Another look at yield spreads: the role of liquidity.
Kim, Dong Heon
1. Introduction
The expectations hypothesis (hereafter EH) of the term structure of
interest rates states that the long-term rate is determined by the
expectation for the short-term rate plus a constant term premium. With
rational expectations, one of the EH implications is that the
coefficient in a regression of the change in expected future short-term
interest rates on the current yield spread between long- and short-term
rates is unity. Many empirical studies, such as Shiller, Campbell, and
Schoenholtz (1983), Fama (1984), Mankiw and Miron (1986), Fama and Bliss
(1987), Hardouvelis (1988), Mishkin (1988), Froot (1989), Simon (1989,
1990), Cook and Hahn (1990), Campbell and Shiller (1991), and Roberds,
Runkle, and Whiteman (1996), among others, have shown mixed results,
with more evidence against the EH than in its favor. (1) Even though
Fama (1984), Hardouvelis (1988), Mishkin (1988), and Simon (1990) have
found yield spreads do help predict future rates, the coefficient
appears inconsistent with the EH. (2) Thornton (2006) argues that
analysis should not be based on the slope coefficient of the test
equation only, because even under the alternative hypothesis where the
EH does not hold, one can have slopes that are numerically close to the
theoretical ones.
Several studies have shown that even if the EH does hold, it would
be hard to use it for forecasting due to interest rate smoothing by the
Federal Reserve System (Fed). (3) On the other hand, a number of studies
have focused on the possibility of a time-varying risk premium and
concluded that a time-varying risk premium can help explain the failures
of the EH. (4) From a study of time variation in expected excess bond
returns, Cochrane and Piazzesi (2005) find that a single factor, which
is a single tent-shaped linear combination of forward rates, predicts
excess returns on one- to five-year maturity bonds and strengthens the
evidence against the EH. Wachter (2006) shows that a consumption-based
model in which external habit persistence from Campbell and Cochrane
(1999) and the short-term interest rate that makes long bonds risky are
the driving forces for time-varying risk premia on real bonds.
However, Evans and Lewis (1994) argue that a time-varying risk
premium alone is not sufficient to explain the time-varying term premium
observed in the Treasury bill. Dotsey and Otrok (1995) suggest that a
deeper understanding of interest rate behavior will be produced by
jointly taking into account the behavior of the monetary authority along
with a more detailed understanding of what determines term premia.
Diebold, Piazzesi, and Rudebusch (2005) state that from a macroeconomic prospective, the short-term interest rate is a policy instrument under
the direct control of the central bank, which adjusts the rate to
achieve its economic stabilization goals; from a finance prospective,
the short rate is a fundamental building block for yields of other
maturities, which are just risk-adjusted averages of the expected future
short rate. They suggest that a joint macro-finance modeling strategy
will provide the most comprehensive understanding of the term structure
of interest rates.
Recently, Bansal and Coleman (1996) argued that some assets other
than money play a special role in facilitating transactions, which
affects the rate of return that they offer. In their model, securities
that back checkable deposits provide a transactions service return in
addition to their nominal return. Since short-term government bonds
facilitate transactions by backing checkable deposits, this results in
equilibrium with a lower nominal return for these bonds. Such a view
implies that liquidity plays an important role in determining the
returns of various securities. So, if liquidity is an important factor
determining the returns of financial assets, liquidity may also be
important for yield spreads and the term structure of interest rates.
But how do investors consider liquidity in allocating their funds
between securities of different terms? Since commercial banks are the
principal investors and primary dealers in instruments such as federal
funds, commercial paper (hereafter CP), and Eurodollar CDs, a study of
liquidity demand by commercial banks may provide the key to answering
this question. (5,6)
This paper attempts to answer the following question: Can the fact
that liquidity plays an important role in explaining how banks determine
their allocation of funds explain yield spreads and help provide an
explanation for the failure of the EH?
If a bank might, at some point, be unable to turn its assets into
ready cash, the bank faces a liquidity risk. Liquidity is a crucial fact
of life for banks, and for this reason may have an implication for yield
spreads and the term structure of interest rates. In addition, because
banks' liquidity can vary as a result of Fed policy, financial
market conditions, an individual bank's specific demand for
reserves, and so on, banks' liquidity might play an important role
in explaining time-varying term premia. Most previous studies, however,
have not focused on banks as the main investors in financial markets
and, thus, have not considered the role of banks' liquidity.
The paper begins by developing a model of a bank's optimal
behavior. In terms of this banking model, the paper follows previous
literature such as Cosimano (1987), Cosimano and Van Huyck (1989),
Elyasiani, Kopecky, and Van Hoose (1995), Kang (1997), and Hamilton
(1998), with the new addition of the cash-in-advance (CIA) constraint of
Clower (1967), Lucas (1982), Svensson (1985), Lucas and Stokey (1987),
and Bansal and Coleman (1996). In addition, this model incorporates a
time-varying risk premium. (7) The paper finds that the CIA constraint
plays an important role in determining yield spreads and the term
structure of interest rates. The empirical part of the paper shows that
the simple EH is not consistent with the empirical evidence, but the EH
model allowing for the liquidity premium and the risk premium is a more
realistic term structure model. This result implies that the EH might be
salvaged when account is taken of the liquidity premium and the risk
premium. (8)
The plan of this paper is as follows: Section 2 develops a model
that incorporates liquidity into banks' optimal behavior and
examines the determination of yield spreads and the term structure of
interest rates. Section 3 provides a brief empirical test of the EH of
the term structure and obtains empirical results for the theoretical
model developed in section 2. A brief summary and concluding remarks are
given in section 4.
2. The Model
This section develops a model that incorporates liquidity into
banks' optimal behavior. In this model, bank loans are n-period
assets and federal funds are one-period assets. There are many banks (N
is number of banks) in the banking system. Banks have an infinite
horizon. Each period consists of two sessions, the beginning of period t
and the end of period t.
Banks' Optimal Behavior Subject to CIA Constraint
I assume that the reserve supply in the banking system does not
change unless the Fed changes it. When borrowers cannot repay the loan
principal as well as the loan interest rate payment, banks face risks on
loans (default risk). I assume that this default risk increases as the
quantity of loans or the maturity of loans increases. The model assumes
that banks determine optimal balance sheet quantities by taking all
interest rates as predetermined. Suppose that a bank j has the following
profit function:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [L.sub.j,t] is the quantity of new n-period loans for bank j
made in the beginning of period t, [r.sup.L.sub.n,t] is the yield on
n-period loans made at time t, [r.sup.D.sub.t] is the yield on federal
funds lent or borrowed at time t, [F.sub.j,t] is the federal funds lent
or borrowed for bank j at time t, [r.sup.D.sub.t] is the deposit rate,
[delta]'s are nonnegative constants, and [[bar.D].sub.j,t] is the
level of demand deposits for bank j at time t. I assume that
[[bar.D].sub.j,t] is taken to be exogenous. The expressions in
parentheses represent the risk on loans each period.
