Nonlinear purchasing power parity under the Gold Standard.
Peel, David A.
1. Introduction
Recent theoretical analysis of purchasing power deviations (see,
e.g., Dumas 1992; Sercu, Uppal, and Van Hull 1995; and O'Connell
and Wei 1997) demonstrates how transactions costs or the sunk costs of
international arbitrage induce nonlinear adjustment of the real exchange
rate to purchasing power parity (PPP). Globally mean-reverting this
nonlinear process has the important property of exhibiting near unit
root behavior for small deviations from PPP since small deviations from
PPP are left uncorrected if they are not large enough to cover the
transactions costs or the sunk costs of international arbitrage.
A parametric nonlinear model, suggested by the theoretical
literature, that captures the nonlinear adjustment process in aggregate
data is the exponential smooth transition autoregression model (ESTAR)
of Ozaki (1985). A smooth, rather than discrete, adjustment mechanism is
motivated by the theoretical analysis of Dumas (1992). Also, as
postulated by Terasvirta (1994) and demonstrated theoretically by Berka
(2002), in aggregate data regime changes may he smooth, rather than
discrete, given that heterogeneous agents do not act simultaneously even
if they make dichotomous decisions. (1) Recent empirical work (e.g.,
Michael, Nobay, and Peel 1997; Taylor, Peel, and Sarno 2001, Peel and
Venetis 2002) has reported empirical results that suggest that the ESTAR
model provides a parsimonious fit into a variety of data sets,
particular for monthly data for the interwar and postwar floating period
as well as for annual data spanning 200 years, as reported in Lothian
and Taylor (1996). In addition, nonlinear impulse response functions
derived from the ESTAR models show that although the speed of adjustment
for small shocks around equilibrium will be highly persistent, larger
shocks mean-revert much faster than the glacial rates previously
reported for linear models (Rogoff 1996). In this respect, the ESTAR
models provide some solution to the PPP puzzle outlined in Rogoff
(1996). (2)
The ESTAR model can also provide an explanation of why PPP
deviations analyzed from a linear perspective appear to be described by
either a nonstationary integrated I(1) process, or alternatively,
described by fractional processes (see, e.g., Diebold, Husted, and Rush
1991). Taylor, Peel, and Sarno (2001), and Pippenger and Goering (1993)
show that the Dickey-Fuller tests have low power against data simulated
from an ESTAR model. Michael, Nobay, and Peel (1997) and Byers and Peel
(2003) show that data that is generated from an ESTAR process can appear
to exhibit the fractional property. That this would be the case was an
early conjecture by Acosta and Granger (1995). Given that the ESTAR
model has a theoretical rationale, whereas the fractional process is a
relatively nonintuitive one, the fractional property might reasonably be
interpreted as a misleading linear property of PPP deviations (Granger
and Terasvirta 1999).
Whereas the empirical work employing ESTAR models provides some
explanation of the glacially slow adjustment speeds obtained in linear
models, there is one aspect of the empirical work that is worthy of
further attention. A second way of explaining the Rogoff puzzle, raised
by Rogoff himself, (3) is to relax the assumption that the equilibrium
real exchange rate is a constant (see, e.g., Canzoneri, Cumby, and Diba
1996; and Chinn and Johnston 1996). Theoretical models, such as that of
Balassa (1964) and Samuelson (1964), imply a nonconstant equilibrium in
the real exchange rate if real productivity growth rates differ between
countries. (4) Nonlinear models that incorporate proxies fur these
effects are found to parsimoniously fit post-Bretton Woods data for the
main real exchange rates (see Venetis, Paya, and Peel 2002; and Paya,
Venetis, and Peel 2003). Naturally, models that ignore this effect may
generate misleading speeds of PPP adjustment to shocks. In this regard,
the empirical results of Hegwood and Papell (2002) for the Gold Standard
period are particularly interesting. Balassa-Samuelson effects are one
of the major arguments for the numerous equilibrium mean shifts found in
Hegwood and Papell (2002) for the real exchange rates in the 16 real
exchange rate series analyzed in Diebold, Husted, and Rush (1991) for
the period 1792-1913 under the Gold Standard. Hegwood and Papell (2002)
assume linear adjustment around an occasionally changing equilibrium
determined on the basis of the Bai-Perron (1998) test for multiple
structural breaks. They report that quick mean reversion around an
occasionally changing mean provides a more reasonable representation of
the data than does fractional integration, which was originally reported
by Diebold, Husted, and Rush (1991) for their data set. They conclude
that long-ran PPP (LRPPP) does not hold but instead it is quasi-PPP
(QPPP) theory-the one supported by their analysis of the data. They also
state that the slow convergence of LRPPP is due to the unaccounted mean
shifts in the equilibrium rate and that a reduction of more than 50% is
achieved in the half-lives of shocks when those shifts are included in
the model.
These results are potentially important and provide motivation for
our study. Hegwood and Papell (2002) only consider the impacts of
structural breaks in the context of linear adjustment. In this article,
we further examine the real exchange rate adjustment mechanism in the
19th and early 20th centuries under the Gold Standard by employing an
ESTAR framework that allows for both a constant and structural breaks in
the equilibrium real rate. Because the gold standard era was a high
point of international cooperation (Diebold, Husted, and Rush 1991, p.
