The Great Moderation and the relationship between output growth and its volatility.
Fang, Wen-Shwo ; Miller, Stephen M.
1. Introduction
Macroeconomic volatility has declined substantially over the past
20 years. Kim and Nelson (1999), McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000),
Blanchard and Simon (2001), Stock and Watson (2003), and Ahmed, Levin,
and Wilson (2004), among others, have documented this Great Moderation
in the volatility of U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) growth. Moreover,
the current Federal Reserve Board Chairman Bernanke (2004) also
addressed this issue. Most research focuses on the causes of the Great
Moderation, such as good policies, structural change, good luck, or
output composition shifts. (1) This paper empirically investigates the
effect of the Great Moderation on the relationship between the output
growth rate and its volatility. (2)
Macroeconomists have long focused on business cycles and economic
growth. Recently, increasing attention has been paid to the relationship
between business cycle volatility and the long-run trend in growth.
Alternative models give rise to negative, positive, or independent
relationships between the output growth rate and its volatility. For
example, the misperceptions theory, proposed originally by Friedman
(1968), Phelps (1968), and Lucas (1972), argues that output fluctuations
around its natural rate reflect price misperceptions due to monetary
shocks, whilst the long-run growth rate of potential output reflects
technology and other real factors. The standard dichotomy in
macroeconomics implies no relationship between the output growth rate
and its volatility.
Bernanke (1983) and Pindyck (1991) demonstrated that
irreversibility makes investment especially sensitive to various forms
of risk. Output volatility generates risk about future demand that
impedes investment, leading to a negative relationship between output
volatility and growth. Martin and Rogers (1997) argued that
learning-by-doing generates growth whereby production complements
productivity-improving activities and stabilization policy can
positively affect human capital accumulation and growth. One natural
conclusion, therefore, implies that short-term economic instability can
prove detrimental to human capital accumulation and growth (Martin and
Rogers 2000).
In contrast, Black (1987) argued that technology comes with varying
levels of risk and expected returns that are associated with the degree
of specialization. More specialization means more output volatility.
Investment occurs in specialized technologies only if expected returns
sufficiently compensate for associated risk. Thus, when high expected
return technologies emerge, high output volatility and high growth
coexist. Mirman (1971) argued that higher output volatility leads to
higher precautionary saving, implying a positive relationship between
output volatility and growth. Bean (1990) and Saint-Paul (1993) showed
that the opportunity cost of productivity-improving activities falls in
recessions, implying that higher output volatility may positively affect
growth. According to Blackburn (1999), a relative increase in the
volatility of shocks increases the pace of knowledge accumulation and,
hence, growth, implying a positive relation between output variability
and long-term growth.
In a simple stochastic growth model, Blackburn and Galindev (2003)
illustrated that different mechanisms of endogenous technological change
can lead to different implications for the relationship between output
variability and growth. Generally, the relationship is more likely to
exhibit a positive correlation if internal learning drives technological
change through deliberate actions that substitute for production
activities. The relationship exhibits a negative correlation if external
learning drives technological change through nondeliberate actions that
complement production activity. Blackburn and Pelloni (2004) predicted
that real shocks generate a positive correlation between output
variability and growth, and nominal shocks produce a negative
relationship.
The statistical evidence also exhibits ambiguity. The empirical
literature presents two approaches. Using cross-country data, Kormendi
and Meguire (1985) and Grier and Tullock (1989) found a positive
relationship between growth and its standard deviation, but Ramey and
Ramey (1995), Miller (1996), Martin and Rogers (2000), and Kneller and
Young (2001) reported a negative relationship. More recently, Rafferty
(2005) discovered that unexpected volatility reduced growth and expected
volatility increased it, while the combined effect of expected and
unexpected volatility reduced growth.
Applying generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity in mean (GARCH-M) models, Caporale and McKiernan (1996, 1998) found a
positive relationship between output volatility and growth for the
United Kingdom and the United States, whereas Fountas and Karanasos
(2006) found a positive relationship for Germany and Japan. Speight
(1999), Grier and Perry (2000), and Fountas and Karanasos (2006),
however, concluded that no relationship exists in the United Kingdom and
the United States. In contrast, Macri and Sinha (2000) and Henry and
Olekalns (2002) discovered a negative link between volatility and growth
for Australia and the United States.
The lack of robust evidence concerning the relationship between the
output growth rate and its volatility motivates our analysis. While many
empirical studies employ postwar data, no one explicitly considers the
effect of the Great Moderation on this relationship. (3) The volatility
of U.S. GDP growth has fallen by more than half since the early to
mid-1980s. Although no agreement exists on the causes of the Great
Moderation, the reduced volatility implies that empirical models for
output growth over periods that span the break may experience model
misspecification.
In addition to considering the relationship between the output
growth rate and its volatility, we first consider the possibility that
structural change affects the process(es) generating the volatility of
output growth. Deibold (1986) first raised the concern that structural
changes may confound persistence estimation in GARCH models. He noted
that Engle and Bollerslev's (1986) integrated GARCH (IGARCH) values
may result from instability in the constant term of the conditional
variance, that is, nonstationarity of the unconditional variance.
Neglecting such changes can lead to spuriously measured persistence; the
sum of the estimated autoregressive parameters of the conditional
variance is heavily biased towards one. Lamoureux and Lastrapes (1990)
explored Diebold's conjecture and provided confirmation that the
failure to account for discrete shifts in unconditional variance, the
misspecification of the GARCH model, can produce an upward bias in GARCH
estimates of persistence in variance, and this vitiates the usefulness
of GARCH when the degree of persistence proves important. The longer the
sample period, the higher is the probability that such changes will
occur. Inclusion of dummy variables to account for such shifts
diminishes the degree of GARCH persistence. More recently, Mikosch and
Starica (2004) argued theoretically that the IGARCH model makes sense
when nonstationarity data reflect changes in the unconditional variance.
Hillebrand (2005) showed that in the presence of neglected parameter change points, even a single deterministic change point, GARCH
inappropriately measures volatility persistence. Before carrying out
GARCH estimations, we performed a thorough change-point study of the
data to avoid the spurious effect of almost-integration.
The identification of change points will occur endogenously in the
data-generating process. We employed Inclan and Tiao's (1994)
iterated cumulative sums of squares (ICSS) algorithm to detect sudden
changes in the variance of output growth, as well as the time point and
magnitude of each detected change in the variance. (4) The algorithm
finds one change point at 1982:I, two years earlier than that of 1984:I
in McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000). Most analysts argue that the break
date occurred some time in the early to mid-1980s, but the exact timing
of the decline remains controversial. For example, Blanchard and Simon
(2001) analyzed the large decline in U.S. output volatility starting in
1982:I.
This paper employs GARCH-M and ARCH-M models to examine the effect
of the Great Moderation on the volatility-growth relationship over the
period 1947:I to 2006:IV with the break date of 1982:I. Our empirical
results show strong evidence of IGARCH effects and no evidence of
significant links between volatility and growth for the United States.
Moreover, the time-varying variance falls sharply or even disappears
once we allow for the structural break in the unconditional variance of
output growth. That is, the IGARCH effect proves spurious due to the
Great Moderation. These results prove robust to the alternative break
1984:I. Section 2 discusses the data and the Great Moderation in output
volatility. Section 3 presents the methodology and empirical results.
Section 4 considers additional evidence, and section 5 concludes.
