Some evidence on the relationship between performance-related pay and the shape of the experience-earnings profile.
Sessions, John G.
1. Introduction and Background
In this paper we explore the shape of the experience-earnings
profile for individuals employed under different types of contracts:
fixed-wage, performance-related pay (PRP), and self-employment contracts. We follow Lazear (1979, 1981) and Lazear and Moore (1984) in
hypothesizing that the slope of the experience-earnings profile reflects
agency costs, and the reduction thereof, with increased agency costs
inducing steeper profiles. If monitoring costs are high, firms may
implement compensation schemes designed to encourage employees to
self-select behavior in the firms' interests. One such scheme
defers a substantial amount of compensation until the later years of
tenure. The resulting experience-earnings profile provides a penalty for
shirking (Lazear and Moore 1984).
We, therefore, presume that the profiles of workers employed under
fixed-wage contracts are steeper than those of self-employees for whom
the issue of agency does not arise because of the duality of principal
and owner (Lazear and Moore 1984). The interesting case is that of
workers employed under PRP. If such contracts represent a hybrid between
fixed-wage and self-employment, then one would expect their
experience-earnings profiles to lie somewhere between these two extreme
cases. Thus, PRP and a steep experience-earnings profile may be regarded
as substitute mechanisms for inducing employee effort.
The nature of the experience-earnings profile has important
implications for labor market behavior. If agency considerations
prevail, then issues arise concerning the credibility of long-term employment contracts--firms may have an incentive to replace expensive
"older" workers with cheaper "younger" recruits. The
shape of the experience-earnings profile may also influence decisions to
quit jobs. Experienced "generally" trained workers may face
more options in the labor market than their
"firm-specifically" trained counterparts. But both types of
worker may have more labor market options than those "older"
workers whose earnings reflect agency considerations.
We generalize Lazear and Moore (1984) by allowing for the
intermediate category of PRP, which enables us to further explore the
agency explanation behind the positive slope of the experience-earnings
profile. Our presumption is that all three employment contracts can be
nested in the form
[W.sub.j] = (1 - [[lambda].sub.j]) [bar.w] +
[[lambda].sub.j]f(e;[theta]), (1)
where j = fw, prp, se denotes "fixed-wage,"
"PRP," and "self-employment," respectively,
[w.sub.j] denotes total remuneration, [bar.w] the component of total
remuneration that is "fixed" (i.e., independent of worker
performance), and f(e; [theta]) some function mapping the relationship
between worker performance (i.e., effort), e, "uncertainty,"
[theta], and pay. (1) [[lambda].sub.j] represents the degree of equity
held by a worker in his/her enterprise, that is, the proportion of total
remuneration that is dependent on performance. We assume that for
fixed-wage employment, [[lambda].sub.fw] = 0; for PRP contracts,
[[lambda].sub.prp] [member of] (0, 1); and for self-employment,
[[lambda].sub.se] = 1. Our hypothesis is that the shape of the
experience-earnings profile depends critically on [[lambda].sub.j]. To
be sure, we predict that agency costs decline monotonically with
[[lambda].sub.j] such that the slope of the PRP earnings profile falls
between the zero-equity, fixed-wage, and 100% equity, self-employed profiles. (2)
2. Data and Methodology
Our empirical analysis draws on three British data sets: the
British Social Attitudes Surveys 1985, 1987, 1993, and 1996, the British
Household Panel Surveys 1991-1999, and the British Family Expenditure
Surveys 1997/98, 1998/99, and 1999/00.
The British Social Attitudes Surveys (BSAS) are an annual series of
cross-section surveys initiated by Social and Community Planning
Research in 1983. The sample comprises individuals, aged 18 and over,
living in private households whose addresses were on the electoral
registrar; 114 out of 650 Parliamentary constituencies in Great Britain were selected. A polling district was randomly selected from each
constituency with addresses being randomly chosen from each district.
The surveys conducted in 1985, 1987, 1993, and 1996 contained
questions relating to the presence of PRP: whether in the year of
interview the respondent had received some component of their total
remuneration in the form of: (i) a productivity-linked bonus scheme;
(ii) an annual bonus (at the employing organization's discretion);
(iii) a share ownership or share option scheme; or (iv) a profit-sharing scheme. Individuals who reported that they had participated in any of
the four schemes were labeled as PRP employees. (3) Selecting out all
male respondents in fixed-wage, PRP, or self-employment with complete
records rendered 1467, 783, and 491 individuals, respectively. (4)
Our second data set is based on the British Household Panel Survey
(BHPS). This is a random sample survey conducted by the Institute for
Social and Economic Research of each adult member of a nationally
representative sample of more than 5000 private households. For wave 1,
the interviews took place in 1991. The same individuals are
reinterviewed in successive waves.
We explore data from the 1991-1999 surveys. In the first wave
(1991), all individuals were asked whether their pay includes bonuses or
profit sharing, thereby enabling us to identify PRP employees. For the
period 1992-1995, this question was asked only to individuals who
changed their jobs. We, therefore, assume that individuals who did not
change job remain in their 1991 employment type. We specify an
unbalanced panel of data wherein the minimum number of times an
individual is in the sample is one and the maximum is nine. Our sample
comprises 4594 fixed-wage employees, 2806 PRP employees, and 1153
self-employees.
Our third data set is drawn from the Family Expenditure Survey
(FES) for Great Britain. This is a nationally representative survey that
has been conducted annually since 1957. Approximately 10,000 households
are selected each year to take part in the FES, and the average response
rate is approximately 70%.
We use data from the 1997-1998, 1998-1999, and 1999-2000 surveys.
(5) Our subsample comprises working males aged between 18 and 65 who are
either self-employed or employed under a fixed-wage contract or a
contract characterized by PRP. Those individuals classified as being
employed under a PRP contract were those in receipt of a
productivity-linked bonus, profit-related pay, dividends from employee
share ownership, an incentive bonus, or a performance-related bonus. Our
sample consists of 8405 male respondents comprising 5965 fixed-wage
employees, 1201 PRP employees, and 1239 self-employees.
It is apparent that there is some tension between our theoretical
and empirical definitions of PRP. The former defines PRP as any contract
in which current pay is related to current performance broadly defined.
Some jobs reward performance with a promotion and/or a salary increment rather than with an explicit bonus. Moreover, some bonus schemes may
also be used to identify "fast-track" employees, and for
these, a revelatory component may be in operation as the employer learns
more about a worker's skills and ability in the early years
following an initial hire. (6) The BHPS, but not the BSAS or FES, asks
specific questions relating to promotions and salary increments in each
year, and we, therefore, augment our BHPS empirical analysis by
including dummy variables to control for these factors. (7)
The empirical definitions of PRP in the three data sets are quite
explicit. The BSAS and FES adopt similarly broad definitions that
include productivity-linked and discretionary bonuses, share
ownership/options, and profit sharing. The BHPS focuses on just bonuses
(type not defined) and profit sharing. (8) Which definition is more
appropriate is largely a matter of interpretation, but our results are
broadly consistent across the three data sets.