1254) and it was a symmetric arrangement (both parts were committed to
maintain parities), the symmetric nonlinear ESTAR model is an
appropriate model of real exchange rate behavior at that time. We find
that ESTAR models incorporating the structural breaks employed by
Hegwood and Papell (2002) provide a parsimonious explanation of the
data. We determine the significance of the structural breaks via
bootstrap and Monte Carlo analysis. We then investigate the speeds of
adjustment obtained from nonlinear impulse response functions in these
models and compare them to the estimated models that exclude structural
breaks. Our results provide further support, on a new data set, for the
hypothesis that real exchange rates are stationary, symmetric, nonlinear
processes that reverted in this time period to a changing equilibrium
real rate. The half-life of shocks implied by the nonlinear impulse
response functions were found to be dramatically faster than those
obtained in models that do not include the breaks. Clearly, our results
support those of Hegwood and Papell (2002).
The rest of the article is organized as follows. In section 2, we
discuss the ESTAR model considered in our empirical applications and
report empirical estimates of ESTAR models where the real exchange rate
long run path is modeled both as a variable or a constant. Section 3
presents the Monte Carlo simulation exercise for the confidence interval of the statistics. Section 4 presents the results of the estimated
impulse response functions for the nonlinear models. Finally, section 5
summarizes our main conclusions.
2. Nonlinear PPP
We analyze properties of a set of currencies (dollar, pound,
Deutsche mark. French franc, Belgian franc, and Swedish krona) spanning
the period 1792-1913. We use the same data set as in Diebold, Husted,
and Rush (1991) and Hegwood and Papell (2002). (5) This data set
includes 10 real exchange rates using wholesale price index (WPI) as the
deflator of the nominal exchange rate, and six real exchange rates that
use the consumer price index (CPI) as the deflator. We normalize all of
the real rates so that the first observation is set equal to zero.
Hegwood and Papell (2002) could not reject the null of a unit root on
the basis of the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) tests for 11 out of the
16 series. Six additional series reject the null of unit root when they
apply the Perron-Vogelsang (1992) test for unit root while allowing a
single mean shift in the data. The five remaining real exchange rates
reject the unit root test in favor of a fractionally integrated
alternative as reported in Diebold, Husted. and Rush (1991). These
results are all consistent with the possibility that the real exchange
rate followed an ESTAR process as noted in the previous section. (6)
We assume the true data-generating process for the PPP deviations
([y.sub.t]) modified for structural breaks has the simple form of the
ESTAR model reported in Taylor, Peel, and Sarno (2001) and Paya,
Venetis, and Peel (2003):
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where [y.sub.t] is the real exchange rate ([y.sub.t] = [s.sub.t] -
[p.sub.t] + [p.sup.*.sub.t]), [s.sub.t] is the logarithm of the spot
exchange rate, [p.sub.t] is the logarithm of the domestic price level,
and [p.sup.*.sub.t] the logarithm of the foreign price level; [alpha] is
the constant equilibrium level of the real exchange rate, [gamma] is a
positive constant (the speed of adjustment), [[beta].sub.i] are
constants, [d.sub.1] ... [d.sub.n] are dummies for shifts in the
equilibrium rate, and [u.sub.t] is a random disturbance term. (7)
The first model we estimate is the simple ESTAR model for the real
exchange rate with a constant equilibrium ([d.sub.1] ... [d.sub.n] are
set to zero). Tables 1 and 2 present the results of the estimations for
Wholesale Price Index (WPI) and Consumer Price Index (CPI) real rates,
respectively. The speed of adjustment parameter is significant in all
cases except for the Belgium/U.S. and Belgium/Germany WPI rates and the
Belgium/Germany CPI rate. The autoregressive structure of the ESTAR
model (the [[beta].sub.i]) varies from an AR(1) to an AR(3). (8) Given
the significance of [gamma] and that in all cases we cannot reject that
the sum of the autoregressive terms adds up to 1, we impose this
constraint in all estimations. (9)
Hegwood and Papen (2002), on the basis of the Bat and Perron (1998)
test for multiple mean shifts, provide evidence that the real exchange
rates do not exhibit a constant conditional mean for the whole sample,
but instead they follow a mean reversion process to a changing mean. We
include the same dummies that they found significant in the equilibrium
process of the real exchange rates. (10) Tables 3 and 4 present the
results for the estimation of the ESTAR model with changing equilibrium
rates. Some of the initial dummies appeared to be insignificant when the
real rates were allowed to follow a nonlinear mean-reverting process. We
then removed the dummies that were insignificant in the new estimations.
(11) The last column of Tables 3 and 4 display the F-test for the joint
significance of all remaining dummies. In all cases, we can reject the
null that all dummies were insignificant when taken all together, except
in the case of the France/Sweden CPI real exchange rate. However, the
residuals do exhibit significant nonnormality, and in this case the
distribution of the statistics could follow nonclassical forms within a
nonlinear framework. Consequently, we employ a bootstrap method in order
to obtain appropriate test statistics.
