education, average tax revenues, and enrollment in higher
education per voter. The reduced form equations estimated in this paper
are closely related to these structural models to the extent that
changes in the business cycle affect tax revenues and enrollments. The
estimates reported by Hoenack and Pierro (1990) indicate that
appropriations and tax revenues rise and fall together, and to the
extent that changes in tax revenues and enrollments are due to business
cycle effects, the results in this paper support their conclusions about
the determinants of state appropriations to higher educa tion. [3]
This study uses total state personal income as a measure of
state-specific business cycle conditions. Total state personal income
offers several potential advantages over more aggregated measures of
business cycle activity. First total state personal income, or any
state-specific indicator of business cycle conditions, will reflect
state-specific changes in the business cycle better than aggregate
indicators of business cycle conditions if turning points in the
aggregate economy differ from turning points in states. Nardinelli,
Wallace, and Warner (1988) identified 13 states where income
fluctuations differ from fluctuations in aggregate income over the
period 1956-1982, indicating that the turning point in the business
cycle may differ across states.
Second, total state personal income reflects state-specific changes
in household income. Sales taxes and to a lesser extent personal income
taxes represent an important source of state and local government tax
revenues. Over the period 1969-1994, the sample period in this paper,
sales taxes and personal income taxes accounted for 32% of total state
and local government tax revenues. [4] If spending cuts motivated by
budget balancing in response to decreases in tax revenues made by state
legislators and bureaucrats are the transmission mechanism through which
business cycles affect state spending on higher education, then
state-specific changes in personal income will be a good explanatory variable for this analysis. Aggregated measures of business cycle
activity like the NBER coincident index reflect changes in many
different measures of aggregate economic activity like total employment
and production that may not accurately reflect state-specific business
cycle conditions.
This discussion raises the point that state tax revenues may be a
better explanatory variable than total state personal income, because
tax revenues are the transmission mechanism by which business cycles
affect appropriations. However, state tax revenues would also be
affected by factors like tax relief measures and changes in income or
sales tax rates. Adjusting state tax revenues for these effects would
require an immense amount of data collection as no comprehensive
compilation of these policy changes exists. Also, income is a widely
used, but by no means definitive, indicator of business cycle conditions
and should be correlated with changes in tax revenue but not correlated
with tax relief measures or changes in the tax rate.
The timing of the measure of state-specific business cycle
conditions may also be an important determinant of the effect of
business cycles on state government spending on higher education.
Appropriations to higher education are set by legislatures as part of
the budgetary process. These decisions are made at regular intervals
during the fiscal year, according to legislative schedules. Thus the
timing of turning points in the business cycle relative to annual state
budgetary cycles might produce lags in this relationship. In particular,
state legislatures may not learn of unexpected changes in tax revenues
until well after cyclical turning points have occurred. State
legislatures may not respond to short-run economic fluctuations, either
because they are not in session when these events occur, or because
appropriations bills become effective only after they are passed.
Finally, using variables from year t to explain observed variation in
government appropriations to higher education in year t may lead to sim
ultaneity bias in the empirical estimates if unmeasured or omitted
factors are causing variation in both variables. For these reasons, I
use lagged income as a measure of state-specific business cycle
conditions.
Differences in population and preferences for the provision of
public higher education in states may also affect the relationship
between income and state appropriations to public higher education. One
way to control for this is to normalize the appropriations variable by a
measure of enrollment in public institutions of higher education and
personal income by a measure of population. This normalization has
intuitive appeal because both expenditure per student and income per
person are easier to compare than total appropriations and aggregate
state personal income. Thus, one part of the empirical analysis defines
[A.sub.i,t] as real state appropriations to higher education per FTE
enrolled in two- or four-year public institutions of higher education
and all income variables measured in per capita terms. [5]
This normalization has some drawbacks. Although the numerator of
this fraction reflects changes made by state government officials, the
denominator also changes in response to many factors, including business
cycles. The exact cyclical behavior of enrollments in public higher
education in this sample is difficult to determine, because of the lack
of state-specific reference cycles. However, an approximate measure of
the cyclicality of enrollments can be obtained. I regressed FTE
enrollments on a constant and a time trend for each state
[FTE.sub.i,t] = [[beta].sub.0,i] + [[beta].sub.1,i][t.sub.i] +
[[eta].sub.1,i,t]
and real income on a constant and time trend for each state
[INC.sub.i,t] = [[gamma].sub.0,i] + [[gamma].sub.1,i][t.sub.i] +
[[eta].sub.2,t]
where [t.sub.i] is a state-specific time trend. The contemporaneous
correlation between the residuals from these two regressions was -0.26,
indicating that when real income is above trend, FTE enrollments tend to
be below trend. This result suggests that enrollments are
countercyclical much like the findings of Betts and McFarland (1995).
