The determinants of bank rates in local consumer lending markets: comparing market and institution-level results.
Feinberg, Robert M.
1. Introduction
With the exception of a few very recent studies, the sizeable
literature on the impact of market structure in banking markets (1) has
ignored the potential competitive role played by credit unions. This is
surprising, since the continuing consolidation of the financial services industry in recent years has naturally raised concerns about competitive
effects and credit unions would seem to be a likely source of market
discipline. (2) This paper explores these issues using both market and
firm data.
Using a variety of approaches, economists have started paying some
attention to the interaction between banks and credit unions. Emmons and
Schmid (2000), using county-level data, examine two-way intertemporal
linkages between credit union participation rates and market
concentration of the commercial banking sector to support the view that
the two types of institutions compete in the market for consumer
deposits; similarly, Feinberg and Rabman (2001) find that credit union
and bank rates for two consumer loan products can each be shown to be
influenced by the other. Tokle and Tokle (2000) found a competitive
influence of credit unions on bank certificate of deposit (CD) rates
offered in Idaho and Montana, while Feinberg (2001) explored their
impact on consumer loan rates in a broader sample of relatively small
local markets (3) over the 1992-1997 period.
The latter article found that both unsecured and new vehicle loan
rates offered by banks in these markets were affected in a significant
manner by the market share held by the two leading banks (implying a
competitive role for smaller financial institutions generally) and--for
new vehicle loan rates alone--by the share of credit unions in those
markets. Whether these results would generalize to larger metropolitan
areas is unclear and is the topic of what follows. I focus on the same
two loan products, 24-month unsecured (non-credit card) loans and
48-month new vehicle loans, both of which seem likely to be provided in
a local market, and empirically explain the determinants of bank loan
rates in a sample of 56 markets--both large and small--for the period
1992-1998. An innovative aspect of this paper is that I analyze both
market-level data and institution-level data for 81 banks in those 56
markets and consider as well the role of multimarket linkages affecting
these banks.
2. Theoretical Framework
Virtually all models of imperfect competition imply that increasing
entry and supply from fringe suppliers will lower prices. This clearly
suggests that an increasing credit union presence should discipline
prices in local financial services markets. To formalize, I employ a
modified version of the dominant firm-price leadership model. The
modification involves the notion that while credit unions may generally
be thought of as fringe suppliers, not all banks and savings and loans (S&Ls) would realistically constitute a dominant group. Nevertheless
as a group we can think of banks and S&Ls as being relatively
dominant, with the degree to which a monopoly position over their
residual demand (i.e., netting out credit unions) is exploited depending
on how concentrated bank and S&L deposits are in the leading two
institutions. (4)
The number of major firms is often quite small in local consumer
lending markets, and there is a genuine concern that in the absence of
pressure from a "competitive fringe" these leading firms may
be able to act in a collusive manner. In the spirit of Saving (1970), I
assume a homogeneous product, with market demand for loans Q = D(P).
Credit unions are treated as a price-taking fringe, with their supply
[S.sup.CU](P) and the demand faced by banks and S&Ls, [D.sup.B](P),
a residual:
[D.sup.B](P) = D(P) - [S.sup.CU](P). (1)
Taking first derivatives with respect to price, multiplying all
terms by (P/Q), and multiplying the lefthand side expression by
([D.sup.B](P)/[D.sup.B](P)) and the last term on the right-hand side by
([S.sup.CU](P)/[S.sup.CU](P)), I obtain
[PD.sup.B]'(P)[D.sup.B](P)/[D.sup.B](P)D(P) = D'(P)P/D(P)
- [S.sup.CU]'(P)[PS.sup.CU](P)/[S.sup.CU](P)D(P) (2)
or, simplifying, and defining CU to be equal to [S.sup.CU](P)/D(P),
the credit union market share, and then dividing through by 1 - CU, I
obtain an expression in terms of price elasticities of demand and
supply,
\[[eta].sub.B]\ = \[eta]\/(1-CU) + [[epsilon].sub.CU] (CU/(1-CU)).
(3)
If I assumed that all non-credit union institutions acted to
jointly maximize profits, I would of course find that their Lemer Index,
LI = (P - MC)/P = 1/\[[eta].sub.B]\ . More realistically, I parameterize the extent to which the Lemer Index approaches this value as a function
of dominance within the bank and S&L group of the two leading firms
(to simplify, a linear function) so that
LI = [theta]/\[[eta].sub.B]\, (4)
where [theta] = kCR2/(1 - CU), CR2 = the share of the two largest
financial institutions in total market deposits (including credit
unions), k is a constant, and 0 < [theta] < 1.