In this case, a bank j has two options at time t - 1. One option is
for the bank to hold reserves at the end of period t - 1 in order to
lend them over n periods at the beginning of period t. The other option
is that the bank rolls over reserves as federal funds for n periods. If
bank./" lends to the public over n periods, the bank faces risks on
loans and this default risk increases as the quantity of loans or the
maturity of loans increases.
Bank j chooses the level of new loans, [L.sub.j,t], and lends this
amount to the public at the beginning of period t. The bank will get
back the loan at the beginning of period t + n. At the end of period t,
it chooses the quantity of federal funds to lend, [F.sub.j,t]. These
choices, along with some other exogenous or predetermined factors,
determine the level of reserves, [R.sub.j,t], with which the bank will
end the period. These other factors are the bank's level of demand
deposits, [[bar.D].sub.j,t], with a positive value for
[[bar.D].sub.j,t], [[bar.D].sub.j,t-1] i increasing the bank's
end-of-period reserve position; the repayment of the federal funds the
bank lent the previous period, [F.sub.j,t-1]; and the repayment of the
loans the bank made n periods previously, [L.sub.j,t]. The bank's
end-of-period reserves thus evolve according to (9)
[R.sub.j,t] = [R.sub.j,t] + [L.sub.j,t-n] + [F.sub.j,t-1] +
[[bar.D].sub.j,t] - [[bar.D].j,t-1] - [L.sub.j,t] - [F.sub.j,t]. (1)
In addition, the bank must satisfy thte reserve requirement
[R.sub.j,t] [greater than or equal to][theta][[bar.D].sub.j,t], (2)
where [theta] is the required reserve ratio, (10)
At the beginning of period t, bank j starts with reserve balances
given by [R.sub.j,t-1] + [L.sub.j,t-n], the transferred previous reserve
balances plus the repayment of the loans made n periods previously.
Given the loan rate and the federal funds rate, bank j must choose its
loan supply, [L.sub.j,t], before knowing its deposits,
[[bar.D].sub.j,t]. This choice is subject to predetermined holdings
[R.sub.j,t-1] + [L.sub.j,t-n] of reserve balances. That is, in our
model, a borrower from the bank wants cash, and the bank can only extend
a loan to such a customer if it has cash (reserves) on hand equal to the
amount of the loan. In this case, the bank's need for liquidity
(sufficient reserves) can be for transaction purposes as well as the
precautionary purpose of meeting depositor withdrawals or the reserve
requirement.
I can model the bank's demand for liquidity in the same way
that the CIA literature has modeled demand for liquidity by private
households. In the conventional CIA formulation, goods must be purchased
with cash, and a consumer can only obtain goods if he has cash on hand
sufficient to pay for them. In this case, a household's demand for
cash is mainly for transaction purposes. In terms of banks, loans are
funded with reserves, and the bank can only have loan commitments with
sufficient reserve balances. This kind of transaction reserve model can
be compatible with Hamilton (1996, 1998), in which banks would want to
hold reserves even if there were no reserve requirements for the same
reason that members of the public hold cash: Namely, funds are needed to
effect transactions. Reserves are useful to banks beyond the purpose of
reserve requirements in the sense that reserves provide banks with a
transactions service return. In this case, even though banks are subject
to the required reserve constraint, the true value of the reserve for
liquidity services might not be captured using only the shadow price of
the required reserve constraint.
How should one think of the CIA constraint in the light of borrowed
reserves? By studying the discount window borrowing by weekly reporting
banks disaggregated by Federal Reserve District, Cosimano and Sheehan
(1994) show that any single bank seldom visits the discount window and
argue that this behavior is consistent either with banks not
aggressively managing their discount window borrowings or, more
plausibly, with the presence of considerable harassment costs imposed by
the discount window officer. Hamilton (1998) states that banks act as if
they faced a cost function for borrowing reserves from the Fed, and the
cost of borrowing includes nonpecuniary costs in the form of additional
regulation, supervision, and inferior credit standing with other banks.
From this point of view, banks should not place excessive reliance on
the discount window to obtain reserves and fund their loans to the
public; thus, they might need to hold excess reserves for liquidity
yield purposes. Hence, the CIA constraint that the bank faces might
reflect the bank's demand for liquidity.
However, the strict CIA requirement ignores real-life institutions
such as credit cards available to consumers or within-day overdraft privileges available to banks on their accounts with the Fed. Even so,
the requirement of needing actual cash on hand for certain transactions
seems to capture the key idea of what is meant by liquidity and has
proven to be a useful framework for thinking about liquidity demand by
private households. I propose that it may also be fruitful for seeing
how the need for liquidity may impact the rates of return on assets of
different maturities held by banks. Thus, I propose that bank j faces a
CIA or liquidity constraint such as the following:
[L.sub.j,t] [less than or equal to][R.sub.j,t-1] + [L.sub.j,t-n],
(3)
where [R.sub.j,t-1] is the reserve balance transferred from the
previous period to the start of period t for the bank j. In this case, I
assume that the repayment of outstanding loans contributes to the
bank's liquidity balances at the beginning of period t. Thus, the
bank enters period t with predetermined holdings of reserves, as the
liquidity balances and the bank's new loans must obey the CIA
constraint. (11)
The Equilibrium
Bank j faces the choice of new loans at the beginning of period t
and the choice of federal funds at the end of period t. The state
variables that are relevant for the bank's decision of the quantity
of federal funds to lend at the end of period t are [L.sub.j,t],
[L.sub.j,t-1], ..., [L.sub.j,t-n], [F.sub.j,t-1], [R.sub.j,t-1], and
[[bar.D].sub.j,t]. Consider the following value function formulation of
the decision at the end of period t:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
subject to
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [U.sub.j,t](.) denotes the lifetime value of bank j's
optimal program as of the second session of period t, whereas
[V.sub.j,t+1](L.sub.j,t],[L.sub.j,t-1], ..., [L.sub.j,t-
n+1],[F.sub.j,t],[R.sub.j,t],[[bar.D].sub.j,t]) is the value as of the
first session of period t + 1, and [beta] denotes the discount factor.
The bank's problem is to maximize the value function
[V.sub.j,t](.) subject to the CIA constraint (Eqn. 3) at the first
session of period t and the value function [U.sub.j,t](.) subject to the
balance-sheet constraint (Eqn. 1) and required reserve constraint (Eqn.