In order to further investigate the effect of business cycles on
state appropriations to higher education, Equation 1 was estimated with
[A.sub.i,t] defined as the growth rate of real state appropriations to
higher education and all state-specific income variables defined as
growth rates. Growth rates are commonly used in the empirical business
cycle literature; estimating the relationship between the growth rate of
real income and the growth rate of real appropriations will make the
results in this paper more comparable to this existing literature.
Transforming the levels data to growth rates may also correct for the
effects of heteroscedasticity, if present.
3. Empirical Results and Discussion
Table 1 shows the results obtained by estimating Equation 1 for the
entire panel under several specifications of [X.sub.i,t]. [6] The
dependent variable is real state appropriations per FTE for all
specifications reported on Table 1. Specification 1 includes a single
variable, real per capita income per person lagged one year, as the
measure of state-specific business cycle conditions. Year-specific dummy
variables were also included in this specification to capture unmeasured
factors that affect government spending on higher education in states
over time. The year dummies and state-specific effects were all
significant for this specification. [7] The parameter on lagged real per
capita income is significant at the 1% level. The implied elasticity of
real state appropriations to higher education per FTE with respect to
changes in real per capita income in the previous year, based on this
point estimate and the means of the variables is 1.39, implying that a
1% change in real per capita income in the precedin g year is associated
with a 1.39% change in real state appropriations per FTE to higher
education in the following year; state appropriations per FTE to higher
education are highly sensitive to state-specific changes in the business
cycle in this specification.
Specification 2 includes two lags of real per capita personal
income as well as year dummies. Including a second lag of per capita
income allows this specification to capture effects of the business
cycle on state appropriations to higher education that occur over a
longer period of time than those in specification 1. The coefficient on
real personal income lagged one year is statistically significant, but
the coefficient on real per capita income lagged two years is not.
Specification 1 is nested in specification 2 under the condition that
the parameter on the second lag of real per capita income is equal to
zero. The F-statistic for this restriction has a value of 42.5, which
suggests that two lags of real per capita income belong in the empirical
model, even though the second lag is not statistically significant. [8]
A two-year lag is consistent with the results in Holtz-Eakin,
Newey, and Rosen (1989) regarding the relationship between government
revenues and government expenditure. It is also consistent with biennial
budget cycles that are used in some states. The overall impact of
business cycle effects on real state government appropriations to higher
education is very close to the one-year effect estimated from
specification 1. The cumulative impact has an elasticity of 1.39 at the
means of the variables, which again suggests that variations in real per
capita income have a more than proportional effect on real
appropriations per FTE.
Specification 3 investigates the possibility that the effect of
business cycles on state appropriations to higher education varies
across legs of the business cycle. In order to test this hypothesis, a
state-specific measure of the turning points in the business cycle was
constructed, based on the annual growth rate of real personal income in
each state in each year in the sample. Years in which this growth rate
was negative were defined as recessions, and years in which this growth
rate was zero or positive were defined as expansions. This method is
roughly consistent with the method used by the NBER Dating Committee to
determine the turning points in the business cycle for the entire U.S.
economy, although the NBER uses quarterly data. Using this procedure,
18% of the state-years in the sample were recessionary.
Based on this criterion, two dummy variables were created,
reflecting the expansionary and recessionary years for each state. The
dummy variable for recessionary years, [[D.sup.r].sub.i,t] was
constructed using the criteria
[[D.sup.r].sub.i,t] = {0 if % change in real per capita personal
income [greater than or equal to] 0 {1 otherwise.
The dummy variable for expansionary years was constructed using
[[D.sup.e].sub.i,t] = {1 if % change in real per capita personal
income [greater than or equal to] 0 {0 otherwise.