Substituting Equation 3 into Equation 4, I obtain the bank/thrift
Lemer Index to be
LI = kCR2/\[eta]\ + [[epsilon].sub.CU]CU. (5)
Without any further mathematical analysis, the following
implications clearly emerge: (i) As CR2 increases the LI increases as
well; (ii) as CU increases the LI declines; (iii) as [[epsilon].sub.CU]
increases the LI declines; and, not quite as obvious (but easy to
derive), (iv) the declines in (ii) and (iii) are larger in absolute
value as CR2 is larger. All of the qualitative results above follow when
I replace LI with the market price, which is the variable I seek to
explain in the empirical work to follow.
While obviously this model is quite ad hoc in nature, the clear
implication is that bank concentration, the credit union share, and the
supply elasticity of credit unions all matter in determining the
exercise of market power in these markets.
3. Data
Data on bank loan rates (5) were obtained (via a Freedom of
Information Act request) from the Federal Reserve Board's Quarterly
Report of Interest Rates on Selected Direct Consumer installment Loans,
and on local market structure from Sheshunoff Information Services, for
the 1992-1998 period. The two bank loan rates (reported for the second
week of Februaiy, May, August, and November) are for 48-month new auto
loans and for 24-month non-credit card unsecured consumer loans, for
which banks are requested to report their most common rate. These types
of loans are the only ones reported on in the Federal Reserve Board
survey.
Markets were included for which data were available on bank rates
for both types of loans for at least two-thirds of the 28 quarterly
observations from 1992 through 1998. I also deleted six markets in which
a single credit union was among the top two depository institutions during this period (as these markets seem inconsistent with the model
above in which credit unions are viewed as a competitive fringe)6 and
three markets in which local market structure data were distorted by the
presence of bank credit card operations. (7) This left 56 markets
(listed in Appendix A), defined as metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs)
or nonmetropolitan counties. (8) Of these, 52 are MSAs ranging in size
(based on 1990 population figures) from Victoria (Texas)--with a
population of 74,361--to the New York City consolidated MSA--with almost
20 million people. The other four are rural counties ranging in size
from Atchison County (Kansas)--16,932--to Sussex County (Delaware)--1
13,229. The median 1990 population for the 56 mar kets was 674,267.
My initial analysis was performed at the level of the market, with
a simple average of loan rates of surveyed banks within that market (or
if only one bank was surveyed that bank's loan rate) taken to proxy
the market rate. Based on deposit data from banks, thrifts, and credit
unions (collected by Sheshunoff Information Services), the share of
total market deposits held by credit unions and by the top two
depository institutions and (as a proxy for scale economies being
exploited in the market) the absolute total of the largest institution
deposits in the market were recorded for each market and time period.
(9) To proxy the elasticity of supply by credit unions, data were
obtained from the Credit Union National Association (CUNA) on
state-level credit union membership as a percentage of adult population.
The federal funds rate (obtained from Federal Reserve statistics) was
employed as a proxy for the cost of funds to banks.
Descriptive statistics for the market-level analysis are given in
Table 1, which contains a breakdown by small and big markets, those
below or above one million in 1990 population. Clearly, the average big
market has a somewhat smaller credit union presence (7.9% vs. 9.1%) and
slightly smaller top two bank share (39.6% vs. 41.4%). Not surprisingly,
the largest institution is considerably bigger (averaging more than $10
billion vs. just over one billion dollars for the small markets). The
average rates are roughly one-quarter (for new vehicle loans) to
three-quarters (for unsecured loans) of a percentage point higher in the
big markets. In the individual bank analysis to follow, bank deposit
market shares and absolute deposit size were included and the loan rate
of the particular bank was used; in addition, I examine the impact of
participation by banks in leading bank holding companies for performance
in particular markets (descriptive statistics for the individual bank
sample are presented below).
4. Regression Results
I employ a fixed effects regression model, (10) with coefficient
estimates reported in Table 2, explaining (with all variables in natural
logs (11)), across both time and markets, bank loan rates (UNSECURED and
NEWVEHICLE) by the deposit share of the top two non--credit union
institutions (CR2), the total share of deposits held by credit unions
(CU), deposit size of largest institution in the market (TOPDEPOSITS),
the federal funds rate one quarter lagged (12) (FEDFUNDS), quarterly
dummies (to control for seasonal factors), and market-fixed effects.