2) at the second session of period t. In other words, bank j chooses
federal funds to maximize the value function [U.sub.j,t](.) subject to
the bank's balance-sheet constraint and the required reserve
constraint at the end of period t. The first-order conditions are as
follows:
[r.sup.F.sub.t] + [beta][E.sub.t][partial
derivative][V.sub.j,t+1]/[partial derivative][F.sub.j,t] =
[beta][E.sub.t][partial derivative][V.sub.j,t+1]/[partial
derivative][R.sub.j,t] + [[lambda].sub.j,t], (4)
[R.sub.j,t][greater than or equal to] [theta] [[bar.D].sub.j,t],
with equality if [[lambda].sub.j,t] > 0, (5)
where [[lambda].sub.j,t] is the Lagrange multiplier of the required
reserve constraint and represents the implicit price of this constraint.
Note that the balance-sheet constraint can be substituted for
[R.sub.j,t] in the value function and the required reserve constraint,
so we do not have a Lagrange multiplier for the balance-sheet
constraint.
At the beginning of period t, bank j starts with reserve balances
given by [R.sub.j,t-1] + [L.sub.j,t-n]. Given the loan rate and the
federal funds rate, bank j must choose its loan supply, [L.sub.j,t],
before knowing the deposits, [[bar.D].sub.j,t]. The state variables for
the decision at the beginning of period t are [L.sub.j,t- 1],
[L.sub.j,t-2], ..., [L.sub.j,t-n], [F.sub.j,t-1], [R.sub.j,t-1], and
[[bar.D].sub.j,t-1]. The value function of the beginning of period at
time t is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
subject to
[L.sub.j,t] [less than or equal to] [R.sub.j,t-1] + [L.sub.j,t-n].
Maximizing the value function [V.sub.j,t](.) subject to the CIA
constraint at the beginning of period t, I have the following
first-order conditions:
[r.sup.L.sub.n,t] + [partial derivative][U.sub.j,t]/[partial
derivative][L.sub.j,t] - ([[delta].sub.0] + [delta][L.sub.j,t]) =
[[eta].sub.j,t], (6)
[L.sub.j,t-n] + [R.sub.j,t-1][greater than or equal to][L.sub.j,t],
with equality if [[eta].sub.j,t] > 0, (7)
where [[eta].sub.j,t] is the Lagrange multiplier of the CIA
constraint and represents the shadow price of this constraint. Using the
envelope conditions from the value functions at the beginning of period
t and at the end of period t, I have:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
since [beta][E.sub.t][[eta].sub.j,t+1] + [[lambda].sub.j,t] =
[r.sup.F.sub.t], ..., [[beta].sup.n-1][E.sub.t][[eta].sub.j,t+n-1] +
[[beta].sup.n-2][E.sub.t] [[lambda].sub.j,t+n-2] =
[[beta].sup.n-2][E.sub.t][r.sup.F.sub.t+n-2] and
[[beta].sup.n-1][E.sub.t][[lambda].sub.j,t+n-1] =
[[beta].sup.n-1][E.sub.t] [r.sup.F.sub.t+n-1] -
[[beta].sup.n][E.sub.t][[eta].sub.j,t+n]. Using the above equations and
the first-order conditions, it is straightforward to characterize the
equilibrium as satisfying the following equations: (12)
[r.sup.F.sub.t] = [beta][E.sub.t][[eta].sub.j,t+1] +
[[lambda].sub.j,t], (8)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (9)
Equation 9 can be rewritten as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (10)
Equation 10 states that the n-period loan rate is the weighted
average of the current federal funds rate and expected future federal
funds rate over n period, plus the cost resulting from the risk (or
transaction costs) on loans and the cost of loss of the liquidity
benefit for bank j. The term in parentheses on the right-hand side is
the risk premium, and the second bracket of the right-hand side is the
liquidity premium. The liquidity premium depends on the difference
between the current shadow price of the CIA constraint and the expected
shadow price of the CIA constraint at time t + n. If the bank j expects
the liquidity benefit of the loan lent at time t to be higher at the
beginning of time t + n when the bank gets back the loan lent at the
beginning of time t, the bank does not require as much compensation for
liquidity loss. On the other hand, if the bank expects the liquidity
benefit of the loan lent to be lower at the beginning of time t + n than
today, the bank will require more compensation for liquidity loss. Bank
j chooses [F.sub.j,t] (and hence a value for [[lambda].sub.j,t] and
[E.sub.j,t] and [[eta].sub.j,t+1]) so as to satisfy Equation 8.
Implication for the Aggregate Banking
To consider the implication for aggregate banking (market
equilibrium), I sum Equation 1 and take an average for Equations 8-10.
This yields
[r.sup.F.sub.t] = [beta][E.sub.t][[eta].sub.t+1] +
[[lambda].sub.t], (11)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (12)
[R.sub.t] = [R.sub.t-1] + [L.sub.t-n] + [F.sub.t-1] +
[[bar.D].sub.t] - [[bar.D].sub.t-1] - [L.sub.t] - [F.sub.t], (13)
where [[lambda].sub.t] = 1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.j] = 1
[[lambda].sub.j,t], [E.sub.t][[eta].sub.t+1] = 1/N
[[summation].sup.N.sub.j] = 1 [E.sub.t][[eta].sub.j,t+1], [R.sub.t-i] =
1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.j = 1] [R.sub.j,t- i], for i = 0, 1,
[L.sub.t-n] = 1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.j=1][L.sub.j,t-n],
[F.sub.t-1] = 1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.j=1][F.sub.j,t- 1],
[[bar.D].sub.t-1] = 1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.j=1][[bar.D].sub.j,t-i],
for i = 0, 1, [L.sub.t] = 1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.j=1][L.sub.j,t],
and [F.sub.t] = 1/N [[summation].sup.N.sub.j=1][F.sub.j,t].
In equilibrium, [F.sub.t] must be zero, and the exogenous supply of
reserves and demand for loans will determine [[lambda].sub.t] and
[E.sub.t][[eta].sub.t+1], which, together with Equation 11, determine
[r.sup.F.sub.t]. The interest rate adjusts to clear the market. Equation
11 bears an analogy with Svensson's (1985) paper. It states that
the current federal funds rate is the sum of the discounted expected
value of next period's shadow price of the CIA constraint and the
shadow price of the required reserve constraint at time t. Even if the
required reserve constraint is non-binding and the shadow price of it is
zero, the existence of a binding liquidity constraint would warrant a
positive federal funds rate. So reserves are held against federal funds
for the future liquidity services they provide, and the value of these
liquidity services is the value of relaxing the future liquidity
constraint. Equation 12 is an Euler equation and an optimizing condition
between the loan market and the federal funds market. This equation
implies that the marginal benefit of increasing the volume of loans is
equal to the marginal benefit of lending federal funds. Equation 12 can
be rewritten as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (14)
Equation 14 states that the n-period loan rate is the weighted
average of the current federal funds rate and the expected future
federal funds rate over n period plus the cost resulting from the risk
(or transaction costs) on loans and the cost of loss of the liquidity
benefit. Multiplying Equation 12 by [beta], taking the expectation at
time t - 1, and rearranging I get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (15)
Equation 15 is the term structure model that incorporates a
time-varying liquidity premium and a risk premium; given information at
time t - 1. One point to make is that if the CIA constraint is binding,
monetary policy draining or injecting reserve balances can have an
impact not only on the federal funds rate and the loan rate, but also on
the term premium and, thus, monetary policy can affect the term
structure of interest rates.