Sample statistics of the key variables for each of the data sets
are set out in Table 1. (9) A common finding in all three data sets is
the relatively low earnings of self-employed respondents. The problems
of accurately measuring pay from self-employment are well documented
(see Eardley and Corden 1996; Hamilton 2000). Because our focus is on
the slope of the experience-earnings profile, measurement error is not
too problematic if the earnings of the self-employed are consistently
underreported.
Our analysis is based on a Mincerian earnings equation of the form:
1n [w.sub.ijt] = [X.sub.ijt][B.sub.j] + [[alpha].sub.j][E.sub.ijt]
+ [[beta].sub.j][E.sup.2.sub.ijt] + [[epsilon].sub.ijt], (2)
where [w.sub.ijt] represents the hourly earnings of an individual i
employed in employment type j at time t, with j = s, prp, se
representing the three employment categories. (10) [X.sub.ijt]
represents a vector of personal and workplace characteristics including
education, occupational status, and industrial affiliation, and
[E.sub.ijt] denotes labor force experience at time t, proxied by the
respondent's age at time t less his/her age when he/she completed
full-time education. (11) It is apparent that a first-best estimation of
Equation 2 would utilize a panel data source. We adopt such an approach
with the BHPS sample, which follows the same individuals across 1991 to
1999. In the case of the BSAS and FES analysis, we are obliged to use
pooled cross-section data. This is not too problematic: If we assume
that the vector of personal/ workplace characteristics is stable across
time then [X.sub.ijt] = [X.sub.ij], [for all] t. (12)
Estimation is further complicated on account of potential sample
selection bias. Our earnings data derive from observing a particular
employment contract (i.e., fixed-wage, PRP, or self-employment), and
there may be variables that affect both the probability of observing
such a contract and the return to any factors in the earnings equation.
To take account of such considerations, we control for sample selection
bias. Probit analysis with three discrete outcomes is used to model the
determination of Z, prob([Z.sub.i] = j), that is, the probability of
being in one of the three possible types of employment, which is then
used to calculate the standard inverse mills ratio term,
[[delta].sub.ijt]=[phi]([H.sub.ijt])/[PHI]([H.sub.ijt]), where
[H.sub.ijt] = [[PHI].sup.-1]([P.sub.ijt]), [P.sub.ijt] denotes the
predicted probability of individual i at time t being employed under
contract type j, [phi](.) represents the probability density function of
the standard normal distribution, and [PHI](.) represents the cumulative
density function of the standard normal distribution.
By incorporating [[delta].sub.ijt] into the wage regression, we
control for the possibility that particular types of individuals may be
employed under specific types of contract.
To explore the robustness of our findings, we experimented with
three alternative measures of labor market experience. First, for all
three data sets, we estimated age-earnings profiles. Second, for the
BSAS only (such information is not available in the BHPS or FES), we
estimated employer tenure-earnings profiles for fixed-wage and PRP
employees, making use of the question asked in 1993 and 1996: How long
have you been continuously employed by your present employer? And
finally, for the BHPS only, we estimated job tenure-earnings profiles,
making use of the following question: What was the date you started
working in your present position? This question is asked to all employed
respondents, whereas all self-employed respondents were asked, On what
date did you start doing your present job? By that I mean the beginning
of your current spell of doing the work you are doing now on a
self-employed basis? Thus, the responses to both questions are used to
calculate current job tenure for employees and self-employees.
3. Results
We estimate a standard quadratic Mincerian wage equation as
depicted by Equation 2. In the case of the cross-section data, we employ
standard ordinary least squares (OLS) techniques, whereas in the case of
the BHPS we have employed a random effects estimator. (13) We have
experimented with a number of combinations of explanatory variables as
well as changes to our set of overidentifying instruments in the
selection equation, and we have found the regressions to be generally
well specified and highly robust. (14) The selectivity terms suggest
that ignoring selection issues would have led to significant bias in the
estimated coefficients. In general, our findings accord with the
previous literature, suggesting a generally positive relationship
between earnings and education as well as a concave relationship between
earnings and experience. For brevity, in Tables 2 to 4, only one
specification, which includes both educational certificates and years of
education, is presented. (15) Tables 2, 3, and 4 present the results
relating to the BSAS, the BHPS, and the FES, respectively.
It is apparent that the least robust regressions are those for the
self-employed respondents. This is not surprising. Such workers will not
be motivated by Mincerian-type arguments to the same extent as their
employed counterparts and, under an (extreme) argument whereby the
earnings profile is a reflection of agency issues only, would not face
the necessity of rewarding themselves with an upward sloping profile to
ensure efficient effort over their life cycle (Lazear and Moore 1984).
It is apparent from Tables 2 to 4 that the estimated coefficients
on the various labor force experience proxies (i.e., Age, Years in Labor
Force, Job Tenure, and Employer Tenure) support our theoretical
assumption that the slope of the earnings profile for PRP workers lies
between those of their fixed-wage and self-employed counterparts. In
terms of the BSAS and FES (Tables 2 and 4), the three profiles are
significantly different from one another at the 1% level of significance
irrespective of the experience proxy used. In terms of the BHPS (Table
3), the three profiles are significantly different from one another at
the 1% level of significance when experience is proxied by age or job
tenure, whereas the profiles associated with PRP and self-employment
(but not fixed wage and PRP) are significantly different from each other
at the 1% level when experience is proxied by years in the labor force.
Figures 1 to 5 present the estimated experience-earnings profiles for
each set of results, with--for reasons of brevity--the exception of the
age--earnings profiles. (16)
Our BHPS results also highlight the positive relationship between
the dummy variable indicating whether the respondent had been promoted
in the current year (Promotion) and the earnings of fixed-wage and PRP
workers, and between the incremental pay scale dummy variable (Annual
Increment) and the earnings of PRP workers. We experimented with
interacting Annual Increment and Promotion with the various experience
proxies. These results confirm the validity of our findings regarding
the experience-earnings profiles. (17) Moreover, in the case of the
Promotion variable, they also cast additional light on the roles played
by human capital and agency. Interacting the various experience proxies
with Promotion suggested that the ordering of the three profiles was not
affected by whether respondents had enjoyed a promotion in the current
year. Indeed, we found that the difference in the three slopes, for
example, the agency effect was actually more pronounced for those
periods that fell in between promotions. Such findings support the
argument that human capital may be more relevant to obtaining
promotions, whereas agency effects appear to operate primarily between
promotions. (18)
Lambda as a Continuous Variable
The FES and the BHPS (1997-1999) record the total amount of
remuneration received in the form of the bonus. In Equation 1, total
remuneration is split into a fixed and a variable component, the
division depending on the size of [lambda]. For the FES and the BHPS, we
can, therefore, proxy [lambda] by calculating the ratio of bonus to
total pay:
[??] = Bonus Pay/Total Pay = [lambda]f(e; [theta])/(1 -
[lambda][bar.w] + [lambda]f(e; [theta])
Sample statistics for both the FES and BHPS samples relating to
[lambda] are set out in Table 5.