Since the model above indicates a role for the elasticity of supply of
credit unions (essentially a measure of the ease of expansion), I
attempted to proxy this by the state-level credit union membership
penetration ratio (actually a dummy variable, HISTATE, equal to one
where this was greater than 25%). (13) While no interaction term between
CR2 and CU is included (which would seem to be necessary to test
hypothesis (iv) above), a log specification implies that g reater bank
concentration will always increase the price-reducing impact of credit
unions, as long as a greater credit union share does reduce prices and
increased concentration raises prices. (14) No time fixed effects (other
than the quarter dummies) were included since I already am including a
variable--the federal funds rate--which varies intertemporally but not
across markets. (15)
It should be noted that while the dependent variables reflect loan
rates on products representing relatively small shares of a typical
bank's portfolio, the market structure variables are developed from
the bank's deposit position. On the one hand this may be seen as
introducing measurement error into the estimation; however, on the other
hand, deposit shares may be seen as instruments that deal with the
potential simultaneity, often noted in critiques of
structure-performance studies, between price or profit rates and market
shares. In the current context it is hard to imagine a bank's
choice of loan rate on unsecured or auto loans having any significant
effect on its deposits.
While initial expectations were for less of an impact of credit
unions when larger population centers were included than for the
small-market results reported in Feinberg (2001), the results presented
here suggest the opposite, at least for unsecured loans--the coefficient
of the CU share is twice what it was in the small-market sample and is
now statistically significant (which it had not been in the earlier
results). In fact, for both equations all estimated coefficients have
the expected signs, and all but CR2 in the UNSECURED equation are
statistically significant at conventional levels in explaining bank loan
rates. Market-fixed effects are important (F-tests reject the hypothesis
of all zero coefficients for the market dummy variables), and the
quarter dummies suggest some limited seasonality in auto loan rates
(slightly lower in the third and fourth quarters of the year, perhaps in
connection with the introduction of the new season of cars).
The elasticities of the loan rate with respect to the lagged
federal funds rate may seem at first glance to be quite small. However,
full passthrough (around mean values of the loan rates and federal funds
rate) would imply elasticities of +0.35 for unsecured loans and of +0.53
for new vehicle loans; in this context the estimated elasticities of 0.1
for unsecured loans and 0.3 for new vehicle loans are more reasonable.
The impact of the top two bank share (CR2) is relatively small in both
equations (0.03 vs. 0.08). The CU effect is only half as large for
unsecured loans as for the new vehicle rate (-0.06 vs. -0.12) but is
clearly not trivial in magnitude; an increase from the mean CU share
(8.68%) to 10% would imply a reduction in the unsecured bank loan rate
from its mean of 13.42% to 13.30% and a reduction in the new vehicle
bank loan rate from 8.80% to 8.65%. In addition, it is important to note
the significant negative impact on rates for both types of bank loans of
HISTATE, indicating a spillover effect on local markets of a large CU
presence in the state (and, in the context of the model described
earlier, possibly capturing the role of greater ease of CU expansion).
An argument for scale economies in banking is supported by the
statistically significant estimated effect of leading firm absolute
size.
While these results suggest a significant role of credit union
influence (and market structure more generally) on loan pricing in local
markets, the use of market-level observations prevents me from
attempting to separate out firm-level from market-level impacts. In what
follows, I replicate the above results using data on 81 banks (in the 56
markets examined above) over the quarterly observations from 1992 to
1998. Another feature of this analysis is that I can see whether banks
that are part of major bank holding companies determine loan prices
differently from other firms; while a negative effect could be explained
by efficiencies of multibank operation, there is both theory and
previous empirical support for a positive price effect of multimarket
operation (both generally and in the banking sector). (16)
Descriptive statistics for the bank-level variables--loan rates as
defined earlier, market share (BANKSHR), total deposits (BANKSIZE), and
a dummy variable distinguishing banks belonging to one of the top 10
bank holding companies, as of 1996 (TOPlOBHC) (17)--are shown in Table
3. The banks in our sample (listed in Appendix B) have a mean share of
17.1% of market deposits, but this varies from as little as 0.04% to a
high of 47.38%. They range in deposit size from $12.2 million to $83.8
billion. About 18% of the banks in our sample were subsidiaries of one
of the 10 leading bank holding companies (BHCs). (18)
Table 4 describes changes over time in several of our key
variables. Consistent with the wave of bank consolidation occurring
during the decade of the 1990s (and continuing to the present), the mean
bank market share in our sample rises steadily from 16.1% in 1992 to
18.7% in 1998, while the share of the two leading banks and thrifts
rises from 38.9% to 43.0%, and the proportion of our banks associated
with the leading bank holding companies rises from 14% to more than 19%
over the sample period. (19) Perhaps providing something of a
competitive counterweight to this trend, the share of deposits held by
credit unions slowly rises from 7.9% in 1992 to 8.3% in 1996 before
falling in 1997 and (somewhat dramatically, to 7.5%) in 1998. (20)
Regression estimates are reported in Table 5, explaining (as
before, with all variables in natural logs)--in a fixed effects
framework--bank loan rates by the bank's deposit share of the
market, the bank's total volume of deposits within the market, a
dummy variable representing a subsidiary of one of the 10 leading bank
holding companies, (21) and variables previously used in the
market-level regression--CR2, CU, HISTATE, FEDFUNDS, and quarterly dummy
variables.