Term Structure Implication
Equation 15 determines the term structure of interest rates between
the n-period loan rate and the one-period federal funds rate. This term
structure model incorporates time-varying liquidity and risk premia.
Since banks' liquidity can vary over time, the liquidity difference
shows up on the term structure model as the liquidity premium. Hence,
banks' liquidity plays an important role in explaining the
time-varying term premium and thus can help to explain the widespread
rejection of the EH. Consequently, a term structure model that
incorporates banks' liquidity demand into banks' optimal
behavior might provide an alternative to the simple EH.
For clarity, setting [beta] = 1, Equation 15 can be rewritten as
follows:
[r.sup.L.sub.n,t] = 1/n [E.sub.t][n-1.summation over
(i=0)][r.sup.F.sub.t+i] + ([[delta].sub.0] + [[delta].sub.1][L.sub.t]) +
1/n [[[eta].sub.t] - [E.sub.t][[eta].sub.t+n]]. (16)
To explore whether this model can quantitatively match the features
of the EH under the maintained hypothesis concerning the liquidity
premium and risk premium, I need quantitative magnitudes of the shadow
prices. Recall from Equation 11 that, in equilibrium, the current
federal funds rate is the expected value of next period's
discounted shadow price of the CIA constraint, assuming the required
reserve constraint is not binding. (13) Thus, we can take conditional
expectations of both sides of Equation 16 based on information available
at t - 1, as in Equation 15, to use the previous federal funds rate as
the expected value of the discounted shadow price of the CIA constraint.
Similarly, I can assume [E.sub.t-1] [r.sup.F.sub.t+n-1] =
[E.sub.t-1][[eta].sub.t+n]. Then, Equation 16 can be rewritten
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (17)
Further assuming rational expectations, let [v.sub.t+i], i = 0, 1,
2, ..., n - 1, [e.sub.t], and [[xi].sub.t] denote the subsequent
forecast errors orthogonal to information available at time t - 1: (14)
[v.sub.t+i] = [r.sup.F.sub.t+i] - [E.sub.t-1][r.sup.F.sub.t+i], i =
0, 1, 2, ..., n - 1, (18)
[e.sub.t] = [r.sup.L.sub.n,t] - [E.sub.t-1][r.sup.L.sub.n,t], (19)
[[xi].sub.t] = [L.sub.t] - [E.sub.t-1][L.sub.t]. (20)
I also assume that [e.sub.t], [[xi].sub.t] and [v.sub.t+j] for all
j's are serially uncorrelated and mutually independent.
Substituting Equations 18 20 into Equation 17 and rearranging it, I get
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (21)
Equation 21 provides plausible parameter values for the risk
premium and liquidity premium under the above assumptions. The second
term on the right-hand side of Equation 21, [[delta].sub.0] +
[[delta].sub.1][L.sub.t], and the third term, 1/n (r.sup.F.sub.t-1] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t+n-1]), capture the risk premium and the liquidity
premium, respectively. Subtracting [r.sup.F.sub.t] from both sides of
Equation 21 and rearranging results in
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (22)
The model 22 implies that the simple EH does not hold because of
the liquidity premium and the risk premium. I can estimate this model
and examine if the EH might be a more realistic model when the liquidity
premium and the risk premium play a role.
3. Estimation of the Term Structure Model
The Data
The weekly data set we use runs from February 1, 1984, to December
27, 2000, giving 882 observations, (15) Interest rates are taken from
Federal Reserve Statistical Release H. 15 provided by the Federal
Reserve Board of Governors. I also take quantities of loans from item
H.8 (assets and liabilities of all commercial banks in the United
States) of the Federal Reserve Statistical Release. (16) Since this
series refers to outstanding loans at each period, I use the change in
this series as a proxy for the volume of new loans extended. We consider
federal funds rates as a short-term rate and one-month and three-month
CP rates as long-term rates. All interest rates are averages of seven
calendar days ending on Wednesday and annualized using a 360-day year.
(17) Here, the CP rate is viewed as a substitute for the rate on
banks' loans to financial and industrial companies.
Figure 1 shows movements of the federal funds rate and the
one-month and three-month CP rates during this sample. One interesting
feature is that the federal funds rate fluctuated around the CP rates
before the 1990 U.S. recession, but after the recession the CP rates
were higher than the federal funds rate. Sample period averages of the
federal funds rate, one-month, and three-month CP rates are 6.23%,
6.28%, and 6.29%, respectively, and thus the one-month and three-month
CP rates are higher on average by five and six basis points,
respectively, than the federal funds rate. However, the standard
deviation of the federal funds rate is 1.93, higher than those of the
one-month and three-month CP rates, 1.84 and 1.82, respectively, which
implies that the volatility of the federal funds rate is somewhat higher
than those of the CP rates.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
A Test of the Expectations Hypothesis
I start from a test of the simple EH, which implies that the
long-term rate is a weighted average of the current short-term rate and
expected future short-term rates and that the current spread between the
long-term rate and short-term rate predicts the change in future
short-term rates. That is,
[r.sup.L.sub.n,t] = 1/n [E.sub.t][n-1.summation over
(i=0)][r.sup.F.sub.t+i], (23)
where [r.sup.F.sub.n,t] and [r.sup.F.sub.t] are the n-period CP
rate (our substitute for the n-period loan rate) and one-period federal
funds rate, respectively. Assuming rational expectations, one can
rearrange Equation 23 to yield the following relationship as the term
structure regression for empirical investigation:
Model I: [[delta].sub.0] = [[delta].sub.1] = 0, [[eta].sub.t] =
[E.sub.t][[eta].sub.t+n] 1/n [n-1.summation over (i=0)][r.sup.F.sub.t+i]
- [r.sup.F.sub.t] = [alpha] + [phi] ([r.sup.L.sub.n,t] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t]) + [[epsilon].sub.t], (24)
where [[epsilon].sub.t] = 1/n [n-1.summation over
(i=0)][r.sup.F.sub.t+i] - 1/n [E.sub.t][n-1.summation over (i=0)]
[r.sup.F.sub.t+i] and should be uncorrelated with any variable known at
time t. Here, n corresponds to 4 or 12 weeks for one- and three-month
commercial paper, respectively. Equation 24 can be estimated by OLS with
autocorrelation-heteroskedasticity consistent errors. According to the
simple expectations hypothesis, [alpha] = 0, and [phi] = 1. This test
can be nested within our term structure model (Equation 22) by imposing
the restrictions [[delta].sub.0] = [[delta].sub.1] = 0, and
[[eta].sub.t] = [E.sub.t][[eta].sub.t+n].