2. Data and the Great Moderation
Output growth rates ([y.sub.t]) equal the percentage change in the
logarithm of seasonally adjusted quarterly real GDP ([Y.sub.t]),
measured in billions of chained 2000 dollars, which come from the U.S.
Bureau of Economic Analysis over the period 1947:I to 2006:II. A rather
dramatic reduction in output volatility in the most recent two decades
relative to the previous four produces the most striking observation.
McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000), applying tests of Andrews (1993) and
Andrews and Ploberger (1994), detected a unique break in the variance of
the growth rate in 1984:I for the sample 1953:II to 1999:II and no break
in the mean growth rate. This paper extends the data from 1947:I to
2006:II.
As discussed earlier, the methodology used in this study to detect
structural changes in the variance employs the ICSS algorithm described
by Inclan and Tiao (1994). The analysis assumes that the time series of
output growth displays a stationary variance over an initial period, and
then a sudden change in variance occurs. The variance then exhibits
stationarity again for a time, until the next sudden change. The process
repeats through time, yielding a time series of observations with an
unknown number of changes in the variance.
Let {[[epsilon].sub.t]} denote a series of independent observations
from a normal distribution with mean zero and unconditional variance.
When N variance changes occur in T observations, 1 < [k.sub.1] <
[k.sub.2] < ... < [k.sub.N] < T is equal to the set of change
points. Let [C.sub.k] equal the cumulative sum of the squared
observations from the start of the series to the [k.sup.th] point in
time (i.e., [C.sub.k] = [[summation].sup.k.sub.t = 1]
[[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t], k = 1, ..., T). Then, define [D.sub.k] as:
[D.sub.k] = [C.sub.k]|[C.sub.T]) - k|T, k = 1,..., T, with [D.sub.0] =
[D.sub.T] = 0. If no changes in variance occur over the sample period,
the [D.sub.k] statistic oscillates around zero. If one or more sudden
variance changes exist in the series, then the [D.sub.k] values drift
either up or down from zero. Critical values based on the distribution
of [D.sub.k] under the null hypothesis of homogeneous variance provide
upper and lower boundaries to detect a significant change in variance
with a known level of probability. When the maximum of the absolute
value of [D.sub.k] exceeds the critical value, we reject the null
hypothesis of no changes. Let [k.sup.*] equal the value of k for which
[max.sub.k]|[D.sub.k]| occurs. If [max.sub.k][(T/2).sup.0.5] [absolute
value of [D.sub.k]] exceeds the predetermined boundary, then k provides
an estimate of the change point. The factor [(T/2).sup.0.5] standardizes
the distribution. Under the null, [D.sub.k] asymptotically behaves as a
Brownian bridge. The critical value of 1.36 defines the 95th percentile of the asymptotic distribution of [max.sub.k][(T/2).sup.0.5] [absolute
value of [D.sub.k]]. Therefore, upper and lower boundaries occur at [+
or -] 1.36 in the [D.sub.k] plot. If these boundaries are exceeded, this
marks a significant change in variance of output. To examine multiple
change points, the ICSS algorithm successively evaluates [D.sub.k] at
different parts of the series, dividing consecutively after finding a
possible change point.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The procedure identifies one, and only one, change point at 1982:I.
That is, the shift lasts to the end of our sample period, and there are
no breaks in other periods. Figure 1 plots the series of real GDP and
its growth rate and marks the break with a gray area. We further conduct
structural stability tests for the unconditional mean and variance of
the growth rate by splitting the sample into two subperiods: 1947:I to
1981:IV and 1982:I to 2006:1I. For the unconditional mean, a t statistic tests for the equality of means for two different samples, while a
variance-ratio statistic tests for the equality of the unconditional
variances.
Table 1 reports descriptive statistics for the data and the results
of the structural stability tests. The mean growth rate in each
subsample nearly equals the 0.8358% growth rate average for the full
60-year sample. The t statistics, which test for structural change in
the mean between the samples, cannot reject the null hypothesis of
equality of means. In contrast, a clear decline in the standard
deviation of the growth rate occurs, equaling 1.1844% per quarter in the
pre-1982 period and 0.6094% in the post-1982 period, a decline of 49%.
The p values for the variance-ratio F-test significantly reject the null
of variance equality between the samples. Economists term the
substantial drop in the variance of output in the post-1982 period the
Great Moderation. Skewness statistics support symmetric distributions
for the full and pre-1982 sample periods, but not the post-1982 period.
Kurtosis statistics suggest that the full and post-1982 sample series
exhibit leptokurticity with fat tails. Consequently, Jarque-Bera tests reject normality for these two samples but cannot reject normal
distributions in the pre-1982 subsample. The Ljung-Box Q-statistics
(LBQ), testing for autocorrelation of up to six lags, indicate serial
correlation in growth for all three periods. The Lagrange multiplier statistics (LM) test for ARCH effects (Engle 1982) up to six lags,
suggesting a time-varying variance in output growth for the full and
post-1982 sample periods and no heteroscedasticity in the pre-1982
period. The augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit-root test implies that
the growth rate exhibits stationarity for each of the three samples.
Useful information emerges that can assist in model building and
verification stages. First, the evidence of autocorrelation suggests an
autoregressive moving-average (ARMA) model for the mean growth equation
to capture temporal dependence and to generate white-noise residuals for
all three periods. Second, the emergence of a time-varying variance
argues for GARCH-M and ARCH-M models to examine the effect of volatility
on growth. The robustness of this conclusion to the Great Moderation,
however, requires the allowance for a one-time shift in the
unconditional variance. Third, no heteroscedasticity in the pre-1982
subperiod suggests the use of other volatility measures such as a
moving-sample standard deviation to examine the effect for the
subsample. Fourth, and most importantly, the significant decline in the
variance combined with no change of the mean growth rate in the
post-1982 subperiod may imply a weak relationship between volatility and
growth.
3. Methodology and Empirical Results
We first constructed an ARMA model for the growth series to remove
any linear dependence in the data, and then we added output volatility
as an explanatory variable in the mean equation. Based on Schwarz
Criterion, an AR(2) process proves adequate to capture growth dynamics
and produces white-noise residuals for all the three sample periods. The
mean growth equation equals the following:
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] + [a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2]
+ [[lambda][sigma].sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.t], (1)
where the growth rate is [y.sub.t] [equivalent to] 100 x (ln
[Y.sub.t] -ln [Y.sub.t-1]), where In [Y.sub.t] equals the natural
logarithm of real GDP; [[epsilon].sub.t], equals the white-noise random
error; and [[sigma].sub.t] equals a measure of output volatility. The
estimate of [lambda] may exceed or fall below zero and prove significant
or insignificant.