Not surprisingly, the effects of the federal funds rate, credit
union influence variables, and quarterly dummies on bank loan pricing
are very similar to their influence in the market-level regression. Of
particular interest, however, are the impacts of BANKSHR, BANKSIZE,
TOP10BHC, and CR2. For both types of consumer loans, increased market
share increases loan rates (although the effect on auto loans is only
weakly significant, perhaps reflecting the emergence of competition from
national automobile finance companies), while bank size has a strongly
significant negative impact on loan pricing--consistent with scale
economies playing a role.
After controlling for firm-level effects, the concentration
variable now has a negative effect, statistically significant for new
vehicle loans; this result is consistent with much of the prior
literature. (22) Looking to influences beyond the immediate market,
there is a clear indication of higher unsecured loan rates (but not new
vehicle rates) in banks that belong to leading bank holding companies
and that thus meet each other in multiple markets (73) This result is
more consistent with the mutual forebearance view of multimarket contact
than with the notion of efficiencies of branching across multiple
markets.
5. Summary and Conclusions
Findings like those in Feinberg (2001) showing a positive impact of
market concentration on prices (and more often in other studies on
profit rates) are often taken to indicate the presence of collusion among few sellers leading to higher market prices. When a comparable
analysis is performed at a lower level of aggregation, however, that
effect is often seen to be a spurious result of aggregating individual
firm market share effects. In fact, as was found in this study, after
controlling for individual firm effects the impact of market
concentration is often negative; the latter may be the result of scale
economies exploited by leading firms and (through competitive pressures)
transmitted into lower prices for all firms in a market.
The lack of a positive market concentration effect does not deny
the presence of market power in local consumer lending markets. However,
this power is more likely the result of unilateral bank behavior and
must be considered alongside apparent scale economy benefits of large
size. Price-increasing effects can be limited by a significant credit
union presence (both actual and potential) and enhanced by multimarket
contacts among bank holding companies.
The results presented here point to a strong procompetitive role
for credit unions on bank loan pricing. Generally the greater the local
market share of credit unions, and the greater the state-level
membership penetration, the lower bank loan rates are--both for
unsecured and new vehicle loans. In addition, the results support the
importance of local markets in the consumer banking sector; differences
in market structure defined at the local level clearly produce
differences in market and bank loan rates.