3. Robustness Analysis
Our null hypothesis is that the dummy variables for breaks have
zero coefficients. Accordingly we simulate an "artificial"
series for [y.sub.t] [??].sub.t] given the estimates of [alpha] and
[gamma] obtained in Tables 3 and 4, with the coefficients on the dummy
variables for structural breaks set to zero. The residuals [u.sup.b] are
obtained from bootstrapping, with replacement, the estimated residuals
obtained from the ESTAR models reported in those tables that include the
dummies. (12) The resulting "artificial" series are given by
(2) [[??].sub.t] = [??] + [e.sup.[??]([[??].sub.t-1]-[[??]).sup.2]
([[??].sub.t-1] - [??]) + [u.sub.b].
We then estimate the nonlinear ESTAR model including the pertinent
dummies in each case, and we repeat this experiment 10,000 times. The
distribution of the t-statistics are computed as well as the
distribution of the F-test for each real exchange rate. Tables 5 and 6
present the 90% and 95% confidence intervals for the t-statistics of
each dummy and the F-test. On the basis of the F-statistics obtained in
the nonlinear estimation and the critical values from the bootstrap, we
can reject the null of joint nonsignificance of the dummies in all cases
except for the France/Sweden and France/Germany CPI real rates. With
regard to the particular dummy variables, some of them cannot be
considered significant within this framework. (13) Hegwood and Papell
(2002) provide some historical support for some of the dummies they
found significant in their study. Our results support the significance
of most of those dummies: the 1864 dummy in the U.S. real exchange rate
coinciding with the American Civil War, the 1866 dummy in the German
real exchange rates coinciding with the dissolution of the German
Confederation, and the dummies of the 1940s when there was widespread
protest, rebellion, and revolution in Europe (Cook and Stevenson 1998,
p. 460).
4. Nonlinear Haft-Lives of Shocks
In this section we compare the speed of mean reversion of the
nonlinear model of real exchange rates with constant equilibrium as well
as comparing shifting equilibrium with the speed of mean reversion of
the linear model as in Hegwood and Papell (2002). To calculate the
half-lives of PPP deviations within the nonlinear framework, we must
take into account that a number of properties of the impulse response
functions of linear models do not carry over to the nonlinear models.
(14) Koop, Pesaran, and Potter (1996) introduced the generalized impulse
response function (GIRF) for nonlinear models. The GIRF is defined as
the average difference between two realizations of the stochastic
process {[y.sub.1]+h]}, which start with identical histories up to time
t - 1 (initial conditions). The first realization is hit by a shock at
time t, whereas the other one is not:
(3) GIR[F.sub.h] (h, [delta], [[omega].sub.t-1]) = E([y.sub.t+h] [u.sub.t] = [delta], [[omega].sub.t-1]) - E ([y.sub.t+h] / [u.sub.t] =
0, [[omega].sub.t-1]),
where h = 1, 2, ..., denotes horizon, [u.sub.t] = [sigma] is an
arbitrary shock occurring at time t; and [[omega].sub.t-1] defines the
history set of [y.sub.t].
Given that [delta] and [omega.sub.t-1] are single realizations of
random variables, Equation 3 is considered to be a random variable. In
order to obtain sample estimates of Equation 3, we average out the
effect of all histories [[omega].sub.t-1]- that consist of every set
([y.sub.t-1] ..., [y.sub.t-p]) for t [greater than or equal to] p + 1,
where p is the autoregressive lag length, and we also average out the
effect of future shocks [u.sub.t+h]. (15) We set [sigma] = 5%, 10%, 20%,
30%, and 40%. The different values of [sigma]s would allow us to compare
the persistence of very large and small shocks. As in Taylor, Peel, and
Sarno (2001) and in Paya, Venetis, and Peel (2003), Tables 7 and 8
report the half-lives of shocks; that is, the time needed for
[GIRF.sub.h] < 1/2 [sigma]. (16) The last columns of both Tables 7
and 8 correspond to the speeds of adjustment found in the linear models
of Hegwood and Papell (2002). For the nonlinear models with constant
equilibrium (Table 7), the half-life of the shocks decreases
significantly for shocks of around 30%, or even 40% in some cases.
However, compared with the linear case, even with the smallest shock of
5% the speed of mean reversion is faster in the ESTAR model. When the
equilibrium is allowed to change over time (Table 8) the arbitrage band
in the nonlinear model seems to lie around 20%, or even 10%. In this
case, 10 out of the 16 real exchange rates need a shock of 20% to
achieve faster adjustment than the linear case.
5. Conclusions
Hegwood and Papell (2002) analyzed PPP adjustment under the Gold
Standard. They allowed for novel structural breaks in the equilibrium
real exchange rate and suggested that relatively quick linear adjustment
to an occasionally changing mean provides a more reasonable
representation of the data than does the fractional process, with its
long memory property, for their data set--the latter was originally
reported by Diebold, Husted, and Rush (1991).
In this article we have shown that the theoretically well-motivated
nonlinear ESTAR process. embodying structural breaks in the equilibrium
real rate, provides a parsimonious explanation of the data set. As
conjectured by Rogoff (1996) and supported by our analysis and that of
Hegwood and Papell (2002), allowance for a changing real equilibrium can
have dramatic implications for the estimates of PPP adjustment speeds.
On the basis of these results, empirical work exploring this possibility
in postwar data may help solve the Rogoff puzzle.