We now derive an operational measure for output volatility. The
descriptive statistics show that ARCH effects emerge in the full and
post-1982 sample periods. The GARCH(1,1) specification proves adequate
to represent most financial and economic time series (Bollerslev, Engle,
and Nelson 1994). For example, Caporale and McKiernan (1996), Speight
(1999), Grier and Perry (2000), Henry and Olekalns (2002), and Fountas
and Karanasos (2006) used this process to parameterize the time-varying
conditional variance of output growth. Caporale and McKiernan (1998) and
Macri and Sinha (2000), however, used ARCH(l) to examine the time
dependence of the conditional variance. To provide more evidence, we
employed both GARCH(1,1) and ARCH(2) models to account for periods of
high- and low-output volatility for our samples as follows:
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] + [[beta].sub.1]
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.t-1], (2)
and
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] = [[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[alpha].sub.2][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-2], (3)
where Equations 2 and 3 equal the GARCH(1,1) and ARCH(2)
specifications, and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] equals the conditional
variance of the growth rate given the information available at time t -
1. The presence of the square root of [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t],
[[sigma].sub.t], in the mean equation of the growth rate makes Equations
1 and 2 or 3 a GARCH-M or an ARCH-M model (Engle, Lilien, and Robins
1987). The conditions that [[alpha].sub.i] [greater than or equal to]
0, [[beta].sub.i] [greater than or equal to] 0, and [[alpha].sub.1] +
[[beta].sub.1] < 1 in the GARCH model or [[alpha].sub.1] +
[[alpha].sub.2] < 1 in the ARCH model ensure positive and stable
conditional variances of [[epsilon].sub.t]. The sums, [[alpha].sub.1] +
[[beta].sub.1] or [[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha].sub.2], measure the
persistence of shocks to the conditional variances. Evidence of an
integrated GARCH (IGARCH), or, in general, evidence of high persistence,
proves analogous to a unit root in the mean of a stochastic process.
This persistence may result from occasional level shifts in volatility.
If [[beta].sub.1] (or [[alpha].sub.2]) equals zero, the process reduces
to an ARCH(l). When [[alpha].sub.1] and [[beta].sub.1] (or
[[alpha].sub.2]) both equal zero, the variance equals a constant. We
estimated each of the models using maximum likelihood under normality
and using the Berndt et al. (1974) algorithm.
For the pre-1982 subperiod, since we did not find time-varying
variance, we also constructed a moving-sample standard deviation to
measure output volatility for 1947:I to 1981:IV as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
where we selected m = 4, 8, and 12 as the orders of the moving
average. The choice of the moving-average order does not affect the
results, however.
Table 2 reports the estimation results of our GARCH-M and ARCH-M
models for the full sample with standard errors in parentheses, p values
in brackets, and statistics for the standardized residuals. In the mean
equation, AR(2) estimates verify significance at the 5% level, lending
support to the autoregressive specification. The coefficient of the
conditional standard deviation ([lambda]) possesses no statistical
significance. Each estimate in the variance equation exceeds zero. The
volatility persistence of 0.9961 in the GARCH and 0.6837 in the ARCH
process, however, proves high. The likelihood ratio (LR) tests for
[[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] = 1 in the GARCH and [[alpha].sub.1] +
[[alpha].sub.2] = 1 in the ARCH process, respectively, and does not
reject the null hypothesis of an IGARCH effect at the 5% level. It does
reject the IGARCH effect for the ARCH process, however, at the nearly
10% level. The fitted models adequately capture the time-series
properties of the data in that the Ljung-Box Q-statistics for
standardized residuals (LB Q) and standardized squared residuals (LB
[Q.sup.2]), up to six lags, do not detect remaining autocorrelation and
conditional heteroscedasticity. The standardized residuals exhibit
symmetric distributions, but with significant excess kurtosis. Thus,
they do not exhibit the characteristics of a normal distribution, as
observed in Table 1.
The insignificant estimate of the conditional standard deviation
([lambda]) in the mean equation implies no relationship between output
growth and its volatility. This result conforms to Friedman's
(1968), Phelps's (1968), and Lucas's (1972) misperceptions
hypothesis and the previous empirical findings, using GARCH-M models, of
Grief and Perry (2000) and Fountas and Karanasos (2006) for the United
States and Speight (1999) for the United Kingdom. This finding, however,
proves inconsistent with the discovery of a positive relationship by
Caporale and McKiernan (1996, 1998) for the United Kingdom and the
United States, and by Fountas and Karanasos (2006) for Germany and
Japan, as well as the discovery by Macri and Sinha (2000) and Henry and
Olekalns (2002) of a negative relationship for Australia and the United
States.
Although different countries, sample periods, data frequencies, or
econometric models may lead to different findings, two issues emerge
from the empirical results. First, existing research efforts do not
limit the phenomenon of the Great Moderation to U.S. output only. Mills
and Wang (2003) and Summers (2005) found structural breaks in the
volatility of the output growth rate for the G7 countries and Australia,
although the break occurred at different times. The well-documented
moderation in the volatility of GDP growth in the United States and
other developed nations suggests that the finding of (G)ARCH-M effects
and volatility persistence may prove spurious, since researchers have
failed to account for the structural change in the variance. (5)
Lastrapes (1989) showed that changes in the unconditional variance
should receive consideration when specifying ARCH models. In his study,
for instance, the persistence of volatility in exchange rates decreased
after accounting for three U.S. monetary policy regime shifts between
1976 and 1986, diminishing the likelihood of integration-in variance.
Tzavalis and Wickens (1995) found strong evidence of a high degree of
persistence in the volatility of the term premium of bonds. Once they
allowed for the monetary regime shift between 1979 and 1982, the high
persistence in the GARCH(1,1)-M model disappeared. Poterba and Summers
(1986) noted that the degree of persistence in variance of a variable
importantly affects the relationship between the variable and its
volatility, for example, stock returns and their volatility.
Second, the significant statistical property of excess kurtosis
provides a cautionary note. Kurtosis for the standardized residuals
(i.e., [[epsilon].sub.t]/[[sigma].sub.t]) generally falls below that for
the unconditional standard deviation (see Tables 1 and 2). According to
the distributional assumptions in the (G)ARCH specification, the
standardized residuals should reflect a normal distribution, if the
(G)ARCH model totally accounts for the leptokurtic unconditional
distribution. The sample kurtosis in Table 2 for the standardized
residuals indicates that (G)ARCH accounts for some, but not all, of the
leptokurtosis for the output growth rate. (6) Blanchard and Simon (2001)
noted that the distribution of output growth exhibits excess kurtosis
(or skewness) if large and infrequent shocks occur. This suggests that
the evidence of excess kurtosis may also reflect the Great Moderation.
Thus, we expected to resolve the two puzzles by modeling the
nonstationarity variance arising from the Great Moderation. First, the
high persistence of output volatility decreases after accounting for the
Great Moderation, diminishing the likelihood of biasing the sum of the
estimated autoregressive parameters toward one. Second, leptokurtosis in
the unconditional distribution of output growth vanishes after
adjustment for (G)ARCH with conditional normality.
To consider the effect of the Great Moderation on the variance of
output in the GARCHM specification, we included a dummy variable in the
conditional variance equation, which equals unity after 1982:I and is
zero otherwise. To provide more evidence regarding the effect of the
Great Moderation, we also estimated the variance process with the break
date 1984:I.
Table 3 reports the new estimates, showing that the structural
dummy proves highly significant in the variance equation in all four
cases. The substantial and significant increase of the value of the
maximum log-likelihood indicates that including the dummy in the (G)ARCH
equation provides a superior specification. The log-likelihood ratio
test statistics (i.e., [chi square][1] = 24.77 for the GARCH-M or [chi
square][1] = 41.64 for the ARCH-M) prove significant at the 1% level.