Appendix A
List of Markets
1. Birmingham, AL
2. Little Rock, AR
3. Sussex County, DE
4. Fort Pierce/Port St. Luice, FL
5. Macon, GA
6. Des Moines, IA
7. Sioux City, IA
8. Evansville, IN
9. Fort Wayne, IN
10. Atchison County, KS
11. Wichita, KS
12. Louisville, KY
13. Baton Rouge, LA
14. Lafayette, LA
15. Portland, ME
16. Grand Rapids, MI
17. Marquette County, MI
18. Leflore County, MS
19. Billings, MT
20. Fargo, ND
21. Omaha, NE
22. Rena, NV
23. Dayton, OH
24. Mansfield, OH
25. Youngstown, OH
26. Oklahoma City, OK
27. Tulsa, OK
28. Johnstown, PA
29. Amarillo, TX
30. El Paso, TX
31. Victoria, TX
32. Richmond, VA
33. Roanoke, VA
34. Burlington, VT
35. Huntington, WV
36. Hartford, CT
37. Atlanta, GA
38. Chicago, IL
39. Boston, MA
40. Detroit, MI
41. Minneapolis, MN
42. St. Louis, MO
43. Charlotte, NC
44. Buffalo, NY
45. New York, NY
46. Rochester, NY
47. Cincinnati, OH
48. Cleveland, OH
49. Columbus, OH
50. Portland, OR
51. Pittsburgh, PA
52. Providence, RI
53. Memphis, TN
54. Nashville, TN
55. Dallas, TX
56. Milwaukee, WI
Appendix B
Sample of Banks (Names as of 1996) and Their Markets
1. Amsouth Bank ot Alabama, Birmingham
2. Boatmens National Bank, Little Rock
3. Glastonbury Bank and Trust, Hartford
4. First Omni Bank, Sussex County (DE)
5. First NB&TC Treasure Coast, Ft. Pierce (FL)
6. First Union National Bank, Atlanta
7. Suntrust Bank, Atlanta
8. Suntrust Bank Middle Georgia, Macon
9. Norwest Bank Iowa, Des Moines
10. Security National Bank, Sioux City
11. First National Bank, Chicago
12. Northern Trust Company, Chicago
13. LaSalle National Bank, Chicago
14. Aurora National Bank, Chicago
15. Citizens National Bank, Evansville
16. Norwest Bank Indiana, Fort Wayne
17. Exchange NB&TC, Atchison County (KS)
18. Intrust Bank, Wichita
19. National City Bank, Louisville
20. PNC Bank Kentucky, Louisville
21. Hancock Bank of Louisiana, Baton Rouge
22. First National Bank, Lafayette (LA)
23. First National Bank, Boston
24. Fleet Bank New Hampshire, Boston
25. Fleet Bank Maine, Portland
26. Comerica Bank, Detroit
27. NBD Bank, Detroit
28. Michigan National Bank, Detroit
29. Old Kent Bank, Grand Rapids
30. MFC First NB, Marquette County (MI)
31. First Bank, Minneapolis
32. Mercantile Bank, St. Louis
33. Bank of Commerce, Le Flore County (MS)
34. First Interstate Bank, Billings
35. First Union National Bank, Charlotte
36. Norwest Bank ND, Fargo
37. Norwest Bank Nebraska, Omaha
38. Pioneer Citizens Bank, Reno
39. Marine Midland Bank, Buffalo
40. Manufacturers and Traders Bank, Buffalo
41. Bank of New York, New York City
42. Chemical Bank, New York City
43. National Bank, Rochester
44. Star Bank, Cincinnati
45. Fifth Third Bank, Cincinnati
46. PNC Bank, Cincinnati
47. First National Bank of Ohio, Cleveland
48. Bank One Akron, Cleveland
49. National City Bank, Cleveland
50. Premierbank and Trust, Cleveland
51. Huntington National Bank, Columbus
52. National City Bank, Columbus
53. Bank One, Columbus
54. Bank One, Dayton
55. Bank One, Mansfield
56. Mahoning National Bank, Youngstown
57. Liberty Bank and Trust, Oklahoma City
58. Boatmens First National Bank, Oklahoma City
59. Bank of Oklahoma, Tulsa
60. United States National Bank of Oregon, Portland
61. Johnstown Bank and Trust, Johnstown
62. Integra Bank, Pittsburgh
63. PNC Bank, Pittsburgh
64. Mellon Bank, Pittsburgh
65. Rhode Island Hospital Trust NB, Providence
66. Union Planters National Bank, Memphis
67. First American National Bank, Nashville
68. Suntrust Bank, Nashville
69. Amarillo National Bank, Amarillo
70. Bank One Texas, Dallas