Our assumption is that a higher value of [lambda] raises the
expected cost of early-term shirking on the part of the worker and
thereby leads to a flattening of the experience-earnings profile. To
investigate this, we ran three earnings regressions pooling the
self-employed, the PRP employees, and the fixed-wage employees together
for each of the two data sets (see Tables 6 and 7). In the case of the
FES, we conduct OLS analysis, whereas in the case of the BLIPS, we adopt
a random effects approach given the panel element to the data. Once
again, an unbalanced panel is analyzed in which the minimum (maximum)
number of times an individual is in the sample is one (three).
Specification 1 illustrates that higher values of [lambda] are
associated with significantly lower earnings--this effect is probably
reflecting the presence of self-employed workers within our sample.
Specifications 2 and 3 include an interaction between experience and
[lambda]. Our results suggest that higher levels of [??] are indeed
associated with a flattening of the experience-earnings profile. In the
case of the FES, our findings suggest that as the estimated coefficient of [??] moves from zero to unity, the annual rate of return (in terms of
log hourly earnings) to an additional year of labor market experience
falls from just under 5% to less than 1%. To summarize, these findings
provide further support for the hypothesis that the slope of the
experience-earnings profile is influenced by both the presence and
extent of PRP.
Training
Our results support the hypothesis that experience-earnings
profiles reflect agency considerations, with PRP profiles generally
lying somewhere between fixed-wage and self-employed profiles.
Furthermore, we would argue that our findings are relatively robust
given that we have used three different data sets (including both
cross-section and panel data) as well as exploring our theoretical
assumptions via two different approaches and specifying alternative
measures of experience. However, it is apparent that an alternative
explanation can be offered. It may be the case that PRP workers
undertake relatively less training than their fixed-wage counterparts,
implying relatively high (low) starting (future) earnings and thus
flatter profiles. It is difficult to rationalize such an argument; it
might seem that workers remunerated under PRP are, if anything, more
likely to respond to investments in training than their fixed-wage
counterparts. We investigated the relative likelihood of fixed-wage and
PRP respondents having undertaken some form of training at their place
of work. Two of our three data sets (BSAS and BHPS) contained
information regarding whether respondents had received training.
The BSAS survey for 1987 asked respondents whether, in the two
years preceding the survey interview, they had been (i) asked to do
anything just for practice in order to learn the work; (ii) given any
special talks or lectures about the work; (iii) placed with more
experienced people to see how the work should be done; (iv) sent around
to different parts of the organization to see how the work is done; (v)
asked to read things to help learn about the work; (vi) taught or
trained by anyone while actually doing the work; (vii) sent on any
courses to introduce new methods of working. We created two variables: a
dummy variable (Train) that takes the value of one if the respondent
answered "yes" to any of these questions and an index (Trains)
that equals the number of these questions to which the respondent had
answered "yes" to the various types of training. Thus, Train
represents a binary dummy variable indicating whether or not an
individual has received any training, and Trains represents an index,
which ranges from 0 to 7, indicating the number of types of training
undertaken. We are, therefore, able to focus on both the incidence
(Train) and the intensity of training (Trains).
Participants in the BHPS were asked whether in the preceding year
they had participated in any off-the-job education or training. Relevant
summary statistics for the training variables for both data sets are set
out in Table 8. Because our focus is on the incidence of training at
relatively low levels of experience, we present summary statistics for
four levels of experience. In the case of the BSAS, it appears that PRP
employees do receive less training than their fixed-wage counterparts.
This finding may be taken as support for a training effect. The
situation is reversed, however, at the lowest category of experience,
which arguably is the focus of our attention. In the case of the BHPS,
the support for the training explanation is less clear-cut, with PRP
employees, in general, being characterized by a higher incidence of
training.
We explore the incidence and intensity of training across PRP and
fixed-wage employees by conducting probit analysis (dependent variable
Train) and ordered probit analysis (dependent variable Trains). Our
findings are set out in Table 9. In the case of the BSAS, the PRP dummy
variable has no effect on the probability that the respondent had so
engaged in training. The probability of training was, however,
significantly negatively related to the respondent's experience in
the labor market, perhaps reflecting the fact that most training is
undertaken by relatively younger workers. To ascertain whether there was
any interaction between such experience and the PRP dummy, we ran a
second specification of the dichotomous and ordered probit models, this
time including a series of experience-PRP interaction terms such as
Experience less than 5 years*PRP; Experience more than 5 years but less
than 10 years*PRP; Experience more than 10 years but less than 20
years*PRP; and Experience more than 20 years*PRP. The coefficients on
these terms were insignificant in the dichotomous probit, but those on
the last three were significantly negative in the ordered probit. Thus,
it does appear that more experienced workers receive relatively less
training than their non-PRP counterparts, ceteris paribus. It should be
noted, however, that we are primarily interested in the incidence of
training at the lower level of experience.
We repeated this analysis for the BHPS. In the case of the panel
data set, the results from employing a random effects probit estimator
suggest that PRP employees are more likely to receive training, which
provides evidence contrary to the training explanation. Our results are,
therefore, somewhat mixed, and the BSAS findings allude to the
possibility that differences in the experience-earnings profile may not
be driven solely by agency consideration. But these findings are not
reflected in the BHPS.
4. Final Comments
This paper has focused on the relationship between
experience--earnings profiles and the degree of worker equity within an
enterprise. We further explore Lazear and Moore's (1984) thesis that the nature of the profile reflects agency considerations by
focusing not only on those workers with zero or 100% equity (i.e.,
fixed-wage and self-employed workers, respectively) but also on those
with a fractional level of equity, for example, workers remunerated
under some form of PRP. Our presumption is that PRP employees face an
intermediate level of agency costs and as such require an intermediate
profile. Our empirical analysis of three British data sets offers
support for this view.
Our results might be interpreted as support for the argument that
the shape of the experience-earnings profile reflects agency
considerations. As such, they highlight important issues pertaining to
the credibility of long-term employment contracts because employers may
be tempted to replace experienced workers with less costly, but equally
productive, novices. But the latter will not remain "young"
forever, and whether they will be inclined to work for a firm that is
unable to guarantee them employment in their dotage is an open question.
References
Blinder, Alan S. (ed.). 1990. Paying for productivity: A look at
the evidence. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.
Booth, Alison L., and Jeff Frank. 1999. Earnings, productivity and
performance-related may. Journal of Labor Economics 17:447-63.
Eardley, Tony, and Anne Corden. 1996. Self-employed earnings and
income distribution: Problems of measurement. Social Policy Report No.
5, Social Policy Research Unit, University of York.
Hamilton, Barton H. 2000. Does entrepreneurship pay? An empirical
analysis of the returns to self-employment. Journal of Political Economy
108:604-31.
Jovanovic, Boyan. 1979. Job matching and the theory of turnover.
Journal of Political Economy 87:1972-90.
Lazear, Edward P. 1979. Why is there mandatory retirement? Journal
of Political Economy 87:1261-84.
Lazear, Edward P. 1981. Agency, earnings profiles, productivity and
hours restrictions. American Economic Review 71:606-20.
Lazear, Edward P., and Robert L. Moore. 1984. Incentives,
productivity and labor contracts. Quarterly Journal of Economics 99:275-95.
Murphy, Kevin M., and Finis Welch. 1990. Empirical age-earnings
profiles. Journal of Labor Economics 8:202-29.