Based on the log-likelihood values, the two models perform almost
equally well. The Ljung-Box Q-statistics of the standardized residuals
and the squared standardized residuals show no evidence of
autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity, providing further support for
these specifications. The coefficients of skewness and excess kurtosis
prove insignificant at the 5% level. (7) Thus, the standardized
residuals conform to a normal distribution. All results prove robust to
the choice of the alternative break at 1984:I, as shown in Table 3. (8)
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The estimate of [lambda] remains insignificant. That is, no
relationship exists between growth and volatility measured by the two
GARCH-M models with two different break dates. Two important
consequences emerge from allowing for a structural change in the
conditional variance. First, a large decline occurs in the estimated
degree of persistence in the conditional variance. Each estimate in the
variance equation in Table 3 falls below that in the model without the
dummy in Table 2. The highly significant LR statistic in Table 3 proves
no IGARCH effect. In addition, the estimates of [[alpha].sub.1] and
[[beta].sub.1], or [[alpha].sub.1] and [[alpha].sub.2], not only fall in
size but also become insignificant in the specification that includes
the post-1984 dummy variable. The dummy variable replaces the (G)ARCH
effects. Second, a strong interaction emerges between the dummy variable
and the excess kurtosis, which previously proved significant (see Tables
1 and 2). This interaction now proves insignificant. These results
suggest that the statistical evidence for time-varying variance and for
excess kurtosis in the growth rate may reflect a shift in the
unconditional variance caused by the Great Moderation. Figures 2-5 plot
the conditional variances with and without a dummy for the four models,
respectively. The solid line includes the dummy variable, while the
dashed line excludes the dummy variable. One common characteristic
appears in the four figures--a clear shift in the variance. The high
volatility appears in the period before 1982 or 1984.
The structural break for the Great Moderation in 1982:I (or 1984:I)
suggests that we should divide the sample into pre- and post-1982 (or
post-1984) groups to estimate the relationship between the growth rate
and its volatility separately for each period. Since the descriptive
statistics indicate no time-varying variance in the growth series for
three sub-samples (pre- and post-1984 and pre-1982), we constructed a
moving-sample standard deviation to proxy for output volatility and used
ordinary least squares (OLS) to estimate the relationship. For the
post-1982 period, higher-order ARCH tests yield insignificant results in
Table 1, suggesting the appropriateness of a simple ARCH(I) model. (9)
Table 4 presents the results. For the two periods 1947:I to 1981:IV and
1947:I to 1983:IV, the coefficient of the autoregressive term at lag two
proves insignificant. Thus, we report the estimation results for an
autoregressive model with only one lag. The Ljung-Box diagnostic
statistics show no evidence of first- and second-order autocorrelation
in the residuals for the four subsamples, and the residuals reflect a
normal distribution. The insignificant estimate of X again verifies our
earlier finding that no relationship exists between the growth rate and
its volatility in the United States. (10)
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
4. Further Evidence
This section considers two additional tests. First, we examined the
possibility that the output growth rate affects its volatility,
exploring whether an endogeneity bias exists in the GARCH and ARCH
processes. Second, we studied whether a trend decrease in the volatility
of output growth provided a better specification than the one-time shift
considered previously. The first test follows the analysis of Fountas
and Karanasos (2006), while the second test addresses the conclusion of
Blanchard and Simon (2001).
Fountas and Karanasos (2006) recently found, using annual
industrial production data from 1860 to 1999, that the output growth
rate volatility exhibits no effect on the growth rate, but the output
growth rate affects its volatility negatively in the United States, and
bidirectional causality occurs between output growth and its volatility
in Germany. The causal relationship between the output growth rate and
its volatility suggests that the GARCH-M approach suffers from an
endogeneity bias. Fountas and Karanasos (2006) included lagged growth in
the conditional variance equation (the level effect) to test for the
effect of growth on volatility in their GARCH(1,1)-M model. Following
this specification, Table 5 reports the GARCH(1,1)-M estimation results,
where we consider this level effect. The insignificance of [lambda]
continues, even while the lagged growth estimate ([delta]) proves
significant in the variance equation for either break date, 1982:I or
1984:I. All other estimates and diagnostic statistics closely mirror
those in the models without this level effect. The findings that the
output growth rate does not depend on changes in its volatility and that
the output growth rate does affect its volatility negatively prove
consistent with evidence in Fountas and Karanasos (2006), although they
employed the long series of annual output data and we used quarterly
data.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Blanchard and Simon (2001) argued that a trend decline in the
volatility of output growth provides a better explanation of output
growth volatility than does the one-time shift. Tables 6 and 7 present
the evidence. Table 6 introduces a time trend in specifications of the
GARCH and ARCH processes, but without a one-time shift dummy variable.
The coefficient of the time trend proves negative for both
specifications, although it is only significantly negative at the 5%
level in the ARCH process. All other coefficients and diagnostic
statistics closely mirror those in the models estimated without the time
trend or the one-time shift dummy variable (see Table 2). One exception
exists: The LR statistic now proves significant at the 5% level when the
time trend appears, which rejects the null hypothesis of an IGARCH.
Furthermore, although the volatility persistence falls substantially
with the time trend, excess kurtosis remains. Thus, the time trend
captures some, but not all, of the time-varying property of the
variance. Finally, the volatility measure remains insignificant in the
growth rate equation, matching the results of Tables 2 and 3.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Table 7 includes the time trend and the one-time shift dummy
variable together in the GARCH and ARCH processes. In all four models,
the coefficient of the time trend proves insignificant. Moreover, the
coefficient of the one-time shift dummy variable proves significantly
negative in each specification. All remaining coefficients and
diagnostic statistics nearly match those in Table 3, including the
insignificant coefficient of the variance measure in the growth rate
equation.
In summary, the one-time shift dummy variable dominates the time
trend across our various tests. That is, based on the log-likelihood
value, the corresponding specifications in Tables 3 and 7 do not exhibit
significant differences, whereas the corresponding specifications in
Tables 2 and 6 do exhibit significant differences compared to those in
Tables 3 and 7.
5. Conclusion
This paper examines the effect of the Great Moderation on the
relationship between quarterly real GDP growth rate and its volatility
in the United States over the period 1947:I to 2006:II. We began by
considering the possible effects, if any, of structural change on the
volatility process. Our initial results, based on either a GARCH-M or an
ARCH-M model of the conditional variance of the residuals, showed strong
evidence of volatility persistence and excess kurtosis in the growth
rate. Subsequent analysis revealed that this conclusion was not robust
to a one-time shift in output variability due to the Great Moderation.
First, the findings of a time-varying variance measured by the GARCH-M
or ARCH-M model disappeared in the specifications that included the
post-1984 dummy variable. That is, the GARCH effect proved spurious. In
any case, no GARCH-M effect emerged. Second, excess kurtosis vanished in
the specifications that included either the 1982 or the 1984 dummy
variable in either the GARCH or the ARCH process. Both the data analysis
and the OLS estimates generally suggested no relationship between U.S.
output volatility and growth, favoring macroeconomic models that
dichotomize the determination of output volatility and growth. In sum,
our results add to the conclusion that the relationship between the
output growth rate and its volatility in the United States proves weak,
at best.
The independence between the output growth and its volatility needs
careful interpretation. Endogenous growth theory, for example, does not
imply any importance for the second moment. Blackburn and Galindev
(2003) and Blackburn and Pelloni (2004) modeled the link between the
mean and variance of the output growth rate explicitly. Different
mechanisms of endogenous technological change and nominal or real shocks
can lead to a positive or negative relationship between growth and
volatility. In his model, Blackburn (1999) showed that, for a linear
endogenous learning function, the effect of the output growth rate
volatility on the output growth rate equals zero. A concave (convex)
learning function generates a negative (positive) effect. That is, an
independent relationship may exist with or without the Great Moderation.
The discrepancy of our findings from those in previous studies
highlights the sensitivity of the results to the country considered, the
time period examined, the frequency of the data, and the methodology
employed. This apparent inconclusiveness warrants further investigation
of the relationship between growth and its volatility. Moreover, since
studies generally focus on developed countries, additional analysis from
developing countries may prove illuminating. For example, the Asian
newly industrializing countries may provide totally different scenarios
because of their high growth rates.