Table 1 shows the results for estimation of Equation 24. The
coefficient on the spread is significantly less than unity and different
from zero at conventional significance levels. In addition, the
estimated coefficients on the constant are significantly less than zero.
These results are very similar to those of previous empirical studies.
(18)
Test of the Expectations Hypothesis with Liquidity Premium and Risk
Premium
Our model developed in section 2 implies that the simple EH does
not hold because of the liquidity premium and the risk premium. Since
banks' optimal behavior is subject to a CIA constraint, banks'
liquidity causes the shadow price of the CIA constraint to play an
important role in yield spreads and the term structure of interest
rates. Thus, the model suggests that I need to incorporate a liquidity
premium and a risk premium into the simple EH. The model (Equation 22)
forms the basis of the tests of the term structure on which to focus.
Subtracting 1/n [r.sup.F.sub.t+n-1] from both sides of Equation 22 to
avoid including the ex-post future interest rate in the equation as a
regressor, I get:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (25)
Then, Equation 25 involves running the regression:
Model II: [[delta].sub.0][not equal to]0, [[delta].sub.1][not equal
to]0, [E.sub.t-1][[eta].sub.t] = [r.sup.F.sub.t-1],
[E.sub.t-1][[eta].sub.t+n] = [E.sub.t-1][r.sup.F.sub.1+n-1]
1/n [n-2.summation over (i=0)][r.sup.F.sub.t+i] - [r.sup.F.sub.t] =
[alpha] + [phi]([r.sup.L.sub.n,t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t] +
[[gamma].sub.1][r.sup.F.sub.t-1] + [[gamma].sub.2][L.sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t], (26)
where [L.sub.t] is the quantity of new loans at time t, and
[[epsilon].sub.t] = 1/n [[summation].sup.n-2.sub.i=0][v.sub.t] + i +
[[delta].sub.1][[xi].sub.t] - [e.sub.t]. Regression 26 differs from all
tests of EH in the existing literature, where the regressand is not 1/n
[[summation].sup.n-2.sub.i=0][r.sup.F.sub.t], but 1/n
[[summation].sup.n-1.sub.i=0] [r.sup.F.sub.t+i] - [r.sup.F.sub.t].
Equation 26 cannot be estimated by OLS because [[epsilon].sub.t] is
correlated with the regressors [r.sup.L.sub.n,t] and [r.sup.F] Rational
expectations require [[epsilon].sub.t] to be uncorrelated
with anything known to banks at time t - 1, but [r.sup.L.sub.n,t]
and [r.sup.F.sub.t] are not in the date t - 1 information set. However,
Equation 26 can be estimated by instrumental variables using valid
instruments. I consider 2SLS with constant, lagged federal funds rates,
and lagged quantities of new loans as instruments. I employ
Hansen's (1982) method in order to check the overidentifying
restrictions and, thus, test these conjectures about the correct set of
instruments. Hansen's test statistic has an asymptotic [chi square]
distribution with r - k degrees of freedom if the model is correctly
specified, where r is the number of instruments and k is the number of
estimated coefficients. According to Model II, [alpha] =
[[delta].sub.0], [phi] = 1, [[gamma].sub.1] = [-n.sup.-1], and
[[gamma].sub.2] = -[[delta].sub.1]. Table 2 shows the results. In both
cases, the estimated coefficients on the spread are close to unity.
Indeed, the t-statistic for testing the null hypothesis that the
coefficient of the spread is unity is -0.564 for the one-month CP rate
and -0.053 for the three-month CP rate, respectively, and thus in both
cases implies that the estimated coefficients are not statistically
significantly different from unity at the 5% level, in contrast with the
estimated coefficients on the spread in Model I. In addition, following
Hansen's (1982) method, [[chi square].sub.1] for the one-month CP
rate and [[chi square].sub.2] for the three-month CP rate are 1.288 and
5.816, respectively, so the null hypothesis that Model II is correctly
specified is accepted at the 5% level. These results imply that these
instruments are valid. (19)
All the estimated coefficients have the signs predicted by the
theoretical model developed in section 2, and all estimated coefficients
are statistically significant at the conventional level except the
coefficients on [L.sub.t]. In particular, the estimated coefficients on
the liquidity premium are close to the values that the theoretical model
implies (-0.25 for the one-month CP rate and -0.084 for the three-month
CP rate) and statistically significant, indicating that liquidity plays
an important role in explaining the term premium. However, among two
components reflecting the risk premium, the constant is statistically
significant, whereas the estimated coefficients on Lt are not
significantly different from zero.
Another Application: Euro-Dollar Rates
Since I did not have a direct measure of the loan rate, I used the
CP rates as a proxy for the bank loan rate instead. However, as pointed
out in Kashyap, Stein, and Wilcox (1993), bank loans are special, and
the commercial paper might be an imperfect substitute. In addition,
Stigum (1990) and Cook and LaRoche (1993) state that historically the CP
market has been remarkably free of default risk in contrast to bank
loans. From this point of view, the CP rate might not be a good choice
of proxy. To investigate this issue, I consider the Euro-dollar
(hereafter ED) rate as another proxy. Even though the ED is a liability
and the ED rate is a deposit rate, it is subject to default risk and can
fluctuate in accordance with banks' liquidity demand. The one-month
and three-month ED rates are taken from Statistical Release provided by
the Federal Reserve Board of Governors for the sample.
Figure 2 plots movements in these ED rates and the federal funds
rate. The ED rates show very similar movements to the CD rates displayed
in Figure 1. Table 3 shows estimation results for Model I and Model II.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The estimated coefficients on the spread are close to unity, and
the t-statistic for testing the null hypothesis that the coefficient of
the spread is unity, is - 1.264 for the one-month ED rate and -0.267 for
the three-month ED rate, respectively, and thus I cannot reject the null
hypothesis at the 5% level in both cases. In the case of Model II,
Hansen's test statistics are 0.7 for the one-month ED rate and
10.29 for the three-month ED rate, respectively, and I do not reject the
null, indicating that the model is correctly specified. The estimated
coefficients on the liquidity premium are statistically significant and
quite close to the values expected by the theoretical model; although,
the estimated coefficients on the risk premium components are not
significantly different from zero in contrast to the case of the CP
rates. Overall, the results are qualitatively similar to those of the CP
rates.