Sarah Brown, Department of Economics, University of Sheffield,
Sheffield S1 4DT, England; E-mail
[email protected];
corresponding author. and John G. Sessions, Department of Economics and
Intemational Development, University of Bath, Bath BA2 7AY, England;
E-mail
[email protected].
We are particularly grateful to two anonymous referees for
excellent comments. We are grateful to the Data Archive at the
University of Essex for supplying the British Social Attitudes Surveys
1985, 1987, 1993, and 1996, the British Household Panel Surveys
1991-1999, and the Family Expenditure Surveys 1997/98, 1998199, and
1999/00. Our analysis has benefited from discussions with Saul Estrin,
Gianni De Fraja, and Stephen Pudney. Helpful comments were also received
from seminar participants at the Universities of Brunei, Essex, Kent,
Lancaster, Leicester, and Sheffield. The normal disclaimer applies.
Received June 2004; accepted June 2005.
(1) Uncertainty may be related, for example, to conditions in the
output market.
(2) Equation 1 defines PRP as any contract in which current pay is
related to worker performance broadly defined. The practical operation
of such schemes is certainly more nuanced; see, for example, Blinder
(1990), Booth and Frank (1999).
(3) Clearly, the four schemes are diverse in nature and, as such,
create different incentives. Ideally, we would classify individuals
according to the type of PRP scheme. Such an approach would be somewhat
problematic, however, because of the low number of observations in each
scheme.
(4) In order to abstract from issues related to labor market
participation, we focus on male employees only.
(5) Before this period, the dataset had a different structure, and
some of the variables required for our analysis are not available.
(6) We are grateful to an anonymous referee for highlighting this
point.
(7) The specific questions are: Promotion--If you have been
promoted or changed grades, please give me the date of that change;
Annual Increment--Some people can normally expect their pay to rise
every year by moving to the next point on the scale as well as receiving
negotiated pay rises. Are you paid on this type of incremental scale?
Zero-one dummy variables were created from both of these questions.
(8) There is also some distinction between the BSAS/FES and BHPS
definitions of self-employment. In the BSAS and FES, individuals are
categorized according to the following question: In your main job, are
you an employee or a self-employee? In the BHPS, individuals are asked
to specify their current labor force status, with options including
"paid employment," "selfemployment,"
"unemployed," "retired," "on maternity
leave," "in family care," "full-time student,"
"long-term sick/ disabled," "on a government training
scheme," and "other."
(9) A small number of individuals with more than one job,
individuals employed by the armed forces, and agricultural workers were
excluded from the analysis of each data set.
(10) The definition of hourly earnings differs across our three
data sets according to the survey questions asked of respondents. For
the BHPS, hourly earnings are defined as labor income in the previous
month divided by the number of hours normally worked per month. For the
BSAS, they are defined as the respondent's gross annual earnings
divided by the number of hours the respondent works per week multiplied by 52. For the FES, hourly employed earnings are defined as the normal
gross weekly wage divided by usual weekly hours, whereas hourly
self-employed earnings are defined as normal gross income from
self-employment divided by usual weekly hours worked.
(11) Following Murphy and Welch (1990), we also experimented with
cubic and quartic experience terms; the results are available on
request.
(12) However, where a good match has been made between the employer
and the employee, earnings will be relatively high, and tenure will be
relatively long (Jovanovic 1979). Cross-sectional data, which contain no
information about the quality of a job match, may bias estimates of the
returns to job tenure.
(13) The fixed-effects estimation results are available from the
authors by request.
(14) The overidentifying instruments for the underlying sample
selection model included region of residence and a variety of
demographic controls (ethnicity, marital status, number of children,
previous spells of unemployment, and private education). The sample
selection models, which were estimated using probit analysis with three
discrete outcomes, are generally well specified. For reasons of brevity,
the sample selection results are not presented here but are available
from the authors on request. The results reported in Tables 2 to 4 have
all been corrected for sample selection bias (uncorrected results are
also available on request).
(15) As pointed out by an anonymous referee, the shape of the
earnings profiles may be influenced by trade union membership,
unionization of the workplace, and employment in the public sector. Our
results are robust to the inclusion of such controls.
(16) Because we are primarily interested in the relative slopes of
the earnings profiles, the intercept terms in Figures 1 to 5 have been
set to zero.
(17) The results are available on request.
(18) We are grateful to an anonymous referee for highlighting such
issues.
Table 1. Summary Statistics: Key Variables
Fixed-Wage
(N = 1467)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
British Social Attitudes Surveys 1985, 1987, 1993, 1996
Log hourly earnings 1.716 0.619
Years in labor force (YILF) 21.722 12.694
Age 38.644 11.902
Employer tenure (a) 9.227 11.505
Years of education 11.941 2.191
Degree 0.192 0.394
Further education 0.179 0.384
A level 0.141 0.348
GCSE grades A to C 0.197 0.398
GCSE grades below C 0.065 0.247
Other qualification 0.013 0.113
Fixed-Wage
(N = 14,284)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
British Household Panel Survey 1991-1999
Log hourly earnings 1.926 0.517
Years in labor force (YILF) 24.820 12.435
Years of education 13.224 4.018
Job tenure 4.944 6.451
Age 38.088 11.568
Annual increment 0.294 0.455
Promotion 0.053 0.224
Degree 0.177 0.381
Further education 0.241 0.428
A level 0.144 0.351
GCSE grades A to C 0.195 0.396
GCSE grades below C 0.195 0.396
Other qualification 0.035 0.185
Fixed-Wage
(N = 5965)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
Family Expenditure Survey 1997/98, 1998/99, and 1999/00
Log hourly earnings 2.120 0.564
Years in labor force (YILF) 22.283 12.413
Age 39.644 11.618
Years of education 12.361 2.777
Degree 0.224 0.417
Further education/A level 0.192 0.394
GCSE 0.365 0.482
Less than GCSE 0.218 0.413
PRP (N = 783)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
British Social Attitudes Surveys 1985, 1987, 1993, 1996
Log hourly earnings 1.771 0.610
Years in labor force (YILF) 22.253 12.325
Age 38.789 11.643
Employer tenure (a) 10.757 10.713
Years of education 11.540 1.885
Degree 0.102 0.303
Further education 0.171 0.377
A level 0.160 0.367
GCSE grades A to C 0.223 0.417
GCSE grades below C 0.089 0.286
Other qualification 0.010 0.101
PRP (N = 6212)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
British Household Panel Survey 1991-1999
Log hourly earnings 2.029 0.515
Years in labor force (YILF) 23.588 11.754
Years of education 13.214 3.485
Job tenure 4.468 6.106
Age 36.830 11.005
Annual increment 0.418 0.493
Promotion 0.113 0.316
Degree 0.159 0.366
Further education 0.278 0.448
A level 0.160 0.366
GCSE grades A to C 0.206 0.404
GCSE grades below C 0.054 0.225
Other qualification 0.032 0.176
PRP (N = 1201)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
Family Expenditure Survey 1997/98, 1998/99, and 1999/00
Log hourly earnings 2.492 0.574
Years in labor force (YILF) 21.767 11.247
Age 39.493 10.376
Years of education 12.726 2.735
Degree 0.277 0.448
Further education/A level 0.216 0.412
GCSE 0.357 0.479
Less than GCSE 0.149 0.356
Self-Employed
(N = 491)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
British Social Attitudes Surveys 1985, 1987, 1993, 1996
Log hourly earnings 1.613 0.802
Years in labor force (YILF) 25.193 12.398
Age 41.433 12.258
Employer tenure (a) -- --
Years of education 11.566 1.968
Degree 0.112 0.316
Further education 0.147 0.354
A level 0.175 0.380
GCSE grades A to C 0.220 0.415
GCSE grades below C 0.104 0.305
Other qualification 0.016 0.127
Self-Employed
(N = 3716)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
British Household Panel Survey 1991-1999
Log hourly earnings 1.855 0.842
Years in labor force (YILF) 29.939 11.872
Years of education 12.925 3.933
Job tenure 8.409 8.544
Age 42.903 11.078
Annual increment -- --
Promotion -- --
Degree 0.120 0.325
Further education 0.249 0.432
A level 0.126 0.332
GCSE grades A to C 0.222 0.416
GCSE grades below C 0.044 0.205
Other qualification 0.047 0.212
Self-Employed
(N = 1239)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
Family Expenditure Survey 1997/98, 1998/99, and 1999/00
Log hourly earnings 1.601 1.085
Years in labor force (YILF) 27.195 11.104
Age 44.320 10.535
Years of education 12.125 2.810
Degree 0.194 0.395
Further education/A level 0.157 0.364
GCSE 0.362 0.481
Less than GCSE 0.287 0.453
(a) Figures relate to 1993 and 1996 only because this information
was provided only in these years.