Table 1. ESTAR Estimations of Wholesale Price Index (WPI) Real
Exchange Rates, 1792-1973
WPI [[??].sub.0] [[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.2]
United States/ -0.076 1.28 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United Kingdom (0.019) (0.13)
United States/ -0.033 1.09 1 - [[??].sub.1]
Germany (0.031) (0.08)
Germany/ -0.21 1.25 -0.56
United Kingdom (0.039) (0.09) (0.16)
France/ 0.008 1.14 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United Kingdom (0.014) (0.10)
France/ -0.141 1.03 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United States (0.017) (0.10)
France/Germany 0.186 1.23 0.48
(0.027) (0.06) (0.096)
Belgium/ 0.262 1
United Kingdom (0.026)
Belgium/France 0.197 1
(0.019)
WPI [[??].sub.3] [??] s
United States/ -3.12 0.075
United Kingdom (0.90)
United States/ -2.52 0.095
Germany (0.71)
Germany/ 1 - [[??].sub.1] - [[??].sub.2] -1.52 0.076
United Kingdom (0.68)
France/ -11.86 0.057
United Kingdom (1.03)
France/ -7.42 0.060
United States (1.86)
France/Germany 1 - [[??].sub.1] - [[??].sub.2] -2.55 0.051
(0.98)
Belgium/ -2.49 0.042
United Kingdom (0.95)
Belgium/France -2.98 0.047
(0.94)
WPI [R.sup.2] q = 1 q = 4 q = 12
United States/ 0.71 0.70 0.89 0.69
United Kingdom
United States/ 0.65 0.72 0.32 0.37
Germany
Germany/ 0.80 0.42 0.80 0.75
United Kingdom
France/ 0.57 0.95 0.40 0.75
United Kingdom
France/ 0.70 0.93 0.80 0.93
United States
France/Germany 0.89 0.16 0.26 0.55
Belgium/ 0.88 0.16 0.30 0.49
United Kingdom
Belgium/France 0.87 0.31 0.31 0.22
Numbers in parentheses are the Newey-West (1987: NW) standard error
estimates. s denotes residuals standard error. The test for
autocorrelation for lags 1, 4, and 12 denotes the p-values of the
Eitrheim and Terasvirta (1996) Lagrange Multiplier test for
autocorrelation in nonlinear series.
Table 2. ESTAR Estimations of Consumer Price Index (CPI) Real
Exchange Rates, 1792-1913
CPI [[??].sub.0] [[??].sub.0] [[??].sub.0]
Sweden/Germany -0.123 1.26 1 - [[??].sub.1]
(0.039) (0.085)
France/Sweden 0.001 1.51 1 - [[??].sub.1]
(0.010) (0.11)
France/Germany -0.004 1.23 1 - [[??].sub.1]
(0.037) (0.12)
France/Belgium 0.189 1
(0.023)
Belgium/Sweden -0.154 0.94 1 - [[??].sub.1]
(0.018) (0.10)
CPI [[??].sub.3] [??] s [R.sup.2]
Sweden/Germany -2.41 0.074 0.80
(1.23)
France/Sweden -13.77 0.033 0.82
(2.45)
France/Germany -7.17 0.081 0.70
(4.90)
France/Belgium -4.57 0.045 0.83
(1.54)
Belgium/Sweden -4.75 0.045 0.83
(1.40)
CPI q = 1 q = 4 q = 12
Sweden/Germany 0.32 0.16 0.22
France/Sweden 0.12 0.39 0.89
France/Germany 0.34 0.22 0.52
France/Belgium 0.36 0.84 0.99
Belgium/Sweden 0.21 0.08 0.29
Numbers in parentheses are standard error estimates. s denotes the NW
residuals standard error. The test for autocorrelation for lags 1, 4,
and 12 denotes the p-values of the Eitrheim and Terasvirta (1996)
Lagrange Multiplier test for autocorrelation in nonlinear series.