We acknowledge the helpful comments of the editor and two anonymous
referees.
Received September 2006; accepted February 2007.
References
Aggarwal, Reena, Carla Inclan, and Ricardo Leal. 1999. Volatility
in emerging stock markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 34:33-55.
Ahmed, Shaghil, Andrew Levin, and Beth Anne Wilson. 2004. Recent
U.S. macroeconomic stability: Good policies, good practices, or good
luck? Review of Economics and Statistics 86:824-32.
Andrews, Donald W. K. 1993. Test for parameter instability and
structural change with unknown change point. Econometrica 61:821-56.
Andrews, Donald W. K., and Werner Ploberger. 1994. Optimal tests
when a nuisance parameter is present only under the alternative.
Econometrica 62:1383-414.
Bean, Charles R. 1990. Endogenous growth and the pro-cyclical
behaviour of productivity. European Economic Review 34:355-94.
Bernanke, Ben S. 1983. Irreversibility, uncertainty, and cyclical investment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 98:85-106.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2004. The Great Moderation. Lecture at Eastern
Economic Association, Washington, February 20, 2004.
Berndt, E. K., B. H. Hall, R. E. Hall, and J. A. Hausmann. 1974.
Estimation and inference in nonlinear structural models. Annals of
Economic and Social Measurement 4:653-65.
Black, Fisher. 1987. Business cycles and equilibrium. New York:
Basil Blackwell.
Blackburn, Keith. 1999. Can stabilization policy reduce long-run
growth? Economic Journal 109:67-77.
Blackburn, Keith, and Ragchaasuren Galindev. 2003. Growth,
volatility and learning. Economics Letters 79:417-21.
Blackburn, Keith, and Alessandra Pelloni. 2004. On the relationship
between growth and volatility. Economics Letters 83:123-7.
Blanchard, Olivier, and John Simon. 2001. The long and large
decline in U.S. output volatility. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
32:135-74.
Bollerslev, Tim, Robert F. Engle, and Daniel B. Nelson. 1994. ARCH
model. In Handbook of econometrics IV, edited by Robert F. Engle and
Daniel C. McFadden. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, pp. 2959-3038.
Caporale, Tony, and Barbara McKiernan. 1996. The relationship
between output variability and growth: Evidence from postwar UK data.
Scottish Journal of Political Economy 43:229-36.
Caporale, Tony, and Barbara McKiernan. 1998. The Fischer Black hypothesis: Some time-series evidence. Southern Economic Journal
63:765-71.
Diebold, Francis X. 1986. Comments on modelling the persistence of
conditional variance. Econometric Reviews 5:51-6.
Eggers, Andrew, and Yannis M. Ioannides. 2006. The role of output
composition in the stabilization of US output growth. Journal of
Macroeconomics 28:585-95.
Engle, Robert F. 1982. Autoregressive conditional
heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom
inflation. Econometrica 50:987-1007.
Engle, Robert F., and Tim Bollerslev. 1986. Modelling the
persistence of conditional variance. Econometric Reviews 5:1-50.
Engle, Robert F., David M. Lilien, and Russell P. Robins. 1987.
Estimating time varying risk premia in the term structure: The ARCH-M
model. Econometrica 55:391-407.
Fountas, Stilianos, and Menelaos Karanasos. 2006. The relationship
between economic growth and real uncertainty in the G3. Economic
Modelling 23:638-47.
Friedman, Milton. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American
Economic Review 58:1-17.
Grier, Kevin B., and Mark J. Perry. 2000. The effects of real and
nominal uncertainty on inflation and output growth: Some GARCH-M
evidence. Journal of Applied Econometrics 15:45-58.
Grief, Kevin B., and Gordon Tullock. 1989. An empirical analysis of
cross-national economic growth, 1951 80. Journal of Monetary Economics
24:259-76.
Henry, Olan T., and Nilss Olekalns. 2002. The effect of recessions
on the relationship between output variability and growth. Southern
Economic Journal 68:683-92.
Hillebrand, Eric. 2005. Neglecting parameter changes in GARCH
models. Journal of Econometrics 129:121-38.
Inclan, Carla, and George C. Tiao. 1994. Use of cumulative sums of
squares for retrospective detection of changes of variance. Journal of
the American Statistical Association 89:913-23.
Kim, Chang-Jin, and Charles R. Nelson. 1999. Has the U.S. economy
become more stable? A Bayesian approach based on a Markov-switching
model of the business cycle. Review of Economies and Statistics
81:608-16.
Kneller, Richard, and Garry Young. 2001. Business cycle volatility,
uncertainty and long-run growth. Manchester School 69:534-52.
Kormendi, Roger, and Philip G. Meguire. 1985. Macroeconomic
determinants of growth: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Monetary
Economics 16:141-63.
Lamoureux, Christopher G., and William D. Lastrapes. 1990.
Persistence in variance, structural change and the GARCH model. Journal
of Business and Economic Statistics 68:225-34.
Lastrapes, William D. 1989. Exchange rate volatility and U.S.
monetary policy: An ARCH application. Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking 21:66-77.
Lucas, Robert E. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money.
Journal of Economic Theory 4:103-24. Macri, Joseph, and Dipendra Sinha.
2000. Output variability and economic growth: The case of Australia.
Journal of Economics and Finance 24:275-82.
Martin, Philippe, and Carol Ann Rogers. 1997. Stabilization policy,
learning by doing, and economic growth. Oxford Economic Papers
49:152-66.
Martin, Philippe, and Carol Ann Rogers. 2000. Long-term growth and
short-term economic instability. European Economic Review 44:359-81.
McConnell, Margaret M., and Gabriel Perez-Quiros. 2000. Output
fluctuations in the United States: What has changed since the early
1980's? American Economic Review 90:1464-76.
Mikosch, Thomas, and Catalin Starica. 2004. Nonstationarities in
financial time series, the long-range dependence, and the IGARCH
effects. Review of Economics and Statistics 86:378-90.
Miller, Stephen M. 1996. A note on cross-country growth
regressions. Applied Economics 28:1019-26.
Mills, Terence C., and Ping Wang. 2003. Have output growth rates
stabilized? Evidence from the G-7 economies. Scottish Journal of
Political Economy 50:232-46.
Mirman, Leonard. 1971. Uncertainty and optimal consumption
decisions. Econometrica 39:179-85.
Phelps, Edmund S. 1968. Money wage dynamics and labor market equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy 76:678-711.
Pindyck, Robert S. 1991. Irreversibility, uncertainty, and
investment. Journal of Economic Literature 29:1110-48.
Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1986. The persistence
of volatility and stock market fluctuations. American Economic Review
76:1142-51.
Rafferty, Matthew. 2005. The effects of expected and unexpected
volatility on long-run growth: Evidence from 18 developed economies.
Southern Economic Journal 71:582-91.
Ramey, Garey, and Valerie A. Ramey. 1995. Cross-country evidence on
the link between volatility and growth. American Economic Review
85:1138-51.
Saint-Paul, Gilles. 1993. Productivity growth and the structure of
the business cycle. European Economic Review 37:861-90.
Speight, Alan E. H. 1999. UK output variability and growth: Some
further evidence. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 46:175-84.
Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 2003. Has the business cycle
changed? Evidence and explanations. In Monetary policy and uncertainty:
Adapting to a changing economy, Conference Proceedings. Jackson Hole,
WY: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 9-56.