71. Sunwest Bank, El Paso
72. First Victoria National Bank, Victoria
73. Crestar Bank, Richmond
74. Signet Bank, Richmond
75. Central Fidelity National Bank, Richmond
76. First Union National Bank, Roanoke
77. First Virginia Bank--Southwest, Roanoke
78. Key Bank of Vermont, Burlington
79. Firstar Bank, Milwaukee
80. Marshall & Jisley Bank, Milwaukee
81. Bank One West Virginia, Huntington
Table 1
Descriptive Statistics (Number of Observations)
Mean SD Minimum Maximum
56 markets, 28 quarters (1992:1 to
1998:IV)
CU (1568) 8.68% 4.77 0 23.34
CR2 (1568) 40.72% 10.41 16.26 70.08
TOPDEPOSITS (1568) $4.58B 8.75B 66.07M 83.8.2B
STATE-CU PENETRATION(1568) 26.64% 8.51 8.60 58.40
FEDFUNDS (28 quarters) 4.68% 1.04 2.99 6.02
UNSECURED (1519) 13.42% 2.08 7.00 18.99
NEWVEHICLE (1515) 8.80% 1.08 4.82 15.00
Small markets (under one million
1990 population)
CU (980) 9.12% 5.11 0 23.34
CR2 (980) 41.42% 10.83 16.26 62.77
TOPDEPOSITS (980) $1.20B 1.02B 66.07M 5.66B
STATE-CU PENETRATION (980) 27.39% 9.71 8.60 58.40
UNSECURED (924) 13.11% 2.18 7.00 18.88
NEWVEHICLE (921) 8.70% 1.08 4.82 15.00
Big markets (over one million 1990
population)
CU (588) 7.93% 4.04 1.44 20.41
CR2 (588) 39.55% 9.56 18.82 70.08
TOPDEPOSITS (588) $10.23B 12.32B 1.65B 83.82B
STATE-CU PENETRATION (588) 25.40% 5.79 16.60 42.40
UNSECURED (595) 13.91% 1.82 8.50 18.99
NEWVEHICLE (594) 8.97% 1.06 6.00 14.83
Table 2
Regression Results Explaining Bank Loan Rats--Market-Level Observations
(t Statistics in Parentheses)
Dependent Variable
UNSECURED NEWVEHICLE
[FEDFUNDS.sub.t-1] 0.103 0.277
(8.09) (28.13)
CR2 0.031 0.084
(0.62) (2.16)
CU -0.056 -0.118
(2.13) (5.74)
TOPDEPOSITS -0.095 -0.174
(3.71) (8.61)
HISTATE -0.046 -0.042
(2.49) (2.91)
QTR II -0.005 -0.002
(0.66) (0.36)
QTR III -0.012 -0.015
(1.50) (2.45)
QTR IV -0.005 -0.021
(0.57) (3.44)
Observations 1465 1460
[R.sup.2] 0.597 0.523
All variables in natural logs.
Market fixed effects are not presented here.
Table 3
Descriptive Statistics, Bank-Level Data (Number of Observations)
Mean SD Minimum Maximum
81 banks, 28 quarters
(1992:I to 1998:IV)--some
missing observations
UNSECURED (2123) 13.65% 2.45 5.61 24.38
NEWVEHICLE (2110) 8.77% 1.06 5.99 15.00
BANKSHR (2152) 17.14% 8.62 0.04 47.38
BANKSIZE (2152) $4.4B $7.9B $12.2M $83.8B
TOP10BHC (2152) 0.18 0.38 0 1
Table 4
Mean Values by Year, Selected Variables
BANKSHR CR2 CU TOP10BHC
1992 16.1 38.9 7.9 0.14
1993 16.4 38.3 8.1 0.18
1994 16.6 38.4 8.3 0.19
1995 16.6 38.8 8.2 0.19
1996 17.3 40.4 8.3 0.19
1997 18.5 42.3 8.1 0.18
1998 18.7 43.0 7.5 0.19
Table 5
Regression Results Explaining Bank Loan Rates--Bank-Level Observations
(t Statistics in Parentheses)
Dependent Variable
UNSECURED NEWVEHICLE
[FEDFUNDS.sub.t-1] 0.083 0.295
(6.09) (35.33)
CR2 -0.006 -0.146
(1.60) (5.83)
CU -0.037 -0.090
(1.28) (4.97)
BANKSHR 0.114 0.044
(3.08) (1.89)
BANKSIZE -0.086 -0.103
(2.68) (5.11)
TOPIOBHC 0.063 0.002
(2.37) (0.12)
HISTATE -0.049 -0.047
(2.82) (4.25)
QTR II -0.003 -0.002
(0.36) (0.49)
QTR III -0.012 -0.0155
(1.41) (3.01)
QTR IV -0.003 -0.021
(0.33) (4.20)
Observations 2064 2051
[R.sup.2] 0.528 0.563
All variables in natural logs.
Bank fixed effects are not presented here
Received February 2002; accepted October 2002.
(1.) These include Amel and Liang (1997), Rhoades (1997), Humphrey
and Pulley (1997), Simons and Stavins (1998), Berger and Hannan (1989,
1998), Rhoades (1987), and Hannan (1991).
(2.) Related to this is a recent policy debate on the role of
credit unions and whether the government should encourage or limit
access to these organizations.