Table 3. ESTAR Estimations of Wholesale Price Index (WPI) Real
Exchange Rates, 1792-1913 with Dummies
WPI [[??].sub.0] [[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.2]
United States/ -0.124 0.228
United Kingdom (0.024) (0.028)
United States/ 0.027 -0.137 0.113
Germany (0.031) (0.037) (0.036)
Germany/ -0.068 -0.134 -0.237
United Kingdom (0.022) (0.042) (0.027)
France/ -0.028 0.098 -0.042
United Kingdom (0.001) (0.021) (0.017)
France/ -0.220 0.136 0.063
United States (0.014) (0.037) (0.022)
France/Germany 0.054 0.313 0.203
(0.020) (0.025) (0.030)
Belgium/ 0.398 -0.320 -0.226
United Kingdom (0.017) (0.020) (0.018)
Belgium/ -0.002 0.295 0.251
United States (0.045) (0.026) (0.008)
Belgium/Germany 0.073 0.096
(0.023) (0.030)
Belgium/France 0.292 -0.246
(0.012) (0.017)
WPI [[??].sub.3] [[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.2]
United States/ 1.28 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United Kingdom (0.15)
United States/ 0.157 1.07 1 - [[??].sub.1]
Germany (0.043) (0.088)
Germany/ -0.091 1.27 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United Kingdom (0.029) (0.15)
France/ 0.032 1.32 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United Kingdom (0.013) (0.10)
France/ 0.230 1.02 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United States (0.026) (0.08)
France/Germany 0.097 1.22 1 - [[??].sub.1]
(0.028) (0.07)
Belgium/ -0.08 1.09 1 - [[??].sub.1]
United Kingdom (0.018) (0.12)
Belgium/ 1
United States
Belgium/Germany 1.27 1 - [[??].sub.1]
(0.12)
Belgium/France 1
WPI [??] s [R.sup.2]
United States/ -4.28 (1.21) 0.071 0.75
United Kingdom
United States/ -4.43 (0.78) 0.088 0.71
Germany
Germany/ -8.50 (2.18) 0.075 0.81
United Kingdom
France/ -30.9 (9.21) 0.039 0.65
United Kingdom
France/ -34.1 (15.9) 0.050 0.81
United States
France/Germany -27.5 (1.75) 0.046 0.91
Belgium/ -186.7 (64.7) 0.036 0.91
United Kingdom
Belgium/ -0.88 (0.32) 0.061 0.69
United States
Belgium/Germany -8.96 (3.32) 0.055 0.65
Belgium/France -53.3 (17.73) 0.043 0.90
WPI q = 1 q = 4 q = 12 F
United States/ 0.27 0.55 0.52
United Kingdom
United States/ 0.43 0.39 0.61 7.33
Germany
Germany/ 0.08 0.04 0.20 5.76
United Kingdom
France/ 0.40 0.95 0.74 8.84
United Kingdom
France/ 0.11 0.11 0.29 15.6
United States
France/Germany 0.17 0.77 0.53 10.35
Belgium/ 0.88 0.79 0.74 10.38
United Kingdom
Belgium/ 0.15 0.64 0.46 6.99
United States
Belgium/Germany 0.79 0.62 0.74
Belgium/France 0.70 0.76 0.81
Numbers in parentheses are standard error estimates. s denotes
the residuals standard error.
Table 4. ESTAR Estimations of Consumer Price Index (CPI) Real
Exchange Rates, 1792-1913 with Dummies
CPI [[??].sub.0] [[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.2]
Sweden/Germany -0.278 0.312 0.173
(0.017) (0.028) (0.028)
France/Sweden 0.000 -0.023 0.015
(0.007) (0.012) (0.008)
France/Germany -0.030 0.241 0.048
(0.033) (0.064) (0.025)
France/Belgium 0.197 -0.015
(0.024) (0.007)
Belgium/Sweden -0.273 0.264 0.180
(0.009) (0.011) (0.011)
Belgium/Germany -0.732 0.604 0.453
(0.015) (0.017) (0.033)
CPI [[??].sub.3] [[??].sub.4] [[??].sub.5]
Sweden/Germany
France/Sweden
France/Germany
France/Belgium
Belgium/Sweden 0.078
(0.012)
Belgium/Germany 0.192 0.073 0.026
(0.040) (0.029) (0.022)
CPI [[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.2] [??] S
Sweden/Germany 1.43 1 - [[??].sub.1] -17.41 0.060
(0.13) (4.69)
France/Sweden 1.50 1 - [[??].sub.1] -21.18 0.033
(0.11) (4.35)
France/Germany 1.31 -0.62 -7.63 0.074
(0.09) (0.13) (4.25)
France/Belgium 1 -5.20 0.046
(2.11)
Belgium/Sweden 1.16 1 - [[??].sub.1] -2.55 0.037
(0.12) (71.8)
Belgium/Germany 1.39 1 - [[??].sub.1] -19.88 0.062
(0.12) (5.67)
CPI [R.sup.2] q = 1 q = 4 q = 12 F
Sweden/Germany 0.88 0.28 0.15 0.00 22.80
France/Sweden 0.82 0.11 0.35 0.91 0.93
France/Germany 0.75 0.10 0.23 0.62 3.88
France/Belgium 0.85 0.27 0.71 0.99
Belgium/Sweden 0.89 0.30 0.67 0.59 13.16
Belgium/Germany 0.93 0.51 0.63 0.99 7.96
Numbers in parentheses are standard error estimates. s denotes the
residuals standard error. The test for autocorrelation denotes the
p-values of the Eitrheim and Terasvirta (1996) LM test. The
[[??].sub.3] coefficient in the France/Germany rates equals
1 - [[??].sub.1] - [[??].sub.2].