Summers, Peter M. 2005. What caused the Great Moderation? Some
cross-country evidence. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic
Review (Third Quarter):5-32.
Tzavalis, Elias, and Mike R. Wickens. 1995. The persistence in
volatility of the US term premium 1970-1986. Economics Letters 49:381-9.
(1) Good policies refer to better management of the economy by
monetary policymakers. Structural change refers to better inventory
management. Good luck refers to the reduction in economic shocks (e.g.,
oil price shocks). Output composition shifts refer to the fall in the
volatility of output components, such as consumption and investment.
Bernanke (2004) used a lower-bound frontier on inflation and output
volatilities to organize his thinking. Inefficient monetary policy or
inventory management leaves the economy above the frontier, whereas
changes in the volatility of random shocks will shift the lower-bound
frontier. Stock and Watson (2003) attributed the Great Moderation to
good luck, implying that the frontier shifted toward the origin.
Bernanke (2004) argued that a substantial portion of the Great
Moderation reflects better monetary policy, implying a movement toward
the frontier. The distinction proves important, because if Stock and
Watson (2003) are correct, then good luck can turn into bad luck, and
the frontier can shift back to a more unfavorable trade-off. If Bernanke
(2004) is correct, then maintaining good policy can continue the
benefits of the Great Moderation. Finally, Blanchard and Simon (2001)
and Eggers and Ioannides (2006) found that most of the decline reflects
a decline in the volatility of consumption, investment, and/or
manufacturing output.
(2) At least two interpretations can explain the decline in output
growth rate volatility. For example, McConnell and Perez-Quiros (2000)
invoked a step decrease sometime in the mid-1980s. Blanchard and Simon
(2001) detected a trend decline, temporarily interrupted in the 1970s
and early 1980s. This study generally follows the approach of a step
decrease and then investigates its effect on the relationship between
the output growth rate and its volatility. Section 4, however, does
consider the relative effect of a trend decline against a one-time shift
in volatility.
(3) Grief and Tullock (1989), using pooled cross-section data on
113 countries between 1950 and 1980, investigated empirical regularities
in postwar economic growth. They found significant time-period dummy
variables or a trend variable in their mean growth models for OECD countries and concluded that the average growth rate, holding other
variables constant, rose in the post-1961 period. Similarly, Caporale
and McKiernan (1998) included two dummies for periods of the Great
Depression and World War II in their mean equation over a long sample
period from 1870 to 1993. This paper focuses on structural changes in
the variance equation.
(4) Aggarwal, Inclan, and Leal (I999) applied this algorithm to
identify the points of sudden changes in the variance of returns in 10
emerging stock markets, in addition to Hong Kong, Singapore, Germany,
Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
(5) Employing the GARCH-M modeling approach, Caporale and McKiernan
(1998) and Fountas and Karanasos (2006) used annual real GNP or IP
(industrial production) data from the mid-1800s to the 1990s for the
United States, Japan, and Germany; Macri and Sinha (2000) used
Australian quarterly GDP index and IP from the late 1950s to the end of
1999; Henry and Olekalns (2002) used U.S. quarterly real GNP from 1947
to 1998; Caporale and McKiernan (1996), Speight (1999), and Grier and
Perry (2000) used monthly IP from 1948 to the mid-1990s for the United
Kingdom and the United States to examine the relationship between output
growth and its volatility. The longer the sample period, the more likely
was the occurrence of structural changes in variance. Only Caporale and
McKiernan (1996) created a dummy variable equaling several periods of
high volatility in their GARCH process. None of the other studies
considered possible structural changes in variance.
(6) As a general rule, empirical studies report the first- and
second-order serial correlation in the standardized residuals of the
GARCH estimation based on Ljung-Box diagnostic statistics, but most
research lacks skewness, excess kurtosis, and normality tests. We argue
that the higher moments of the standardized residuals provide important
diagnostic information regarding accurate model specification and the
true data-generating process. Speight (1999) reported excess kurtosis
and significant Jarque-Bera statistics after GARCH adjustment. Other
studies pay no attention to the behavior of kurtosis before and after
GARCH estimation.
(7) Blanchard and Simon (2001) calculated skewness and excess
kurtosis statistics for the error term from their estimated rolling
first-order autoregressive process, finding significant skewness and
excess kurtosis only around the early 1980s recession. These results
match our findings. That is, by incorporating a one-time shift in either
1982:I or 1984:I in the GARCH and ARCH variance equations, we observe
insignificant skewness and excess kurtosis.
(8) We also examined descriptive statistics for the data in the
pre- and post-1984 subsamples. The same conclusions emerged as when the
break was 1982:I (see Table 1). The t statistic cannot reject the null
of equality of means between samples, and the variance ratio rejects the
null of variance equality between the samples. One minor difference did
occur, however. No ARCH effects exist in either the pre- or post-1984
periods. To save space, we do not report detailed statistics.
(9) We also experimented with a GARCH(1,1) model, but a negative
and insignificant estimate appeared in the variance equation, violating
the non-negativity assumption.
(10) One referee noted that some inherent limitations may exist in
GARCH-M models for examining the relationship between growth and
volatility. Particularly, the GARCH-M models usually employ
high-frequency data. We use quarterly data. However, the GDP growth in
Figure 1 exhibits volatility clusters. That is, certain time periods
experience high volatility, while other periods experience low
volatility. This basic characteristic of the data suggests the
methodology may be applied to measure volatility and its effect on
growth. Our approach focuses mainly on modeling the nonstationarity
variance arising from the Great Moderation. In Table 4, the full sample
splits, and neither the moving-sample standard deviation nor the ARCH
process produces a significant effect on growth.
Wen-Shwo Fang * and Stephen M. Miller ([dagger])
* Department of Economics, Feng Chia University, 100 Wen-Hwa Road,
Taichung, Taiwan; E-mail
[email protected].
([dagger]) College of Business, University of Nevada--Las Vegas,
4505 Maryland Parkway, Las Vegas, NV 89154-6005, USA; Phone: (702)
895-3776; E-mail
[email protected]; corresponding author.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics for Quarterly Growth of Real GDP
1947:I-2006:II
Sample size 237
Mean 0.8358
Standard deviation 0.9872
Skewness -0.0773 (0.1591)
Excess kurtosis 1.3124 * (0.3184)
Jarque-Bera 17.246 * [0.0001]
LB Q(1) 26.0163 *
LB Q(3) 34.154 *
LB Q(6) 45.754 *
LM (1) 3.3967 ** [0.0653]
LM (3) 8.1946 * [0.0421]
LM (6) 12.407 * [0.0534]
ADF(n) -10.888(0) *
Structural stability test for [H.sub.0]: full-sample = pre-1982
unconditional mean [H.sub.1]: full-sample
[not equal to] pre-1982
t test -0.2871
Structural stability test for [H.sub.0]: full-sample = pre-1982
unconditional variance [H.sub.1]: full-sample < post-1982
F test 0.6947 [0.0072]
1947:I-1981:I V
Sample size 139
Mean 0.8700
Standard deviation 1.1844
Skewness -0.0858 (0.2077)
Excess kurtosis 0.3723 (0.4155)
Jarque-Bera 0.9739 [0.6144]
LB Q(1) 13.0015 *
LB Q(3) 16.8830 *
LB Q(6) 25.1725 *
LM (1) 0.0439 [0.8338]
LM (3) 1.7582 [0.6240]
LM (6) 4.1906 [0.6508]
ADF(n) -8.4126(0) *
Structural stability test for [H.sub.0]: full-sample = post-1982
unconditional mean [H.sub.1]: full-sample
[not equal to] post-1982
t test 0.5460
Structural stability test for [H.sub.0]: full-sample = post-1982
unconditional variance [H.sub.1]: full-sample > post-1982
F test 2.6242 [0.0000]
1982:I-2006:II
Sample size 98
Mean 0.7872
Standard deviation 0.6094
Skewness -0.5931 * (0.2474)
Excess kurtosis 2.2179 * (0.4948)
Jarque-Bera 25.8337 * [0.0000]
LB Q(1) 13.9116 *
LB Q(3) 34.0089 *
LB Q(6) 38.7083 *
LM (1) 5.7063 * [0.0169]
LM (3) 6.2496 [0.1000]
LM (6) 4.2203 [0.6468]
ADF(n) -4.4736(1) *
Structural stability test for [H.sub.0]: pre-1982 = post-1982
unconditional mean [H.sub.1]: pre-1982
[not equal to] post-1982
t test 0.7024
Structural stability test for [H.sub.0]: pre-1982 = post-1982
unconditional variance [H.sub.1]: pre-1982 > post-1982
F test 3.7772 [0.0000]
Standard errors appear in parentheses; p values appear in brackets.