Table 2. British Social Attitudes Survey 1985, 1987, 1993, 1996:
Dependent Variable, Log Hourly Earnings
Fixed-Wage
Spec. A
Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0675 9.93 *
[Age.sup.2] -0.0007 -8.47 *
YILF -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- --
Employer tenure -- --
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -- --
Years of education 0.0317 3.47 *
Selectivity term 0.0088 0.13
Constant -1.2737 -6.40 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 48.2
[R.sup.2] 0.5797
F statistic [87.80.sub.(24, 1442)]
Number of obs. 1467
Fixed-Wage
Spec. B
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- --
YILF 0.0483 13.38 *
[YILF.sup.2] -0.0008 10.57 *
Employer tenure -- --
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -- --
Years of education 0.0439 4.64 *
Selectivity term -0.2068 -2.97 *
Constant -0.3485 -2.08
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 30.2
[R.sup.2] 0.5675
F statistic [87.50.sub.(24, 1442)]
Number of obs. 1467
Fixed-Wage
Spec. C
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- --
YILF -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- --
Employer tenure 0.0234 8.32 *
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -0.0003 -4.85 *
Years of education 0.0104 0.90
Selectivity term 0.0740 0.93
Constant 1.0783 5.64 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 39.0
[R.sup.2] 0.4541
F statistic [30.76.sub.(22, 801)]
Number of obs. 1467
PRP
Spec. A
Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0551 5.97*
[Age.sup.2] -0.0006 -4.86*
YILF -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- --
Employer tenure -- --
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -- --
Years of education 0.0301 2.54
Selectivity term -0.4043 -3.97 *
Constant -0.2468 -0.74
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 45.9
[R.sup.2] 0.6499
F statistic [64.80.sub.(24, 758)]
Number of obs. 783
PRP
Spec. B
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- --
YILF 0.0360 7.36*
[YILF.sup.2] -0.0005 -5.25*
Employer tenure -- --
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -- --
Years of education 0.0421 3.38 *
Selectivity term -0.3600 -4.50 *
Constant 0.3199 1.28
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 36.0
[R.sup.2] 0.651
F statistic [71.66.sub.(24, 758)]
Number of obs. 783
PRP
Spec. C
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- --
YILF -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- --
Employer tenure 0.0159 3.73 *
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -0.0002 -3.67 *
Years of education 0.0315 1.66
Selectivity term -0.2590 -2.48
Constant 1.5331 3.93 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 39.8
[R.sup.2] 0.434
F statistic [17.22.sub.(22, 335)]
Number of obs. 783
Self-
Employed
Spec. A
Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0171 0.80
[Age.sup.2] -0.0001 -0.51
YILF -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- --
Employer tenure -- --
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -- --
Years of education 0.0647 1.52
Selectivity term 0.8313 10.90 *
Constant 0.4793 0.54
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 85.5
[R.sup.2] 0.6882
F statistic [120.16.sub.(24, 466)]
Number of obs. 491
Self-
Employed
Spec. B
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- --
YILF 0.0175 1.73
[YILF.sup.2] -0.0002 -1.08
Employer tenure -- --
Employer [tenure.sup.2] -- --
Years of education 0.0241 0.73
Selectivity term 0.2151 2.12
Constant 0.7479 1.07
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (years) 74
[R.sup.2] 0.303
F statistic [16.99.sub.(24, 466)]
Number of obs. 491
Highest education certificates: Degree, Further education, A level,
GCSE grades A-C, GCSE grades below C, Other qualification.
Occupation dummies: Professional, Other nonmanual, Skilled manual,
Semiskilled, Unskilled manual.
Industry dummies: Energy, Metal extraction, Metal goods, Other
manufacturing, Construction, Distribution, Transport and
communications, Banking, Other services.
Robust standard errors are reported.
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of age and age
squared across the PRP (self-employed) and fixed-wage (PRP) wage
equations led to a test statistic of 7.23 (8.67).
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of YILF and
YILF squared across the PRP (self-employed) and fixed-wage (PRP)
wage equations led to a test statistic of 7.10 (8.46).
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of Employer tenure
and Employer tenure squared across the PRP and fixed-wage wage
equations led to a test statistic of 6.25.
* Statistically significant at the 1 % level for a two-tailed test.