Table 5. Bootstrap Confidence Interval for t-Stat and F-Stat for
Dummies (a)
Wholesale Price Index D1 D2
United States/United Kingdom
90% (-3.2, 3.1)
95% (-4.4, 4.0) *
United States/Germany
90% (-2.8, 2.8) (-2.5, 2.5)
95% (-3.5, 3.4) * (-3.2, 3.2) *
Germany/United Kingdom
90% (-3.9, 4.0) (-3.45, 3.40)
95% (-4.9, 5.0) (-4.35, 4.25) *
United States/France
90% (-3.10, 3.35) * (-3.30, 3.05)
95% (-4.05, 4.80) (-4.40, 4.15)
France/United Kingdom
90% (-2.24, 2.36) (-1.88, 2.10) *
95% (-3.01, 3.08) * (-2.34, 3.45)
France/Germany
90% (-3.25, 2.36) (-2.85, 2.65)
95% (-4.25, 3.25) * (-3.80, 3.45) *
Belgium/United Kingdom
90% (-2.46, 2.36) (-2.3, 2.1)
95% (-3.02, 2.92) * (-2.9, 2.7) *
Belgium/United States
90% (-2.65, 2.55) (-2.55, 2.40)
95% (-3.32, 3.22) * (-2.95, 3.00) *
Belgium/Germany
90% (-2.48, 2.18)
95% (-3.22, 3.02) *
Belgium/France
90% (-1.60, 1.60)
95% (-1.94, 1.92) *
Wholesale Price Index D3 F
United States/United Kingdom
90%
95%
United States/Germany
90% (-2.36, 2.1) 3.34
95% (-3.0, 2.6) * 4.41 *
Germany/United Kingdom
90% (-3.10, 3.15) * 2.84
95% (-3.90, 4.0) 3.60 *
United States/France
90% (-2.85, 2.45) 3.60
95% (-4.20, 3.15) 6.00 *
France/United Kingdom
90% (-2.01, 1.98) * 3.96
95% (-2.75, 2.69) 5.02 *
France/Germany
90% (-2.60, 2.25) 3.45
95% (-3.35, 3.00) * 4.70 *
Belgium/United Kingdom
90% (-2.2, 2.1) 4.55
95% (-2.8, 2.6) * 5.55 *
Belgium/United States
90% 3.71
95% 4.75 *
Belgium/Germany
90%
95%
Belgium/France
90%
95%
(a) * denotes significant dummy variable reported in Table 3.
Table 6. Bootstrap Confidence Interval for t-Stat and F-Stat for
Dummies (a)
Consumer Price D1 D2 D3
Index
Sweden/Germany
90% (-2.28, 2.91) (-2.40, 2.40)
95% (-2.86, 3.72) * (-3.00, 3.05) *
France/Sweden
90% (-2.60, 2.55) (-2.20, 2.12)
95% (-3.30, 3.20) (-2.66, 2.70)
France/Germany
90% (-2.40, 2.38) (-2.35, 2.35)
95% (-3.10, 3.02) * (-3.25, 3.05)
France/Belgium
90% (-3.15, 3.15)
95% (-4.15, 4.01)
Belgium/Sweden
90% (-2.10, 2.10) (-2.05, 2.10) (-2.04, 2.05)
95% (-2.60, 2.65) * (-2.60, 2.70) * (-2.60, 2.70) *
Belgium/Germany
90% (-2.80, 2.95) (-3.00, 2.80) (-2.95, 2.70)
95% (-3.46, 3.78) * (-3.84, 3.60) * (-3.60, 3.30) *
Consumer Price D4 D5 F
Index
Sweden/Germany
90% 3.25
95% 4.25 *
France/Sweden
90% 3.24
95% 4.32
France/Germany
90% 5.25
95% 7.40
France/Belgium
90%
95%
Belgium/Sweden
90% 3.60
95% 4.55 *
Belgium/Germany
90% (-2.80, 2.55) * (-2.55, 2.45) 2.50
95% (-3.45, 3.20) (-3.20, 3.00) 3.12 *
(a) * denotes significant dummy variable reported in Table 4.
Table 7. Estimated Half-Lives Shocks in Months for Annual Model
Shock
[??] 5% 10% 20% 30% 40% Linear
Real rare WPI
United States/United Kingdom -3.12 5 4 3 2 2 4.04
United States/Germany -2.52 4 4 4 3 2 3.24
Germany/United Kingdom -1.52 6 6 5 2 2 5.72
France/United Kingdom -11.8 5 4 3 I 0 3.22
France/United States -7.42 3 3 2 1 0 7.85
France/Germany -2.89 5 4 4 2 1 5.77
Belgium/United Kingdom -2.49 7 7 7 6 4 9.24
Belgium/France -2.98 5 5 5 4 2 9.66
Real rate CPI
Sweden/Germany -2.41 5 5 5 4 3 5.99
France/Sweden -13.7 4 4 2 1 0 5.24
France/Germany -7.17 3 3 2 2 2 4.08
France/Belgium -4.53 5 5 4 3 3 7.31
Belgium/Sweden -4.75 5 4 3 1 0 7.40
Table 8. Estimated Half-Lives Shocks in Months for Annual Model
with Dummies
Shock
[??] 5% 10% 20% 30% 40% Linear
Real rate WPI
United States/United Kingdom -4.28 5 4 3 2 1 2.51
United States/Germany -4.43 3 3 3 2 1 1.24
Germany/United Kingdom -8.5 3 3 2 1 0 1.25
France/United Kingdom -30.7 3 2 0 0 0 1.42
France/United States -34.1 2 2 0 0 0 2.54
France/Germany -27.5 2 2 1 0 0 1.42
Belgium/United Kingdom -186 1 0 0 0 0 0.83
Belgium/United States -0.88 6 5 4 3 2 1.68
Belgium/Germany -8.96 4 4 3 2 1 1.26
Belgium/France -56.9 1 0 0 0 0 1.43
Real rate CPI
Sweden/Germany -17.4 3 2 1 0 0 1.13
France/Germany -7.63 2 1 1 1 0 1.13
Belgium/Sweden -255 1 0 0 0 0 0.61
Belgium/Germany -20 2 2 1 0 0 1.07
(1) Even in high-frequency asset markets, the idea of heteregeneous
traders facing different capital constraints or percieved risk of
arbitrage has been employed to rationalize employment of the ESTAR
model. See, for example, Tse (2001) for arbitrage between stock and
index futures.