Specification 3 interacts these two dummy variables with real per
capita personal income lagged one year. The parameter on
[[D.sup.e].sub.i,t-1] [X.sub.i,t-1] captures the impact of expansionary
years on real state government appropriations per student and the
parameter on [[D.sup.r].sub.i,t-1] [X.sub.i,t-1] captures the impact
during recessions.
The parameters on these two variables are statistically significant
and close to the same size. Specification 1 is nested in specification 3
under the restriction [[beta].sub.e] = [[beta].sub.r]. An F-test on this
restriction has a value of 0.324, accepting the null hypothesis that the
effect of expansions and recessions on real state appropriations to
higher education, is roughly the same.
Table 2 shows the average impact of a recession, here defined as a
2.25% decline--roughly the median decline in the recessionary years in
the sample--in real per capita personal income, on state appropriations
to higher education based on the results for specification 2 on Table 1
for several states. These states represent the extremes of the
distribution of state provision of higher education in the sample for
several definitions of provision. The reported impact is calculated at
the average appropriations per FTE over the period 1969-1994 in 1984
dollars and the average FTE enrollment in two-year and four-year public
institutions of higher education in each state. New Hampshire (average
appropriations per FTE $1,982) and New York ($4,818) represent the two
extremes in terms of average appropriations per FTE. [9] Nevada (2.6%)
and Utah (5.5%) have the lowest and highest average FTE enrollment in
public two- and four-year institutions of higher education per capita in
the sample. Vermont (14,073) and Califor nia (924,143) have the lowest
and highest average FTE enrollment, respectively, in public two- and
four-year institutions of higher education in the sample. These
estimated impacts suggest that the effects of a recession on state
appropriations to higher education are quite substantial in magnitude.
As further evidence of the impact of these effects, consider the
case of Maryland's appropriations to public higher education during
the early 1990s. The impact of the recession during this period on state
funding for higher education in Maryland has been documented by Eaton,
Miyares, and Robertson (1995). Maryland went through a two-year-long
recession in the early 1990s. The results in Table 2 suggest that the
average impact of this recession on state appropriations to higher
education would have been about $26.5 million 1984 dollars. The actual
cuts, which took place over two years, totaled $91 million 1984 dollars,
or $126 million current dollars. The actual decline in real
appropriations was over three times the estimated decline on Table 1,
suggesting that either the economic downturn in the early 1990s in
Maryland was larger than average, or the state legislators and
bureaucrats who determined the size of the spending cuts were unusually
harsh. The decline in real per capita income in Maryland during this
recession was roughly equal to the median decline across all states
during recessions over the sample period. The fraction of state
government expenditure on Medicaid rose from 10% to just below 14%, and
the fraction spent on public safety increased from about 11.5% to 12.5%
during the same period.
Eaton, Miyares, and Robertson argue that the cuts in appropriations
to higher education in the early 1990s in Maryland were extraordinarily
large, relative to both prior experiences in Maryland and to experiences
in other states. The results from Tables 1 and 2 suggest that the
decline in appropriations to higher education in Maryland were
considerably larger than the average decline across all states and
recessions in the sample, which supports their claim. State policy
makers in Maryland appear to have performed a considerable amount of
budget-balancing at the expense of funding to higher education during
this recession. The overall impact of these funding cuts on public
higher education was the discontinuation or reduction in size of 60
bachelors programs and 35 masters and doctoral programs, 22 departments
consolidated into 10, and the elimination of two schools.
The results presented in Tables 1 and 2 suggest that state business
cycle conditions, as reflected in variation in real per capita income,
have a significant effect on real state government appropriations per
FTE enrollment. The estimates from specification 3 also suggest that the
elasticity during recessionary years is equal to the elasticity during
expansionary years. Although appropriations per student fall more than
proportionately during recessions, they also rise more than
proportionately during expansions. This symmetric effect could be
interpreted as evidence that state governments cut back on
appropriations to higher education during recessions and then give back
these funds during expansions.
Another explanation is that changes in enrollments, which are
countercyclical, are contributing to the symmetry of the estimated
effects of recessions and expansions on appropriations per FTE. If
enrollments are countercyclical, then appropriations per FTE will rise
(fall) during expansions (recessions) because the denominator falls
(rises), even if appropriations remain unchanged.