Table 3. British Household Panel Survey: 1991-1999:
Dependent Variable, Log Hourly Earnings
Fixed-Wage
Spec. A Spec. B
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0895 35.29 * -- --
[Age.sup.2] -0.0010 -30.83 * -- --
YILF -- -- 0.0578 37.00 *
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- -0.0008 -30.27 *
Job tenure -- -- -- --
Job [tenure.sup.2] -- -- -- --
Years of
education -0.0007 -0.44 0.0155 9.13 *
Selectivity term -0.1025 -10.58 * -0.1059 -10.92 *
Promotion 0.0284 2.61 * 0.0292 2.68 *
Annual increment 0.0076 1.19 0.0078 1.22
Constant -0.2252 -4.19 * 0.6561 18.33 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation
dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
Turning point (yr) 44.8 36.3
[R.sub.2] within 0.0780 0.0749
[R.sub.2] between 0.4186 0.4196
[R.sub.2] overall 0.3926 0.3918
Wald chi-square [4145.sub.30] [4124.sub.30]
Number of obs. 14,284 14,284
Nos. of groups 4594 4594
Fixed-Wage PRP
Spec. C Spec. A
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age -- -- 0.0821 21.99 *
[Age.sup.2] -- -- -0.0009 -18.90 *
YILF -- -- -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- -- --
Job tenure 0.0192 15.00 * -- --
Job [tenure.sup.2] -0.0005 -9.73 * -- --
Years of
education 0.0016 0.93 0.0001 0.04
Selectivity term -0.0676 -6.79 * 0.0457 2.85 *
Promotion 0.0661 5.68 * 0.4917 4.17 *
Annual increment 0.0011 0.17 0.0191 2.24
Constant 1.5417 53.44 * -0.0901 -1.05
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation
dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
Turning point (yr) 19.2 45.6
[R.sub.2] within 0.0356 0.1153
[R.sub.2] between 0.348 0.4284
[R.sub.2] overall 0.3269 0.4206
Wald chi-square [2507.sub.30] [2538.sub.30]
Number of obs. 14,284 6212
Nos. of groups 4594 2806
PRP PRP
Spec. B Spec. C
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age -- -- -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- -- -- --
YILF 0.0542 23.72 * -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -0.0008 -19.02 * -- --
Job tenure -- -- 0.0151 7.18 *
Job [tenure.sup.2] -- -- -0.0003 -3.88 *
Years of
education 0.0147 6.17 * 0.0017 0.72
Selectivity term 0.0476 2.96 * -0.0099 -0.59
Promotion 0.0500 4.24 * 0.0777 5.97 *
Annual increment 0.0195 2.29 0.0030 0.34
Constant 0.7021 11.69 * 1.6222 33.70 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation
dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
Turning point (yr) 33.9 25.2
[R.sub.2] within 0.1152 0.057
[R.sub.2] between 0.4304 0.3618
[R.sub.2] overall 0.4195 0.3536
Wald chi-square [2553.sub.30] [1668.sub.30]
Number of obs. 6212 6212
Nos. of groups 2806 2806
Self-Employed Self-Employed
Spec. A Spec. B
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0607 2.26 -- --
[Age.sup.2] -0.0007 -2.33 -- --
YILF -- -- 0.0336 1.96
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- -0.0006 -2.11
Job tenure -- -- -- --
Job [tenure.sup.2] -- -- -- --
Years of
education -0.0086 -0.58 -0.0064 -0.41
Selectivity term 0.0019 0.03 0.0046 0.06
Promotion -- -- -- --
Annual increment -- -- -- --
Constant -0.1138 -0.18 0.6329 1.45
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation
dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
Turning point (yr) 43.4 28
[R.sub.2] within 0.0099 0.0097
[R.sub.2] between 0.0353 0.0345
[R.sub.2] overall 0.0381 0.0389
Wald chi-square [68.45.sub.28] [67.49.sub.28]
Number of obs. 3716 3716
Nos. of groups 1153 1153
Self-Employed
Spec. C
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- --
YILF -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- --
Job tenure 0.0022 0.22
Job [tenure.sup.2] 0.0002 0.80
Years of
education -0.0059 -0.40
Selectivity term 0.0362 0.51
Promotion -- --
Annual increment -- --
Constant 0.9139 3.08 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation
dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
Turning point (yr) 5.5
[R.sub.2] within 0.0101
[R.sub.2] between 0.0337
[R.sub.2] overall 0.0383
Wald chi-square [67.82.sub.28]
Number of obs. 3716
Nos. of groups 1153
Highest education certificates: Degree, Further education,
A level, GCSE grades A to C, GCSE grades below C, Other qualification.
Occupation dummies: Managerial, Professional, Intermediate nonmanual,
Sales, Clerical, Personal services, Skilled manual, Semiskilled manual,
Unskilled manual.
Industry dummies: Energy, Extraction, Engineering, Manufacturing,
Construction, Distribution, Transport, Storage and communication,
Finance, Other nonmanufacturing.
Robust standard errors are reported.
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of age and age
squared across the PRP (self-employed) and fixed-wage (PRP) wage
equations led to a test statistic of 18.37 (126.76).
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of YILF and YILF
squared across the PRP (self-employed) and fixed-wage (PRP) wage
equations led to a test statistic of 1.82 (18.08).
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of job tenure
and job tenure squared across the PRP (self-employed) and
fixed wage (PRP) wage equations led to a test statistic of
12.30 (40.98).
* Statistically significant at the 1% level for a two-tailed test.
Table 4. Family Expenditure Survey 1997/98, 1998/99, and 1999/00:
Dependent Variable, Log Hourly Earnings
Fixed-Wage
Spec. A Spec. B
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0677 15.59 * -- --
[Age.sup.2] -0.0007 -14.28 * -- --
YILF -- -- 0.0422 15.44 *
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- -0.0007 -14.36 *
Years of education 0.0160 2.10 0.0311 4.33 *
Selectivity term 0.1679 2.99 * 0.1956 3.04 *
Constant 0.7400 6.54 * 1.5724 17.09 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
Turning point (years) 47.9 30.1
[R.sup.2] 0.3306 0.3304
F statistic [141.13.sub. [143.52.sub.
(25, 5939)] (25, 5939)]
Number of obs. 5965 5965
PRP
Spec. A Spec. B
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0553 5.27 * -- --
[Age.sup.2] -0.0005 -3.77 * -- --
YILF -- -- 0.0380 7.21 *
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- -0.0005 -4.34 *
Years of education 0.0412 3.15 * 0.0610 4.66 *
Selectivity term -0.4378 -4.15 * -0.4896 -4.47 *
Constant 1.3877 4.02 * 2.0280 8.20 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
Turning point (years) 55.3 38.0
[R.sup.2] 0.4356 0.4430
F statistic [33.48.sub. [35.88.sub.
(25, 1201)] (25, 1201)]
Number of obs. 1201 1201
Self-Employed
Spec. A Spec. B
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age -0.0019 -0.06 -- --
[Age.sup.2] -0.0001 -0.40 -- --
YILF -- -- -0.024 -1.31
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- 0.0001 0.47
Years of education -0.0162 -0.68 -0.0388 -1.53
Selectivity term -0.403 -1.57 -0.6098 -2.44
Constant 3.4795 2.61 * 4.4272 4.30 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
Turning point (years) 9.5 120.0
[R.sup.2] 0.3306 0.1522
F statistic [141.13.sub. [10.26.sub.
(24, 1214)] (24, 1214)]
Number of obs. 1239 1239
Highest education certificates: Degree, Further education, A level,
GCSE grades A-C, GCSE grades below C, Other qualification.
Occupation dummies: Professional, Other nonmanual, Skilled manual,
Semiskilled, Unskilled manual.
Industry dummies: Energy, Metal extraction, Metal goods, Other
manufacturing, Construction, Distribution, Transport and
communications, Banking, Other services.
Robust standard errors are reported.
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of age and age
squared across the PRP (self-employed) and fixed-wage (PRP) wage
equations led to a test statistic of 56.02 (163.98).
Tests of equality of the estimated coefficients of YILF and YILF
squared across the PRP (self-employed) and fixed-wage (PRP) wage
equations led to a test statistic of 68.71 (345.83).
* Statistically significant at the 1% level for a two-tailed test.