(3.) While innovations in technology have led some to the view that
all lending markets are national, Simons sad Stavins (1998) present
evidence suggesting that banking markets are stilt predominately local
in nature. They point to the Federal Reserve Board's 1992 Survey of
Consumer Finances, which shows that 94.1% of households using a
financial institution identified a local institution as their primary
provider of financial services; both deposit accounts and sourees of
credit were primarily local in nature. More recently, Amel and
Starr-McCluer (2002) have noted (examining more recent versions of that
survey) that consumer loans--especially new vehicle loans--became less
locally limited during the 1990s.
(4.) Obviously the choice of which concentration ratio to use is
somewhat arbitrary (in particular the top two or top three or even the
top four share); nevertheless I focus in this paper on the top two firm
share. The top four firm share, often used in national-level
manufacturing sector studies, was frequently equal or close to 100%
(especially for the smallest markets) and did not show as much variation
as the top two measure; furthermore, the top two share has been used in
other banking studies of local markets. Another rationale for choosing
the top two share is found in Kwoka (1979), based on its greater ability
(in his empirical study) to explain profit margins in manufacturing.
(5.) These are for commercial banks, both federally and state
chartered, and the loan rates are specific to the particular market in
question (e.g., NationsBank is not asked for a single loan rate for all
markets in which they operate).
(6.) In addition, some of these credit unions were multibranch
credit unions with operations far beyond the boundaries of the
particular market, and one served essentially as a central bank for
credit unions with little impact on the local lending market. Markets
excluded for this reason were Albany (NY), Anchorage (AK), Kansas City (MO), Lynchburg (VA), Peoria (IL), and Washington (DC).
(7.) These were Dover (DE), JCPenney; Sioux Falls (SD), Citicorp;
and Casper (WY), Norwest.
(8.) Market-fixed effects should pick up the impact of variables
(including perhaps per capita income), which may be correlated with
market size.
(9.) Since bank loan rates were available quarterly, but market
structure variables were only available on an annual basis (reflecting
data as of June 30th), some smoothing of the market structure variables
was employed; initially the annual observation was repeated for each
quarter, and then a three-quarter centered moving average was
constructed. As a practical matter this implied that the second and
third quarter observations were the actual reported as of June 30th,
while the first and fourth quarter observations reflected weighted
averages of current and previous or future year figures.
(10.) A Hausman test suggested this was a more appropriate
specification than a random effects approach.
(11.) The few zero observations on credit union shares were
arbitrarily adjusted to 0.05% in order to take logs.
(12.) Using current quarter FEDFUNDS made very little difference in
the results, although the impact of the lagged federal funds rate on all
bank and credit union loan rates was consistently larger than the
contemporaneous effect.
(13.) The 25% cutoff corresponds roughly to the mean value of the
continuous measure. HISTATE performs better than the continuous measure
of state-level CU penetration and conforms to our expectation that the
relationship should be a discontinuous one reflecting cultural and
regulatory factors differing by state that would make future credit
union expansion--potential competition in the market--more or less
likely (although another interpretation would be that membership
penetration could proxy potential future demand for loans). As noted by
a referee, the state-level membership penetration is positively
correlated with the market-level CU deposit share, making it difficult
to separate their impacts on loan rates; HISTATE may be thought of as an
instrument allowing the two effects to be better estimated.
(14.) In earlier work, a regression on levels containing an
interaction term between CU and CR2 did find the estimated coefficient
of this term to be negative as predicted and statistically significant.
(15.) Preliminary attempts to include a demand growth variable
(differing by market) failed to find significant effects. To the extent
these followed national trends, the federal funds rate would likely
capture demand growth; to the extent certain markets had secularly high
or low growth over the period, market-fixed effects would capture these
effects. Similarly, cross-market income differences would be picked up
by fixed effects.
(16.) See Feinberg (1985) and Bernheim and Whinston (1990) and, for
banking specifically, Alexander (1985) and Hannan and Prager (2001).
(17.) These were Chase Manhattan, Citicorp, BankAmerica, JP Morgan,
Nationsbank, First Union, First Chicago NBD, Bankers Trust, Bank One,
and Norwest. Of course, the restriction to 10 BHCs is arbitrary
(although encompassing most of the household names in consumer banking);
however, virtually all the banks surveyed were part of some bank holding
company (some quite small or limited in geographical scope), so some
such cutoff was required for this variable to have any meaning.
(18.) I continue to maintain the inclusion criteria of at least 19
observations during the 28 quarters in the sample period.
(19.) While this implies a bank surveyed in one market often shares
a common parent with a bank surveyed in another, loan rates reported
appear to be determined independently (perhaps more accurately, they are
far from perfectly correlated).