4. Conclusion
This paper has focused on commercial banks as the main investors in
financial markets, and banks' liquidity as an important component
that determines yield spreads over securities with different terms. To
this end, I have developed a term structure model that incorporates
liquidity demands by commercial banks into a model for banks'
optimal behavior. The paper has shown that the shadow price of the CIA
constraint plays an important role in determining the yield spread.
Moreover, the empirical study has shown that the simple EH is not
consistent with the empirical evidence, but when we incorporate the
liquidity premium and the risk premium resulting from transaction
activities into the term structure of interest rates, the EH model
describes yield spreads and the term structure more realistically. This
result implies that the EH might be salvaged under the maintained
hypothesis concerning the liquidity premium and the risk premium.
The results of the paper have an important implication. As most
households' transaction activities are subject to their liquidity
conditions, so are banks' transaction activities. When banks
allocate their funds into financial securities of different maturities,
they incorporate information about liquidity as well as risk into their
portfolio management decisions. Investors know that long-term assets are
relatively less liquid than short-term assets, and the difference in
liquidity among these financial assets is incorporated into their
returns. This might be one reason why previous studies have not produced
a consensus about the empirical failure of the simple EH. I feel that
the story presented here provides a useful alternative to the simple EH.
This paper is based on chapter 1 of the author's University of
California San Diego PhD dissertation. Deep discussions with James D.
Hamilton are gratefully acknowledged. For helpful comments and
suggestions, the author thanks Kent Kimbrough (coeditor), two anonymous
referees, Keith Blackburn, Wouter Den Haan, John Duca, Marjorie Flavin,
Andreas Gottschling, Takeo Hoshi, Garett Jones, Alex Kane, Chang-Jin
Kim, Soyoung Kim, Jong-Wha Lee, Denise Osborn, Marianne Sensier, Kwan Ho
Shin, and seminar participants at Korea University, University of
California San Diego, University of Manchester, University of
Nottingham, University of Southampton, Bank of Korea, Korean Econometric
Society Macroworkshop, RES Conference 2001, Western Economic Association
Meeting 2001, and KAEA/KEA Conference 2002. Financial support from Korea
University Grant, the Institute of Economic Research at Korea
University, University of Manchester, and the Royal Economic Society is
gratefully acknowledged.
Received March 2006; accepted November 2006.
References
Anderson. Richard G., and Robert H. Rasche. 2001. Retail sweep
programs and bank reserves. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
83:51-72.
Bansal, Ravi, and Wilbur J. Coleman. 1996. A monetary explanation
of the equity premium, term premium, and riskfree rate puzzles. Journal
of Political Economy 104:1135-71.
Bataa, Erdenebat, Dong Heon Kim, and Denise R. Osborn. 2006.
Expectations hypothesis tests in the presence of model uncertainty.
Economics Discussion Paper 0611, University of Manchester, Manchester,
UK.
Bekaert, Geert, and Robert J. Hodrick. 2001. Expectations
hypotheses tests. The Journal of Finance 56:1357-94.
Bekaert, Geert, Min Wei, and Yuhang Xing. 2007. Uncovered interest
rate parity and the term structure. International Journal of Money and
Finance 26:1038-1069.
Campbell, John Y., and John H. Cochrane. 1999. By force of habit: A
consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior.
Journal of Political Economy 107:205-51.
Campbell, John Y., and Robert J. Shiller. 1991. Yield spreads and
interest rate movement: A bird's eye view. Review of Economic
Studies 58:495-514.
Chami, Ralph, and Thomas F. Cosimano. 2001. Monetary policy with a
touch of basel. IMF Working Paper.
Clower, Robert W. 1967. A reconsideration of the microfoundations
of monetary theory. Western Economic Journal 6:1-9.
Cochrane, John H., and Monika Piazzesi. 2005. Bond risk premia.
American Economic Review 95:138-60.
Cook, Timothy Q., and Thomas Hahn. 1990. Interest rate expectations
and the slope of the money market yield curve. Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond Economic Review 76:3-26.
Cook, Timothy Q., and Robert K. LaRoche. 1993. The money market. In
Instruments of the money market, 7th edition, edited by Timothy Q. Cook
and Robert K. LaRoche. Richmond, VA: Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond,
pp. 1-6.
Cosimano, Thomas F. 1987. The federal funds market under bank
deregulation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 19:326-39.
Cosimano, Thomas F., and Richard G. Sheehan. 1994. Is the
conventional view of discount window borrowing consistent with the
behavior of weekly reporting banks? The Review of Economics and
Statistics 76:761-70.
Cosimano, Thomas F., and John B. Van Huyck. 1989. Dynamic monetary
control and interest rate stabilization. Journal of Monetary Economics
23:53-63.
Diebold, Francis X., Monika Piazzesi, and Glenn D. Rudebusch. 2005.
Modeling bond yields in finance and macroeconomics. American Economic
Review 95:415-20.
Dotsey, Michael, and Christopher Otrok. 1995. The rational
expectations hypothesis of the term structure, monetary policy, and
time-varying term premia. Federal Reserve Bunk of Richmond Economic
Quarterly 81:65-81.
Elyasiani, Elyas, Kenneth J. Kopecky, and David J. Van Hoose. 1995.
Costs of adjustment, portfolio separation, and the dynamic behavior of
bank loans and deposits. Journal of Money, Credit. and Banking
27:956-74.
Engle, Robert F., David M. Lilien, and Russell P. Robins. 1987.
Estimating time-varying risk premia in the term structure: The ARCH-M
model. Econometrica 55:391-407.
Evans, Martin D. D., and Karen K. Lewis. 1994. Do stationary risk
premia explain it all? Evidence from the term structure. Journal of
Monetary Economics 33:285-318.
Fama, Eugene F. 1984. The information in the term structure.
Journal of Financial Economics 13:509-28.
Fama, Eugene F., and Robert R. Bliss. 1987. The information in
long-maturity forward rates. American Economic Review 77:680-92.
Friedman, Benjamin M., and Kenneth N. Kuttner. 1992. Time-varying
risk perceptions and the pricing of risk assets. Oxford Economic Papers
44:566-98.
Froot, Kenneth A. 1989. New hope for the expectations hypothesis of
the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Finance 44:283-305.
Frost, Peter A. 1971. Banks' demand for excess reserves.
Journal of Political Economy 79:805-25.
Hamilton, James D. 1996. The daily market for federal funds.
Journal of Political Economy 104:26-56.
Hamilton, James D. 1998. The supply and demand for federal reserve
deposits. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 49:1-44.
Hansen, Lars P. 1982. Large sample properties of generalized method
of moments estimators. Econometrica 50:1029-54.