One way to investigate the relationship between appropriations to
higher education and the business cycle and control for differences
among states in size and preferences for the provision of public higher
education, while removing the effects of variation in enrollments, is to
use growth rates of the variables. Table 3 shows estimates of Equation 1
when the dependent variable is the growth rate of real state
appropriations and the business cycle variables are defined as the
growth rate of real income.
The results are similar to those reported on Table 1 in terms of
the sign and significance of the variables. The first lag of growth in
real income is significant in specification 1 and although the second
lag is not significant in specification 2, an F-test on the implied
restriction rejects specification 1 in favor of specification 2. The
elasticity of the growth rate of real appropriations with respect to
changes in the growth rate of real income implied by specification 2 at
the means of the variables is 0.4. This equates to an elasticity of 2.9
when the variables are expressed in levels. The implied impact of
business cycles on state appropriations for this specification is
considerably larger that the impact implied by the results on Table 1.
However, the estimates of specification 3 are strikingly different
in that the effect of recessions on the growth rate of real state
appropriations to higher education are considerably larger than the
effect of expansions. The elasticities, 1.14 for recessions and 0.15 for
expansions, are also different. These estimates imply a much different
effect of recessions on appropriations to higher education than
expansions. Based on these estimates, the cuts in appropriations to
higher education during recessions are more than proportional to the
decline in real income, while the increases during expansions are less
than proportional to the increases in real income. Note that this does
not necessarily imply that total funding to higher education has fallen
as a result of recessions because expansions last considerably longer
than recessions and the increase in income during expansions are
generally larger than the decline during recessions. Still, these
estimates imply that funding to higher education may take quite some
time to return to prerecession levels following a period of
recession-induced budget cuts.
One explanation for the difference between the estimates of
specification 3 reported in Table 1 and those reported in Table 3 is the
effect of enrollments on the dependent variable in Table 1. If the
effect of expansions on enrollments is relatively stronger than the
effect of recessions on enrollments, then changes in appropriations per
FTE will be larger in absolute value during expansions than during
recessions. This would tend to increase the estimated impact of
expansions on appropriations per FTE and decrease the estimated impact
of recessions.
If appropriations to higher education fall more during recessions
than they rise during expansions, then this ratio should exhibit
cyclical variation. An examination of plots of this ratio by state
showed a considerable amount of variation over the business cycle,
confirming the empirical results shown in Table 3. This ratio fell
sharply during both the 1974 recession and the two closely spaced
recessions in the early 1980s and rebounded during the long expansion in
the 1980s in most states. A similar pattern could be seen for the 1990
recession, although differences in the timing of that recession across
states make it harder to clearly discern.
In summary, the results reported in Tables 1 and 3 are consistent.
Both suggest that business cycles affect both state appropriations per
student and the growth rate of state appropriations to higher education.
Both also suggest that the impact of business cycles on appropriations
to higher education during recessions is proportionately larger than the
change in the economic climate, as measured by declines in personal
income. However, the countercyclical behavior of enrollments may mask
asymmetries in the effect of recessions and expansions on state
appropriations to higher education when appropriations are weighted by
enrollments.
4. Conclusions
The results presented in this paper suggest that state-specific
changes in the business cycle have significant effects on state
government appropriations to higher education. A 1% decline in real per
capita income was associated, on average with, a 1.39% decline in state
appropriations to higher education per student in the following year.
The effects are statistically significant as long as two years after a
change in real per capita personal income. Because enrollments rise
during recessions, a decline in funding may place significant fiscal
stress on public institutions of higher education.
Consider the implications of these results, along with the
previously discussed enrollment effects reported by Betts and McFarland
(1995), in community colleges during an economic downturn, If the local
unemployment rate rose 2% during a recession, and real per capita income
fell by 2.25%, a typical community college would experience an 8%
increase in enrollment and a 3.4% decrease in state appropriations per
student at roughly the same time, assuming that the estimates reported
on Table 1 reflect on average the same effect on state appropriations to
four-year colleges and community colleges. [10] A community college
facing such fiscal stress might find it difficult to provide quality
higher educational services to its student body. Worse, the additional
students enrolled during this period are primarily people who were laid
off or fired during the economic downturn and are attempting to acquire
new skills in order to regain employment. Outcomes like this are clearly
not consistent with the main goals of pub lic higher education.