Table 5. Lambda ([??]) Summary Statistics
Family Expenditure Survey 1997/98,
1998/99, 1999/00
[??] All Workers PRP Workers
Mean 0.152 0.054
Standard deviation 0.349 0.069
Minimum 0.000 9.28 x [10.sup.-6]
Maximum 1.000 0.476
Observations 8405 1201
British Household Panel
Survey 1997-1999
[??] All Workers PRP Workers
Mean 0.234 0.302
Standard deviation 0.364 0.223
Minimum 0.000 0.001
Maximum 1.000 0.981
Observations 9187 2840
Table 6. Continuous Lambda, FES 1997/98, 1998/99, 1999/00:
Dependent Variable, Log Hourly Earnings
Spec. 1 Spec. 2
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0755 18.08 * 0.0753 19.06 *
[Age.sup.2] -0.0008 -15.75 * -0.0008 -16.71 *
YILF -- -- -- --
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- -- --
Lambda -0.5354 -16.81 * -- --
Lambda * age -- -- -0.0193 -5.69 *
Lambda * [age.sup.2] -- -- 0.0002 2.21
Lambda * YILF -- -- -- --
Lambda * [YILF.sup.2] -- -- -- --
Years of education 0.0109 1.56 0.0112 1.60
Constant 0.8587 7.21 * 0.8444 7.23 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
[R.sup.2] 0.3071 0.3088
F statistic [154.92.sub. [152.53.sub.
(25, 8379)] (26, 8378)]
Nos. of obs. 8405 8405
Spec. 3 Spec. 4
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0783 21.06 * -- --
[Age.sup.2] -0.0008 -18.45 * -- --
YILF -- -- 0.0457 20.48 *
[YILF.sup.2] -- -- -0.0008 -17.03 *
Lambda 0.6085 1.37 -0.5566 -17.51 *
Lambda * age -0.0478 -2.22 -- --
Lambda * [age.sup.2] 0.0005 1.88 -- --
Lambda * YILF -- -- -- --
Lambda * [YILF.sup.2] -- -- -- --
Years of education 0.0111 1.58 0.0257 3.78 *
Constant 0.7882 6.94 * 1.826 19.36 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
[R.sup.2] 0.3088 0.3077
F statistic [152.53.sub. [[156.21.sub.
(26, 8378)] (25, 8379)]
Nos. of obs. 8405 8405
Spec. 5 Spec. 6
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Age -- -- -- --
[Age.sup.2] -- -- -- --
YILF 0.0488 22.77 * 0.0489 23.19 *
[YILF.sup.2] -0.0008 -19.29 * -0.0008 -19.57 *
Lambda -- -- 0.0259 0.19
Lambda * age -- -- -- --
Lambda * [age.sup.2] -- -- -- --
Lambda * YILF -0.0413 -9.91 * -0.0432 -3.72 *
Lambda * [YILF.sup.2] 0.0007 5.59 * 0.0007 3.15 *
Years of education 0.0256 3.76 * 0.0256 3.76 *
Constant 1.7869 19.04 * 1.7850 19.03 *
Year dummies Yes Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes Yes
Occupation dummies Yes Yes
Industry dummies Yes Yes
[R.sup.2] 0.3113 0.3113
F statistic [156.61.sub. [155.47.sub.
(26, 8378)] (27, 8377)]
Nos. of obs. 8405 8405
Highest education certificates, occupation dummies, and industry
dummies are as in Table 4.
Standard errors adjusted according to the White-Huber approach
because of the presence of heteroskedasticity.
Lambda = PRP/total pay.
* Statistically significant at the 1% level for a two-tailed test.
Table 7. Continuous Lambda, BHPS 1997-1999:
Dependent Variable, Log Hourly Earnings
Spec. 1
Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0872 10.81 *
Age (2) -0.0010 -10.04 *
YILF -- --
YILF (2) -- --
Job tenure -- --
Job tenure (2) -- --
Lambda -0.2620 -7.51 *
Lambda*age -- --
Lambda*age (2) -- --
Lambda*YILF -- --
Lambda*YILF (2) -- --
Lambda*job tenure -- --
Lambda*job tenure (2) -- --
Years of education -0.0071 -1.74
Constant -0.1690 -1.01
Year dummies
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0020
[R.sub.2] between 0.1647
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1473
Wald chi-squared [808.sub.26]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 2
Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0791 9.58 *
Age (2) -0.0009 -8.17 *
YILF -- --
YILF (2) -- --
Job tenure -- --
Job tenure (2) -- --
Lambda -- --
Lambda*age 0.0063 1.74
Lambda*age (2) -0.0003 -3.83 *
Lambda*YILF -- --
Lambda*YILF (2) -- --
Lambda*job tenure -- --
Lambda*job tenure (2) -- --
Years of education -0.0069 -1.69
Constant -0.1071 -0.63
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0034
[R.sub.2] between 0.1677
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1498
Wald chi-squared [848.sub.27]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 3
Coeff T Stat
Age 0.0774 8.56 *
Age (2) -0.0008 -7.34 *
YILF -- --
YILF (2) -- --
Job tenure -- --
Job tenure (2) -- --
Lambda -0.1945 -0.46
Lambda*age 0.0159 0.75
Lambda*age (2) -0.0004 -1.59
Lambda*YILF -- --
Lambda*YILF (2) -- --
Lambda*job tenure -- --
Lambda*job tenure (2) -- --
Years of education -0.0069 -1.69
Constant -0.0748 -0.41
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0034
[R.sub.2] between 0.1676
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1496
Wald chi-squared [847.sub.28]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 4
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
Age (2) -- --
YILF 0.0510 10.55 *
YILF (2) -0.0008 -9.39 *
Job tenure -- --
Job tenure (2) -- --
Lambda -0.2637 -7.55 *
Lambda*age -- --
Lambda*age (2) -- --
Lambda*YILF -- --
Lambda*YILF (2) -- --
Lambda*job tenure -- --
Lambda*job tenure (2) -- --
Years of education 0.0021 0.48
Constant 0.8103 7.82 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0021
[R.sub.2] between 0.1620
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1453
Wald chi-squared [792.sub.26]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 5
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
Age (2) -- --
YILF 0.0483 9.63 *
YILF (2) -0.0007 -7.51 *
Job tenure -- --
Job tenure (2) -- --
Lambda -- --
Lambda*age -- --
Lambda*age (2) -- --
Lambda*YILF -0.0023 -0.56
Lambda*YILF (2) -0.0002 -2.28
Lambda*job tenure -- --
Lambda*job tenure (2) -- --
Years of education 0.0023 0.54
Constant 0.7823 7.56 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0037
[R.sub.2] between 0.1657
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1486
Wald chi-squared [839.sub.27]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 6
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
Age (2) -- --
YILF 0.0525 9.74 *
YILF (2) -0.0008 -7.79 *
Job tenure -- --
Job tenure (2) -- --
Lambda 0.3631 2.13
Lambda*age -- --
Lambda*age (2) -- --
Lambda*YILF -0.0280 -2.20
Lambda*YILF (2) 0.0002 0.73
Lambda*job tenure -- --
Lambda*job tenure (2) -- --
Years of education 0.0025 0.58