The measures of skewness and kurtosis are normally distributed as
N(0,6/T) and N(0,24/T), respectively, where T equals the number of
observations. LB Q(k) equals a Ljung-Box statistic testing for
autocorrelations in growth up to k lags. LM (k) is the Lagrange
multiplier test for conditional heteroscedasticity, distributed
asymptotically as [chi square](k). ADF(n) equals the augmented
Dickey-Fuller unit-root test with n lags selected by the Schwarz
Criterion. The t statistic tests for structural change in the mean
between samples i and j. The F statistic equals the variance-ratio
test between samples i and j, asymptotically distributed as
F([df.sub.i],[df.sub.j]), where df denotes degrees of freedom.
* 5% significance level.
** 10% significance level.
Table 2. GARCH-M Results without Structural Break
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1][[alpha.sup.2.sub.t-1]
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4267 * 0.2371 * 0.2002 * 0.0911
(0.1648) (0.0692) (0.0725) (0.1960)
LB Q (3) LB Q (6) LB [Q.sup.2] (3) LB [Q.sup.2] (6)
1.6828 4.2863 0.7517 6.7173
[0.6407] [0.6379] [0.8609] [0.3477]
[[alpha].sub.0] [[alpha].sub.1] [[beta].sub.1]
0.0106 0.1606 * 0.8355 *
(0.0123) (0.0492) (0.0434)
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.1388 0.8898 * 8.5442 * 0.0213
[0.3870] [0.0059] [0.0139] [0.8839]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -76.5102
ARCH-M Results without Structural Break
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1][[alpha.sup.2.sub.t-2]
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.3891 ** 0.3223 * 0.1611 * 0.1130
(0.2247) (0.0755) (0.0651) (0.2497)
LB Q (3) LB Q (6) LB [Q.sup.2] (3) LB [Q.sup.2] (6)
2.6000 5.8491 1.0033 8.7188
[0.4575] [0.4403] [0.8004] [0.1904]
[[alpha].sub.0] [[alpha].sub.1] [[beta].sub.1]
0.3661 * 0.3107 * 0.3730 *
(0.0564) (0.0883) (0.1190)
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
-0.0293 1.2352 * 15.0378 * 2.6977
[0.8551] [0.0001] [0.0005] [0.1005]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -85.6076
Standard errors appear in parentheses; p values appear in brackets;
LB Q(k) and LB Q2(k) equal Ljung-Box Q-statistics tests for
standardized residuals and squared standardized residuals for
autocorrelations up to k lags. LR equals the likelihood ratio
statistic following a [chi square] distribution with one degree of
freedom that tests for [[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] = 1
or [[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha].sub.2] = 1.
* 5% significance level.
** 10% significance level.
Table 3. GARCH-M Results without Structural Break at 1982: I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-2] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1][[alpha.sup.2.sub.t-1] + [gamma] Dummy, where
Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1982:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4427 * 0.2634 * 0.1757 * 0.0519
(0.1361) (0.0694) (0.0726) (0.1633)
LB Q (3) LB Q (6) LB [Q.sup.2] (3) LB [Q.sup.2] (6)
2.4247 5.4342 0.8279 4.9614
[0.4890] [0.4894] [0.8427] [0.5487]
[[alpha].sub.0] [[alpha].sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [gamma]
0.3948 * 0.0801 * 0.6271 * -0.3322 *
(0.1958) (0.0692) (0.1767) (0.1651)
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0944 0.1846 0.6862 17.5179 *
[0.5560] [0.5684] [0.7095] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -64.1225
ARCH-M Results with Structural Break at 1982:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-2] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[alpha].sub.2][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-2] + [gamma] Dummy, where
Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1982:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4644 * 0.2880 * 0.1559 * 0.0254
(0.1366) (0.0751) (0.0714) (0.1619)
LB Q (3) LB Q (6) LB [Q.sup.2] (3) LB [Q.sup.2] (6)
2.3699 5.3571 0.7853 4.2135
[0.4992] [0.4988] [0.8529] [0.6478]
[[alpha].sub.0] [[alpha].sub.1] [[alpha].sub.2] [gamma]
0.9886 * 0.1891 * 0.0959 * -0.8191 *
(0.1843) (0.0844) (0.1125) (0.1754)
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.1307 0.1385 0.8607 18.1591 *
[0.6967] [0.4153] [0.6502] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -64.7860
GARCH-M Results with Structural Break at 1984:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1][[alpha.sup.2.sub.t-1] + [gamma] Dummy,
where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1984:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4396 * 0.2365 * 0.1888 * 0.0516
(0.1296) (0.0728) (0.0671) (0.1621)
LB Q (3) LB Q (6) LB [Q.sup.2] (3) LB [Q.sup.2] (6)
2.0877 4.0421 1.2643 6.3881
[0.5543] [0.6709] [0.7376] [0.3811]
[[alpha].sub.0] [[alpha].sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [gamma]
1.0989 * 0.1025 * 0.0737 * -0.9326 *
(0.5406) (0.0893) (0.4186) (0.4615)
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0652 0.2646 0.8633 26.3497 *
[0.6830] [0.4115] [0.6494] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -62.2568
ARCH-M Results with Structural Break at 1984:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[alpha].sub.2][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-2] + [gamma] Dummy,
where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1984:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4360 * 0.2592 * 0.1806 * 0.0533
(0.1369) (0.0706) (0.0746) (0.1618)
LB Q (3) LB Q (6) LB [Q.sup.2] (3) LB [Q.sup.2] (6)
2.6621 5.0311 0.4254 5.1444
[0.4467] [0.5398] [0.9349] 0.5254
[[alpha].sub.0] [[alpha].sub.1] [[alpha].sub.2] [gamma]
1.0628 * 0.0913 * 0.0823 -0.8914 *
(0.1946) (0.0821) (0.1073) (0.1828)
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0759 0.1963 0.6057 22.1019 *
[0.6360] [0.5441] [0.7386] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -62.7772
Standard errors appear in parentheses; p values appear in
brackets; LB Q(k) and LB Q2(k) equal Ljung-Box Q-statistics tests
for standardized residuals and squared standardized residuals for
autocorrelations up to k lags. LR equals the likelihood ratio
statistic following a [chi square] distribution with one degree
of freedom that tests for [[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] = 1
or [[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha].sub.2] = 1.