These results have clear policy implications. In order to avoid
placing severe fiscal burdens on institutions of higher education during
economic downturns, state policy makers should consider extending some
budgetary protection to higher education during these periods. The
evidence in this paper suggests that under current policies, funding to
institutions of higher education may be an attractive target for policy
makers seeking the path of least resistance when cutting spending to
balance state budgets. Unfortunately, the timing of these budget cuts
places a considerable amount of fiscal stress on public institutions of
higher education because they coincide with increases in enrollment.
Countercyclical economic policies are typically associated with
monetary and fiscal policies undertaken by the federal government.
However, public higher education plays an important role in educating
workers who lose their jobs during economic downturns, and thus plays an
important, although indirect role in stabilization policies. Because of
the importance of education to long run economic growth and stability,
state government policy makers should, in this case, be encouraged to
pursue their own stabilization policies by not cutting appropriations to
higher education during economic downturns. By maintaining funding to
higher education during recessions, public institutions of higher
education will be better able to provide quality education to students
during recessions. This may reduce the duration of these spells of
unemployment and should make these students more productive when they
return to the labor force.
(*.) Department of Economics, 1000 Hilltop Circle, University of
Maryland Baltimore County, Baltimore, MD 21250, USA; E-mail
[email protected].
Thanks to Bob Black, Kathleen Carroll, Dennis Coates, Bill Lord,
Clark Nardinelli, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Ryan
Mutter provided excellent research assistance; Karl Kendell at the
Census Bureau Governments Division, David Smith at the Bureau of Labor
Statistics, and the Center for Higher Education and Educational Finance
for kindly provided data. All remaining errors are my own.
Received December 1998; accepted January 2000.
(1.) McGranahan (1999) examined the effect of business cycles on
state government budgets and found that many revenue and expenditure
categories are sensitive to changes in the business cycle. This study
found a similar relationship between appropriations and the business
cycle using a different measure of business cycle effects, the
unemployment rate.
(2.) See McKeown (1996) for a detailed discussion of the
development and use of formulas in the funding of education.
(3.) Although this study omits the effects of state and federal
financial aid on state appropriations to higher education, the marginal
cost variable in these models depends in part on enrollments, and thus
may also be affected by business cycles.
(4.) Based on data from table B-87 in the Economic Report of the
President (1998).
(5.) It would be more appropriate to weight income by the
population age 16 and older. However, annual estimates of state
population age 16 and older are not readily available for the early part
of the sample.
(6.) Regression diagnostics indicated that the equation errors for
these regressions were both heteroskedastic and autocorrelated. The
procedure suggested by Newey and West (1987) was used to correct the
standard errors; the reported standard errors are robust to
heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation of order AR(1).
(7.) These results are available on request from the author.
(8.) This F-statstic is based on the sum of squared errors from an
ordinary least squares (OLS) regression, and not on those from the
Newey-West correction. It is not comparable to the t-test implied by the
standard errors reported in Table 1. Because an additional lag reduces
the sample size by 50, the F- and t-tests based on the OLS standard
errors are not strictly comparable. This also holds for the F-test for
the growth rate regressions reported below.
(9.) In the lower 48 states, Alaska and Hawaii both have higher
appropriations per FTE, but I have excluded them from this example but
not the sample.
(10.) Unfortunately, state appropriations data were not available
disaggregated by level of institution.
References
Betts, Julian R., and Laurel L. McFarland. 1995. Safe port in a
storm: The impact of labor market conditions on community college
enrollments. Journal of Human Resources 30:741-65.
Clotfelter, Charles T. 1976. Public spending for higher education:
An empirical test of two hypotheses. Public Finance 32:177-94.
Eaton, Gertrude, Javier Miyares, and Ruth Robertson. 1995.
Statewide planning during declining state support. Planning far Higher
Education 23:27-34.
Getz, Malcolm, John J. Siegfried, and Hao Zhang. 1991. Estimating
economies of scale in higher education. Economics Letters 37:203-8.
Hoenack, Stephen A. 1983. Economic Behavior Within Organizations.
New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Hoenack, Stephen A., and Daniel J. Pierro. 1990. An econometric
model of a public university's income and enrollments. Journal of
Economic Behavior and Organization 14:403-23.
Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, Whitney Newey, and Harvey Rosen. 1989. The
revenues-expenditures nexus: Evidence from local government data.
International Economic Review 30:415-29.
Koshal, Rajindar K., and Manjulika Koshal. 1999. Economies of scale
and scope in higher education: A case of comprehensive universities.