(2) Namely, how to reconcile the enormous short-run volatility of
real exchange rates with the extremely slow rate at which shocks appear
to damp out (in linear models, around 3-5 years, which seems far too
long to be explained by nominal rigidities).
(3) He suggests for instance that the sustained post-Bretton Woods
war appreciation of Japan's real exchange rate against the dollar
is consistent with the Balassa-Samuelson (BS) effects, in fact, he calls
it the canonical example of BS effects.
(4) We know from the analysis of Taylor (2001) that if the true
data generation process is nonlinear, then the use of the linear models
can severely underestimate the speed of adjustment, particularly if the
tow frequency data is temporally aggregated.
(5) We thank Hegwood and Papell for kindly providing as with the
data.
(6) A key property of some ESTAR models (also shared by some
threshold models) is that data simulated from them, although globally
mean-reverting, can appear to exhibit a unit root. As a consequence, the
test proposed in Froot and Rogoff (1995)--namely, that we impose unit
coefficients and test directly, employing unit root tests, whether PPP
deviations are mean-reverting--can have low power if the true
data-generating process is nonlinear.
(7) We note in this article, as pointed out by a referee, that we
test for nonlinear mean reversion while assuming that PPP holds. In this
article, it is assumed that there is reversion to a changing mean and
that what is being tested is the form of the reversion. As a
consequence, the standard errors reported for the ESTAR have classical
values. There is a common misconception that research on nonlinear
adjustment to PPP tests a unit root null against a nonlinear
mean-reverting alternative.
(8) This variation is not surprising if we assume that the true
data generating process (DGP) of the real exchange rate is generated at
a higher frequency, that is, monthly. In that case, Paya and Peel (2003)
show that temporal aggregation of the true monthly DGP into, for
instance, annual data induces additional autoregressive terms in the
ESTAR model.
(9) We observe from Equation 1 that when ([n.summation over (i=1)]
[[beta.sub.i] =1 if [??] = 0 PPP deviations follow a unit root.
(10) See Hegwood and Papell (2002) for an explanation of potential
causes of the different breaks. We recognize that the breaks were
obtained from estimates of a linear structure. Our Monte Carlo evidence
suggests the breaks are in the majority significant.
(11) In particular, for the WPI rates we removed the third dummy of
the Belgium/Germany, third dummy in the Belgium/U.S., fourth dummy in
the France/U.K., and the fourth dummy in the U.S./Germany rate. For the
CPI rates, we removed the first dummy of the France/Sweden rate and the
third dummy of the Sweden/Germany rate.
(12) The bootstrapped residuals were centered on zero and scaled.
The scaling factor is (n/n-k[)[??].sub.0.5].
(13) In particular, the first dummy of the Germany/U.K. WPI rate,
second dummy of the France/U.S. WPI rate, second dummy of the
France/U.K. WPI rate, second dummy of the France/Germany CPI rate, fifth
dummy of the Belgium/Germany rate, and both dummies of the France/Sweden
CPI rate.
(14) In particular, impulse responses produced by nonlinear models
are (i) history dependent, so they depend on initial conditions, (ii)
dependent on the size and sign of the current shock, and (iii) depend on
the future shocks as well. That is, nonlinear impulse responses
critically depend on the "past, present, and the future."
(15) For each available history, we use 300 repetitions (500
repetitions found similar result) to average out future shocks where
future shocks are drawn with replacement from the models'
residuals, and then we average the result across all histories. We set
to max{h} = 48.
(16) The France/Sweden and France/Belgium CPI exchange rates have
not been included in Table 8 because the dummy variables were not
jointly significant according to the bootstrap confidence interval
presented in Table 6. In the case of the France/ Germany CPI rate, we
include the dummy that appears significant under the bootstrap
confidence interval.
References
Acosta, Aparicio F.M., and Clive W.J. Granger. 1995. A linearity
test for near-unit root time series. Discussion Paper No. 95-12.
University of California San Diego, San Diego, CA.
Bai. Jushan, and Pierre Perron. 1998. Estimation and testing linear
models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica 66:47-78.
Balassa. Bela. 1964. The purchasing-power parity doctrine: A
reappraisal. Journal of Political Economy 72:584-96.
Berka. Martin. 2002. General equilibrium model of arbitrage trade
and real exchange rate persistence. Unpublished paper, University of
British Columbia.
Byers, David, and David A. Peel. 2003. A nonlinear time series with
misleading linear properties. Applied Economics Letters 10:47-51.
Canzoneri, Matthew B., Robert E. Cumby, and Behzad T. Diba. 1996.
Relative labor productivity and the real exchange rate in the long run:
Evidence for a panel of OECD countries. Journal of International
Economics 47:245-66.