(20.) Anecdotally, the drop in the credit union deposit share after
1996 corresponds to a major legal effort by banks to block the growth in
credit union membership, which culminated in a U.S. Supreme Court
decision in February 1998, ruling that federal credit unions had
illegally expanded to include unrelated occupational groups (legislation
signed by President Clinton in the summer of 1998, and which took effect
in January 1999, largely overturned that decision).
(21.) The list of 10 leading bank holding companies is defined as
of 1996. As banks were acquired during the period by these bank holding
companies, there is some variation in this dummy variable over time.
(22.) An early finding along these lines was Ravenscraft (1983).
(23.) In preliminary results not reported here, there appear to be
some patterns of common BHC effects across markets. Unsecured rates were
significantly higher at subsidiaries of Bank of Boston, First Chicago
NBD Boatmens, Wells Fargo, Bank of America, and First Union; they were
significantly lower at US Bank, PNC, Bank One, and SunTrust.
References
Alexander, Donald L. 1985. An empirical test of the mutual
forebearance hypothesis: The case of bank holding companies. Southern
Economic Journal 52:122-40.
Amel, Dean F., and J. Nellie Liang. 1997. Determinants of entry and
profits in local banking markets. Review of Industrial Organization
12:59-78.
Amel, Dean F., and Martha Starr-McCluer. 2002. Market definition in
banking: Recent evidence. Antitrust Bulletin 47:63-89.
Berger, Allen N., and Timothy H. Hannan. 1989. The
price-concentration relationship in banking. Review of Economics and
Statistics 71:291-9.
Berger, Allen N., and Timothy H. Hannan. 1998. The efficiency cost
of market power in the banking industry: A test of the "quiet
life" and related hypotheses. Review of Economics and Statistics
80:454-65.
Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Michael D. Whinston. t990. Multimarket
contact and collusive behavior. The Rand Journal of Economics 21:1-26.
Emmons. William R., and Frank A. Sebmid. 2000. Bank competition and
concentration: Do credit unions matter? Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis Review 82:29-42.
Feinberg, Robert M. 1985. "Sales-at-risk": A test of the
mutual forbearance theory of conglomerate behavior. Journal of Business
58:225-41.
Feinberg, Robert M. 2001. The competitive role of credit unions in
small local financial services markets. Review of Economics and
Statistics 83:560-3.
Feinberg, Robert M., and A. F. M. Alaur Rabman. 2001. A causality test of the relationship between bank and credit union lending rates in
local markets. Economics Letters 71:271-5.
Hannan, Timothy H. 1991. Bank commercial loan markets and the role
of market structure: Evidence from surveys of commercial lending.
Journal of Banking and Finance 15:133-49.
Hannan, Timothy H., and Robin A. Prager. 2001. The competitive
implications of multimarket bank branching, Federal Reserve Board,
Finance and Economics Discussion Paper No. 2001-43.
Humphrey, David B., and Lawrence B. Pulley. 1997. Banks'
responses to deregulation: Profits, technology, and efficiency. Journal
of Money, Credit, and Banking 29:73-93.
Kwoka, John E., Jr. 1979. The effect of market share distribution
on industry performance. Review of Economics and Statistics 61:101-9.
Ravenscraft, David J. 1983. Structure-profit relationships at the
line of business and industry level. Review of Economics and Statistics
65:22-3 1.
Rhoades, Stephen A. 1987. The effect of nonbank thrift institutions on commercial bank profit performance in local markets. Quarterly Review
of Economics and Business 27:16-28.
Rhoades, Stephen A., ed. 1997. Special issue on industrial
organization topics in banking. Review of Industrial Organization
12:1-139.
Saving, Thomas. 1970. Concentration ratios and the degree of
monopoly. International Economic Review 11:1396.
Simons, Katerina, and Joanna Stavins. 1998. Has antitrust policy in
banking become obsolete? New England Economic Review, March/April:13-26.
Tokle, Robert J., and Joanne G. Tokle. 2000. The influence of
credit union and savings and loan competition on bank deposit rates in
Idaho and Montana. Review of Industrial Organization 17:427-39.
Robert M. Feinberg *
* Department of Economics, American University, Washington, DC
20016-8029, USA; Email
[email protected].
The author thanks Ataur Rahman for research assistance; Bill Kelly,
Doug Davis, Tim Hannan, Larry White, and two referees for helpful
suggestions; and acknowledges research funding support from the Filene
Research Institute and the Center for Credit Union Research, School of
Business, University of Wisconsin--Madison. All views expressed are
those of the author alone.