Economics of Education Review 18:269-77.
Leslie, Larry L., and Garey Ramey. 1986. State appropriations and
enrollments, does enrollment growth still pay? Journal of Higher
Education 57:1-19.
Lewis, Laurie, and Elizabeth Farris. 1995. Statistics in brief:
Higher education finances and services. Washington, DC: United States
Department of Education, National Center for Education Statistics.
McGranahan, Leslie. 1999. State budgets and the business cycle:
Implications for the federal balanced budget amendment debate. Federal
Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives 23:2-17.
McKeown, Mary P. 1996. State funding formulas: Promise fulfilled?
In Struggle to survive: Funding higher education in the next century,
edited by David S. Honeyman, James L. Wattenbarger, and Kathleen C.
Westbrook. Thousand Oaks, CA: Corwin Press, pp. 49-85.
Nardinelli, Clark, Miles Wallace, and John Warner. 1988. State
busines cycles and their relationship to the national cycle: Structural
and institutional determinants. Southern Economic Journal 54:950-60.
NASBO Information Brief. 1996. State innovations in higher
education finance and government. Washington, DC: National Association
of State Budget Officers.
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1987. A simple, positive
semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent
covariance matrix. Econometrica 55:703-8.
Quigley, John, and Daniel Rubenfeld. 1993. Public choices in public
higher education. In Studies of supply and demand in higher education,
edited by Charles Clotfelter and Michael Rothchild. Chicago, IL:
University of Chicago Press, pp. 243-83.
United States Department of Education. 1990. State higher education
profiles. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.
United States Department of Education. 1996. Digest of educational
statistics. Washington, DC: United States Department of Education.
United States Government Printing Office. 1998. Economic report of
the president. Washington, DC: United States Government Printing Office.
Data Appendix
State-specific data on total personal income and population for the
period 1969-1994 were taken from the U.S. Department of Commerce
Regional Economic Information System (REIS) CD-ROM, which is available
from the Bureau of Economic Analysis, Regional Economic Measurement
Division. Data on state government appropriations to higher education
were provided by the Center for the Study of Education Finance at
Illinois State University and can also be found in past editions of the
higher education newsletter Grapevine, which is published by the Center
for the Study of Educational Finance, 340 DeGarmo Hall, Illinois State
University, Normal, IL 61761-6901. Some of the year-to-year variation in
enrollment is due to the closing of existing institutions of higher
education and the opening of new institutions of higher education.
Although such events are relatively rare, they do occur in the sample.
The year-specific dummy variables described above also serve as a
control for these year-to-year changes in the total num ber of
institutions of higher education in the states.
The appropriation data were deflated using the higher education
price index (HEPI): the personal income data were deflated using the
consumer price index (CPI). The CPI and HEPI data were taken from the
Digest of Educational Statistics (1996), table 38. These data are
available on line at http://nces.ed.gov/pubs/digest97/d97t038.html, the
National Center for Education Statistics website. Deflating the
appropriations data by the CPI had no substantial effect on the
empirical results.
The enrollment data were compiled from two sources. Total and FTE
enrollment by state from 1969 through 1990 were published in State
Higher Education Profiles (SHEP) (1990). For the period 1991-1994,
similar measures of total and FTE enrollment were calculated from the
publicly available Integrated Postsecondary Education Data System (IPEDS) Fall Enrollment surveys. The 1991-1994 enrollment data were
constructed using the same set of public institutions that comprised the
1990 SHEP sample; the 1991-1994 data are comparable to the pre-1991
data.
The mean values of the key variables for each state for the period
1969-1994, in 1984 dollars, are shown on Appendix Table 1. There is a
good deal of variation in state appropriations per FTE in public
institutions in the sample, as well as the preferences for the provision
of public higher education, as measured by FTE enrollment per capita.
Note when comparing appropriations per FTE and income per person that
the denominators are quite different, as shown by column three.
Appendix Table 2 shows the sample means by state for the data
expressed in growth rates, which yield the estimates shown on Table 3.
One interesting feature of this table is the negative growth rates of
enrollment per capita in the group of predominantly western states
(Arizona, California, Hawaii, Oregon, and Washington, along with
Minnesota). It appears that the population in these states was growing
faster than the capacity of public institutions of higher education over
the sample.