Constant 0.7265 6.81 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.004
[R.sub.2] between 0.1659
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1492
Wald chi-squared [843.sub.28]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 7
Coeff T Star
Age -- --
Age (2) -- --
YILF -- --
YILF (2) -- --
Job tenure 0.0201 4.90 *
Job tenure (2) -0.0005 -3.35 *
Lambda -0.2412 -6.87 *
Lambda*age -- --
Lambda*age (2) -- --
Lambda*YILF -- --
Lambda*YILF (2) -- --
Lambda*job tenure -- --
Lambda*job tenure (2) -- --
Years of education -0.0050 -1.20
Constant 1.4589 18.66 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0025
[R.sub.2] between 0.1485
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1315
Wald chi-squared [689.sub.26]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 8
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
Age (2) -- --
YILF -- --
YILF (2) -- --
Job tenure 0.0286 5.85*
Job tenure (2) -0.0006 -3.33 *
Lambda -- --
Lambda*age -- --
Lambda*age (2) -- --
Lambda*YILF -- --
Lambda*YILF (2) -- --
Lambda*job tenure -0.0376 -4.85 *
Lambda*job tenure (2) 0.0007 2.41
Years of education -0.0051 -1.22
Constant 1.4065 18.04 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0019
[R.sub.2] between 0.1475
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1313
Wald chi-squared [683.sub.27]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Spec. 9
Coeff T Stat
Age -- --
Age (2) -- --
YILF -- --
YILF (2) -- --
Job tenure 0.0242 4.75 *
Job tenure (2) -0.0005 -2.64 *
Lambda -0.1600 -3.41 *
Lambda*age -- --
Lambda*age (2) -- --
Lambda*YILF -- --
Lambda*YILF (2) -- --
Lambda*job tenure -0.0177 -1.82
Lambda*job tenure (2) 0.0002 0.69
Years of education -0.0050 -1.21
Constant 1.4409 18.36 *
Year dummies Yes
Highest ed. cert. Yes
Occupation dummies Yes
Industry dummies Yes
[R.sub.2] within 0.0019
[R.sub.2] between 0.1520
[R.sub.2] overall 0.1336
Wald chi-squared [698.sub.28]
Nos. of observations 9187
Nos. of groups 4464
Highest education certificates,
occupation dummies, and industry
dummies are as in Table 3.
Standard errors adjusted according
to the White-Huber approach because
of the presence of heteroskedasticity.
Lambda = PRP/total pay.
* Statistically significant at the
1% level for a two-tailed test.
Table 8. Training Frequencies
PRP Employees
Standard
Obs. Mean Deviation
BSAS 1987
Train
Exp. < 5 yr 28 0.9286 0.2623
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 31 0.7742 0.4250
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 61 0.7541 0.4342
Exp. > 20 yr 153 0.5882 0.4938
All employees 273 0.6813 0.4668
Trains
Exp. < 5 yr 28 3.8929 2.0788
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 31 2.6129 2.0278
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 61 2.4590 2.1952
Exp. > 20 yr 153 1.7190 1.9717
All employees 273 2.2088 2.1395
BHPS 1991-1999
Train 6212 0.1718 0.3772
Exp. < 5 yr 68 0.3088 0.4654
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 765 0.2065 0.4051
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 2015 0.1856 0.3889
Exp. > 20 yr 3364 0.1528 0.3598
All employees 6212 0.1718 0.3772
Fixed-Wage Employees
Standard
Obs. Mean Deviation
BSAS 1987
Train
Exp. < 5 yr 50 0.9000 0.3030
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 52 0.7885 0.4124
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 101 0.6931 0.4635
Exp. > 20 yr 203 0.6847 0.4658
All employees 406 0.7266 0.4463
Trains
Exp. < 5 yr 50 3.7000 2.0923
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 52 2.6923 2.2798
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 101 2.4158 2.2058
Exp. > 20 yr 203 1.9803 1.9447
All employees 406 2.3916 2.1400
BHPS 1991-1999
Train 14,284 0.1246 0.3303
Exp. < 5 yr 198 0.2475 0.4326
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 1792 0.1735 0.3788
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 4000 0.1465 0.3537
Exp. > 20 yr 8294 0.1006 0.3008
All employees 14,284 0.1246 0.3303
All Employees
Standard
Obs. Mean Deviation
BSAS 1987
Train
Exp. < 5 yr 78 0.9103 0.2877
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 83 0.7831 0.4146
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 162 0.7160 0.4523
Exp. > 20 yr 356 0.6433 0.4797
All employees 679 0.7084 0.4548
Trains
Exp. < 5 yr 78 3.7692 2.0758
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 83 2.6627 2.1768
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 162 2.4321 2.1951
Exp. > 20 yr 356 1.8680 1.9579
All employees 679 2.3181 2.1401
BHPS 1991-1999
Train 20,496 0.1389 0.3458
Exp. < 5 yr 266 0.2632 0.4412
5 < Exp. < 10 yr 2557 0.1834 0.3871
10 < Exp. < 20 yr 6015 0.1596 0.3663
Exp. > 20 yr 11,658 0.1156 0.3198
All employees 20,496 0.1389 0.3458
Table 9. PRP and Training Incidence (Summary of Results)
BSAS 1987
Probit (1) Ordered Probit (1)
Dep Var = Train Dep Var = Trains
Coeff T Stat Cceff T Stat
Experience -0.0335 -5.95 * -0.0324 -7.47 *
PRP dummy -0.0700 -0.59 -0.0071 -0.08
(Exp. < 5) * PRP -- -- -- --
(5 < Exp. < 10) * PRP -- -- -- --
(10 < Exp. < 20) * PRP -- -- -- --
(Exp. > 20) * PRP -- -- -- --
Log likelihood -339.3235 -1219.0619
Nos. of observations 679 679
BSAS 1987
Probit (2) Ordered Probit (2)
Dep Var = Train Dep Var = Trains
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Experience -0.0311 -4.72 * -0.0292 -5.81 *
PRP dummy 0.2736 0.64 0.6316 2.04
(Exp. < 5) * PRP 0.0130 0.10 -0.0878 -0.99
(5 < Exp. < 10) * PRP -0.0525 -0.87 -0.0899 -2.07
(10 < Exp. < 20) * PRP -0.0211 -0.76 -0.0440 -2.15
(Exp. > 20) * PRP -0.0116 -0.88 -0.0211 -2.12
Log likelihood -338.37818 -1215.8068
Nos. of observations 679 679
BHPS 1991-1999
Probit (1) Probit (2)
Dep Var = Train Dep Var = Train
Coeff T Stat Coeff T Stat
Experience -0.183 10.49 * -0.020 10.15 *
PRP dummy 0.106 3.30 * 0.015 0.12
(Exp. < 5) * PRP -- -- 0.099 2.27
(5 < Exp. < 10) * PRP -- -- -0.002 0.14
(10 < Exp. < 20) * PRP -- -- 0.003 0.40
(Exp. > 20) * PRP -- -- 0.005 1.15
Log likelihood -6738.750 -6733.579
Nos. of observations 20,496 20,496
Controls were also included for occupation,
region, industry, education, firm size,
marital status, and ethnicity.
* Statistically significant at the 1% level
for a two-tailed test.