Hardouvelis, Gikas A. 1988. The predictive power of the term
structure during recent monetary regimes. Journal of Finance 43:339-56.
Kang, Imho. 1997. An analysis of the reserve market interpreting
vector autoregressions using a theoretical model. Ph.D. dissertation,
University of California at San Diego, San Diego, CA.
Kashyap, Anil K., Raghuram Rajan, and Jeremy C. Stein. 2002. Banks
as liquidity providers: An explanation for the coexistence of lending
and deposit-taking. Journal of Finance 57:33-73.
Kashyap, Anil K., Jeremy C. Stein, and David W. Wilcox. 1993.
Monetary policy and credit conditions: Evidence from the composition of
external finance. American Economic Review 83:78-98.
Kim, Dong Heon. 2003. Another look at yield spreads: The role of
liquidity. Economics Discussion Paper 0306, University of Manchester,
Manchester, UK.
Lee, Sang-Sub. 1995. Macroeconomic sources of time-varying risk
premia in the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 27:549-69.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1982. Interest rates and currency prices in a
two-country world. Journal of Monetary Economics 10:335-60.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., and Nancy L. Stokey. 1987. Money and
interest in a cash-in-advance economy. Econometrica 55:491-513.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, and Jeffrey A. Miron. 1986. The changing
behavior of the term structure of interest rates. Quarterly Journal of
Economics 101:211-28.
McCallum, Bennett T. 1994. Monetary policy and the term structure
of interest rate. NBER Working Paper No. 4938.
Mishkin, Frederic S. 1988. The information in the term structure:
Some further results. Journal of Applied Econometrics 3:307-14.
Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1987. A simple, positive
definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance
matrix. Econometrica 55:703-8.
Roberds, William, David Runkle, and Charles H. Whiteman. 1996. A
daily view of yield spreads and short-term interest rate movements.
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 28:35-53.
Roberds, William, and Charles H. Whiteman. 1999. Endogenous term
premia and anomalies in the term structure of interest rates: Explaining
the predictability smile. Journal of Monetary Economics 44:555-80.
Rudebusch, Glenn D. 1995. Federal reserve interest rate targeting,
rational expectations, and the term structure. Journal of Monetary
Economics 35:245-74.
Sarno, Lucio, Daniel L. Thornton, and Giorgio Valente. 2007. The
empirical failure of the expectations hypothesis of the term structure
of bond yields. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 42:81-100.
Shiller, Robert J., John Y. Campbell, and Kermit L. Schoenholtz.
1983. Forward rates and future policy: Interpreting the term structure
of interest rates. Brooking Papers on Economic Activity 1:173-217.
Simon, David P. 1989. Expectations and risk in the treasury bill
market: An instrumental variables approach. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 24:357-65.
Simon, David P. 1990. Expectations and the treasury bill-federal
funds rate spread over recent monetary policy regimes. Journal of
Finance 45:567-77.
Stigum, Marcia L. 1990. The money market. 3rd edition. New York:
Irwin Professional.
Svensson, Lars E. O. 1985. Money and asset prices in a
cash-in-advance economy. Journal of Political Economy 93:919-44.
Thornton, Daniel L. 2004. Testing the expectations hypothesis: Some
new evidence for Japan. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
86(5):21-39.
Thornton, Daniel L. 2006. Tests of the expectations hypothesis:
Resolving Campbell-Shiller paradox. Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking 38:511-42.
Wachter, Jessica A. 2006. A consumption-based model of the term
structure of interest rates. Journal of Financial Economies 79:365-99.
(1) Rudebusch (1995) refers to the 'U-shaped' pattern of
the predictability of the yield curve. Roberds and Whiteman (1999) state
the existence of a "predictability smile" in the term
structure of interest rates: Spreads between long maturity rates and
short rates predict subsequent movements in interest rates provided the
long horizon is three months or less or if the long horizon is two years
or more, but not for intermediate maturities.
(2) For recent EH tests based on VAR specification, see Bekaert and
Hodrick (2001), Thornton (2004), Bataa, Kim, and Osborn (2006), Bekaert,
Wei, and Xing (2007), and Sarno, Thornton, and Valente (2007).
(3) See Mankiw and Miron (1986), McCallum (1994), and Rudebusch
(1995) for the relation between the EH and Federal Reserve behavior.
(4) For a time-varying risk premium, see Engle, Lilien, and Robins
(1987), Simon (1989, 1990), Friedman and Kuttner (1992), and Lee (1995),
among others.
(5) Stigum (1990) states that "in the money market, in
particular, banks are players of such major importance that any serious
discussion of the various markets that comprise the money market must be
prefaced with a careful look at banking" (p. 117). Cook and LaRoche
(1993) also emphasize that commercial banks play an important role in
the money market. Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2002) argue that a bank
that offers liquidity on demand must invest in certain costly
"overhead" in order to carry out its job effectively and that
since banks often lend via commitments, their lending and deposit-taking
may be two manifestations of one primitive function the provision of
liquidity on demand. Their model shows that there is a synergy between
the two activities to the extent that both require banks to hold large
balances of liquidity assets.
(6) Detailed information on the amount of Treasuries of alternate
maturity held by banks is not available on the Flow of Funds. However,
commercial banks' holdings of securities account for 23% of bank
assets as of January 2006 (www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h8/current).
The volume of transactions of government securities by commercial banks
was about 20% in the money market in the 1980s (Stigum 1990).
(7) Since the paper draws attention to the role of liquidity in
determining the yield structure, it might be interesting to consider
incorporation of liquidity into a dynamic general equilibrium model. For
example, this idea can be extended to the situation where long-term
government bonds are less liquid than short-term government bonds, and
thus the liquidity difference might affect the yield structure of these
assets.
(8) Since most of the empirical term structure literature
concentrates on the term structure for government securities, our term
structure model might be limited for general application. Even so, the
key idea of what is meant by liquidity seems to provide a significant
implication for the term structure.
(9) We assume that interest income less default loss is paid out as
stockholder dividends, and so these terms do not affect the level of
reserves. In practice, federal funds interest is paid by banks a week
after the loan, and term loan interest is paid much later. Abstracting
from the effects of interest payments on reserves seems a useful
simplification, which is unlikely to matter for the results presented
here.
(10) The analysis of Anderson and Rasche (2001) suggests that the
willingness of bank regulators to permit use of deposit sweeping
software has made statutory reserve requirements a "voluntary
constraint" for most banks, and thus the economic burden of
statutory reserve requirements is zero.
(11) Chami and Cosimano (2001) point out that capital requirements have effectively replaced reserve requirements as the main constraint on
the behavior of banks and explore the implications of risk-based capital
requirements for monetary policy. From this point of view, an anonymous
referee raised an issue about the possibility that the result of the
paper would change as a result of the phase out of reserve requirements
in terms of Chami and Cosimano (2001). However, the CIA constraint (or
liquidity constraint) is neither reserve requirement nor capital
requirement in the spirit of replacement of liquidity needs, and thus
this issue might not erode qualitatively the role of the CIA constraint
in the model presented here.