Chinn, Menzie, and Louis Johnston. 1996. Real exchange levels,
productivity and demand shocks: Evidence from a panel of 14 countries.
NBER Working Paper No. 5709.
Cook, Chris, and John Stevenson. 1998. Longman handbook of modern
European history 1763-1997. 3rd edition. New York: Addison Wesley
Longman.
Diebold, Francis X., Steven Husted, and Mark Rush. 1991. Real
exchange rates under the gold standard. Journal of Political Economy,
99:1252-71.
Dumas, Bernard. 1992. Dynamic equilibrium and the real exchange
rate in a spatially separated world. Review of Financial Studies
5:153-80.
Eitrheim, Oyvind. and Timo Terasvirta. 1996. Testing the adequacy
of smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of Econometrics 74:59-75.
Froot, Kenneth A., and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995. Perspectives on PPP
and long-run real exchange rates. In Handbook of international
economies, Volume 3, edited by G.M. Grossman and K. Rogoff. Amsterdam:
North Holland, pp. 1647-87.
Granger, Clive W.J., and Timo Terasvirta. 1999. Ocasional
structural breaks and long memory. Discussion Paper No. 98-03.
University of California San Diego, San Diego, CA.
Hegwood, Natalie D., and David H. Papell. 2002. Purchasing power
parity under the Gold Standard. Southern Economic Journal 69:72-91.
Koop, Gary, Hashem Pesaran, and Simon M. Potter. 1996. Impulse
response analysis in nonlinear multivariate models. Journal of
Econometrics 74:119-47.
Lothian, James R., and Mark P. Taylor. 1996. Real exchange rate
behavior: The recent float from the perspective of the past two
centuries. Journal of Political Economy 104:488-507.
Michael, Panos, Robert Nobay, and David A. Peel. 1997. Transactions
costs and nonlinear adjustment in real exchange rates: An empirical
investigation. Journal of Political Economy 105:862-79.
Newey. Whitney, and Kenneth West. 1987. A simple positive
semi-definite, heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent
covariance matrix. Econometrica 55:703-8.
O'Connell, Paul, and Shang-Jin Wei. 1997. The bigger they are,
the harder they fall: How price differences between U.S. cities are
arbitraged. NBER Working Paper No. 6089.
Ozaki, Tohru. 1985. Nonlinear time series models and dynamical
systems. In Handbook of statistics V, edited by E.J. Hannah, P.R.
Krishnaiah. and M.M. Rao. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 2543.
Paya, Ivan, and David A. Peel. 2003. Temporal aggregation of an
ESTAR process: Some implications for PPP adjustments. Unpublished paper,
Cardiff Business School.
Paya, Ivan, Ioannis A. Venetis, and David A. Peel. 2003. Further
evidence on PPP adjusment speeds: The case of effective real exchange
rates and the EMS. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
65:421-38.
Peel. David A,. and Ioannis A. Venetis. 2002. Purchasing power
parity over two centuries: Trends and non-linearity. Applied Economics
35:609-17.
Perron, Pierre, and Timothy J. Vogelsang. 1992. Nonstationarity and
level shifts with an application to purchasing power parity. Journal of
Business and Economic Statistics 10:301-20.
Pippenger, Michael K., and Gregory Goering. 1993. A note on the
empirical power of unit root tests under threshold processes. Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 55:473-81.
Rogoff, Kenneth. 1996. The purchasing power parity puzzle. Journal
of Economic Literature 34:647-68.
Samuelson, Paul. 1964. Theoretical notes on trade problems. Review
of Economics and Statistics 46:145-54.
Sercu, Piet. Raman Uppal, and C. Van Hull. 1995. The exchange rate
in the presence of transactions costs: Implications for tests of
purchasing power parity. Journal of Finance 50:1309-19.
Taylor, Alan M. 2001. Potential pitfalls for the purchasing power
parity puzzle? Sampling and specification biases in mean-reversion tests
of the law of one price. Econometrica 69:473-98.
Taylor, Mark P., David A. Peel, and Lucio Sarno. 2001. Nonlinear
mean-reversion in real exchange rates: Toward a solution to the
purchasing power parity puzzles. International Economic Review
42:1015-42.
Terasvirta, Timo. 1994. Specification, estimation and evaluation of
smooth transition autoregressive models. Journal of the American
Statistical Association 89:208-18.
Tse. Yi. 2001. Index arbitrage with heterogeneous investors: A
smooth transition error correction analysis. Journal of Banking and
Finance 25:1829-55.
Venetis, Ioannis A., Ivan Paya. and David A. Peel. 2002. Do real
exchange rate "mean revert" to productivity? A nonlinear
approach. Unpublished paper, Cardiff Business School.
Ivan Paya, Departamento Fundamentos Analisis Economico, University
of Alicante, 03080 Alicante, Spain; E-mail ivanpaya@ merlin.fae.ua.es;
corresponding author.
David A. Peel, Lancaster University Management School, Lancaster,
LA1 4YX, UK; E-mail
[email protected].
The authors are grateful to participants of the Understanding
Evolving Macroeconomy Annual Conference, University College Oxford.
September 15-16 2003. The first author acknowledges financial support of
Instituto Valenciano Investigaciones Economicas (VIE).
Received June 2003: accepted December 2003.