(12) More details for the derivation of Equation 8-10 are provided
in the appendix of Kim (2003).
(13) Frost (1971) shows that banks hold excess reserves because the
cost associated with constantly adjusting reserve positions is greater
than the interest earned on short-term securities, and the profitability
of holding excess reserves when interest rates are very low makes the
banks' demand for excess reserves kinked at a low rate of interest.
In practice, excess reserves from the data for depository institution that are taken from Statistical Release provided by the Federal Reserve
Board of Governors are always positive during the sample period of our
empirical study. Therefore, our assumption is consistent with the U.S.
data over this sample period.
(14) The anonymous referee raised an issue about the possibility of
correlation between shocks in Equations 18-20. Indeed, we might consider
that the disturbance to the federal funds market affects immediately the
demand for the loan and thus the loan market. However, since we are not
focusing on the effect of structural shocks on the term structure, we
assume that these structural shocks are mutually independent.
(15) Because the Fed changed from lagged reserve accounting to
contemporaneous reserve accounting in February 1984, we use only data
after February 1984.
(16) These quantities of loans are loans and leases in bank credit
by weekly reporting banks. These quantities are slightly different
depending on all commercial banks, domestic commercial banks, and large
commercial banks. However, the estimation results were quantitatively
and qualitatively similar.
(17) The original CP rates are business-daily averages of offering
rates on CP placed by several leading dealers for firms whose bond
rating is AA or the equivalent. After we multiply Friday's interest
rate by three and use the value of the previous business day for
holidays, we construct weekly averages of seven-day series.
(18) Rudebusch (1995) provides an excellent survey of previous
empirical results.
(19) When we included lagged CP rate as an instrument on the
estimation of Equation 26, we rejected the null hypothesis of
Hansen's test, which implies that lagged CP rates are not valid
instruments. In addition, we estimated the equation using more lagged
federal funds rates and lagged quantities of new loans as instruments.
In some cases, we rejected the null hypothesis that the model is
correctly specified, but overall the estimated results were similar.
Dong Heon Kim, Department of Economics, Korea University, 5-1
Anam-dong, Seongbuk-Gu, Seoul, 136-701, South Korea; E-mail
[email protected], University of Manchester, UK.
Table 1. The Expectation Hypothesis Test without
Liquidity Premium and Risk Premium
1/n [n - 1.summation over (i = 0)] [r.sup.F.sub.t] =
[alpha] + [phi] ([r.sup.L.sub.n,t] - [r.sup.F.sub.t])
+ [[epsilon].sub.t]
Maturity [??] [??] [R.sup.2]
One-month CP -0.020 ** (0.009) 0.297 *** (0.083) 0.169
Three-month CP -0.052 * (0.028) 0.488 *** (0.082) 0.218
* The numbers in parentheses are Newey and West's (1987)
autocorrelation-heteroskedasticity consistent standard errors
corrected with four lags for one-month CP rate and 12 lags for
the three-month CP rate. ***, **, and * denote statistical
significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level in a two-tailed test,
respectively.
Table 2. The Expectations Hypothesis Test with Liquidity
Premium and Risk Premium: Two-Stage Least Squares Estimation
1/n [n-2.summation over (i = 0)] [r.sup.F.sub.t+i] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t] = [alpha] + [phi]([r.sup.L.sub.n, t] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t]) + [[gamma].sub.1][r.sup.F.sub.t-1] +
[[gamma].sub.2][L.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
Maturity [??] [??]
One-month CP -0.308 *** (0.069) 0.903 *** (0.172)
Three-month CP -0.385 *** (0.129) 0.989 *** (0.208)
1/n [n-2.summation over (i = 0)] [r.sup.F.sub.t+i] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t] = [alpha] + [phi]([r.sup.L.sub.n, t] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t]) + [[gamma].sub.1][r.sup.F.sub.t-1] +
[[gamma].sub.2][L.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
Maturity [[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.2]
One-month CP -0.206 *** (0.010) -0.005 (0.011)
Three-month CP -0.047 ** (0.021) 0.027 (0.019)
1/n [n-2.summation over (i = 0)] [r.sup.F.sub.t+i] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t] = [alpha] + [phi]([r.sup.L.sub.n, t] -
[r.sup.F.sub.t]) + [[gamma].sub.1][r.sup.F.sub.t-1] +
[[gamma].sub.2][L.sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t]
Maturity Instrument
One-month CP constant, [r.sup.F.sub.t-2], ..., [r.sup.F.sub.t-4],
[L.sub.t - 1]
Three-month CP constant, [r.sup.F.sub.t-1], ..., [r.sup.F.sub.t-4],
[L.sub.t - 2]
The numbers in parentheses are Newey and West's (1987)
autocorrelation-heteroskedasticity consistent standard
errors corrected with four lags
for the one-month CP rate and 12 lags for the three-month CP
rate. *** and ** denote statistical significance at the 1%
and 5% level in a two-tailed test of the null hypothesis that
the coefficient of the spread is zero, respectively. In addition,
the t-statistic for testing the null hypothesis that the coefficient
of the spread is unity is -0.564 for one-month CP rate and -0.053
for three-month CP rate, respectively.
Table 3. The Expectations Hypothesis Test with Liquidity
Premium and Risk Premium: Federal Funds Rate and the ED Rates
Model Maturity [??] [??]
M. I One-month -0.033 *** (0.009) 0.334 *** (0.094)
Three-month -0.107 *** (0.024) 0.457 *** (0.094)
M. II One-month -0.080 (0.050) 0.813 *** (0.148)
Three-month -0.023 (0.085) 0.972 *** (0.105)
Model Maturity [[??].sub.1] [[??].sub.2]
M. I One-month
Three-month
M. II One-month -0.250 *** (0.006) 0.004 (0.011)
Three-month -0.114 *** (0.015) 0.005 (0.006)
Model Maturity Instrument
M. I One-month
Three-month
M. II One-month constant, [r.sup.F.sub.t-2],
..., [r.sup.F.sub.t-4], [L.sub.t-1]
Three-month constant, [r.sup.F.sub.t-2],
..., [r.sup.F.sub.t-12], [L.sub.t-2]
The numbers in parentheses are Newey and West's (1987) autocorrelation-
heteroskedasticity consistent standard errors corrected with four lags
for the one-month ED rate and 12 lags for the three-month ED rate. ***
denotes statistical significance at the 1% level in a two-tailed test.
M.I and M.II denote the Model I in Equation 24 and the Model II in
Equation 26, respectively.