* 5% significance level.
Table 4. Subsample Results with Structural Break at 1982:I
AR(1): 1947:1-1981:IV
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ACSII]
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [lambda]
0.8160 * 0.3089 * -0.2937
(0.4157) (0.0900) (0.6735)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.3929 4.4391 4.0181 5.2361
[0.4949] [0.6174] [0.2595] [0.5139]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera
0.0609 0.7565 ** 3.1319
[0.7806] [0.0891] [0.2088]
AR(2)-ARCH-M: 1982:I-2006:II
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1]
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2]
0.6398 * 0.1717 0.2881 *
(0.2474) (0.1113) (0.0973)
[lambda] [a.sub.0] [a.sub.1]
-0.4121 0.1578 * 0.3386 **
(0.5470) (0.0373) (0.1821)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
1.8017 2.4284 0.8315 2.6803
[0.6145] [0.8763] [0.8419] [0.8477]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera
0.2668 -0.1686 1.2793
[0.2882] [0.7423] [0.5274]
Subsample Results with Structural Break at 1984:I
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ACSII]
where m = 8.
AR(1): 1947:1-1983:IV
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [lambda]
0.8244 * 0.3401 * -0.3740
(0.4033) (0.0839) (0.6578)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
1.9239 4.6216 2.1934 2.6126
[0.5883] [0.6417] [0.5333] [0.8566]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera
0.0358 0.6570 2.2728
[0.8655] [0.1260] [0.3209]
AR(2): 1984:I-2006:II
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4893 * 0.1907 ** 0.393l * -0.4156
(0.1825) (0.1039) (0.1066) (0.5190)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.2561 2.5491 2.6447 6.0366
[0.5218] [0.8636] [0.4503] [0.4193]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera
-0.0174 0.0461 0.0121
[0.9479] [0.9327] [0.9939]
Standard errors appear in parentheses; p values appear in brackets;
LB Q(k) and LB [Q.sup.2](k) equal Ljung-Box Q-statistics, testing
for residuals (standardized residuals) and squared residuals
(squared standardized residuals) for autocorrelations up to k lags.
* 5% significance level.
** 10% significance level.
Table 5. GARCH-M Results with the Level Effect and Structural Break
at 1982:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1][[sigma].sup.2.sub.t-1] + [delta][y.sub.t-1] +
[gamma] Dummy, where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to]
1982:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda] [a.sub.0]
0.3948 * 0.2325 * 0.1978 * 0.1066 0.4156 *
(0.1544) (0.0726) (0.0727) (0.1633) (0.1685)
[a.sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [gamma] [delta]
0.0805 0.6532 * -0.2784 * -0.0907 **
(0.0690) (0.1477) (0.1255) (0.0478)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.2408 4.792 0.7720 4.7959
[0.5239] [0.5707] [0.8561] [0.5702]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0759 0.0103 0.2281 18.5340 *
[0.6358] [0.9746] [0.8921] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -61.5242
GARCH-M Results with the Level Effect and Structural Break at 1984:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1][[sigma].sup.2.sub.t-1] + [delta][y.sub.t-1] +
[gamma] Dummy, where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to]
1984:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda] [a.sub.0]
0.3737 * 0.2112 * 0.1914 * 0.1583 0.6903 *
(0.1517) (0.0741) (0.0721) (0.1600) (0.3448)
[a.sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [gamma] [delta]
0.0953 0.4373 -0.4708 ** -0.1391 *
(0.0796) (0.2850) (0.2672) (0.0643)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.4636 4.6720 0.5555 4.3049
[0.4819] [0.5865] [0.9065] [0.6354]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0395 0.0011 0.0616 17.7487 *
[0.8051] [0.9972] [0.9696] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -60.5848
Standard errors appear in parentheses; p values appear in brackets;
LB Q(k) and LB [Q.sup.2](k) equal Ljung-Box Q-statistics, testing
for standardized residuals and squared standardized residuals for
autocorrelations up to k lags. LR equals the likelihood ratio
statistic following a [chi square] distribution with one degree
of freedom that tests for [[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] = 1.
* 5% significance level.
** 10% significance level.
Table 6. GARCH-M Results with Time Trend
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[beta].sub.1][[sigma].sup.2.sub.t-1] + [omega]t
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4497 * 0.2448 * 0.1716 * 0.0765
(0.1469) (0.0738) (0.0725) (0.1686)
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [omega]
0.2833 * 0.1170 ** 0.7077 * -0.0011
(0.1917) (0.0633) (0.1331) (0.0007)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
1.6637 4.3703 1.2280 5.1846
[0.6450] [0.6266] [0.7462] [0.5203]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.1258 0.8619 * 7.9283 * 6.1271 *
[0.4328] [0.0077] [0.0189] [0.0133]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -71.6664
ARCH-M Results with Time Trend
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[alpha].sub.2][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-2] + [omega]t
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda]
0.4202 * 0.2885 * 0.1595 * 0.0828
(0.1484) (0.0706) (0.0799) (0.1659)
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [omega]
1.1111 * 0.1144 0.2047 * -0.0043 *
(0.1944) (0.0753) (0.0979) (0.0008)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.0563 4.7750 0.4943 4.1656
[0.5608] [0.5729] [0.9201] [0.6542]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0708 0.7629 * 5.9219 * 13.6673 *
[0.6588] [0.0184] [0.0517] [0.0002]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -70.4836
Standard errors appear in parentheses; p values appear in brackets;
LB Q(k) and LB [Q.sup.2](k) equal Ljung-Box Q-statistics testing
for standardized residuals and squared standardized residuals for
autocorrelations up to k lags. LR equals the likelihood ratio
statistic following a [chi square] distribution with one degree
of freedom that tests for [[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] = 1 or
[[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha].sub.2] = 1.
* 5% significance level.
** 10% significance level.
Table 7. GARCH-M Results with Time Trend and Structural Break at
1982:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1]
[[beta].sub.1][[sigma].sup.2.sub.t-1] + [omega]t + [gamma] Dummy,
where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1982:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda] [a.sub.0]
0.4427 * 0.2634 * 0.1756 * 0.0519 0.3963 *
(0.1371) (0.0696) (0.0729) (0.1638) (0.2106)
[a.sub.1] [[beta].sub.1] [omega] [gamma]
0.0802 0.6263 * 0.0000 -0.3318 *
(0.0697) (0.1795) (0.0004) (0.1674)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.4190 5.4276 0.8264 4.9524
[0.4901] [0.4902] [0.8431] [0.5499]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0945 0.1848 0.6878 17.4906 *
[0.5555] [0.5679] [0.7089] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -64.1224
ARCH-M Results with Time Trend and Structural Break at 1982:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[alpha].sub.2][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-2] + [omega]t + [gamma]
Dummy, where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1982:I;
0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda] [a.sub.0]
0.4582 * 0.2878 * 0.1562 * 0.0327 1.0336 *
(0.1379) (0.0745) (0.0725) (0.1626) (0.2189)
[a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [omega] [gamma]
0.1757 * 0.0982 -0.0005 -0.7598 *
(0.0885) (0.1110) (0.0011) (0.2104)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.2990 5.2517 0.7697 4.1941
[0.5127] [0.5119] [0.8566] [0.6504]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.1232 0.1582 0.8441 18.3301 *
[0.4422] [0.6249] [0.6556] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -64.6902
GARCH-M Results with Time Trend and Structural Break at 1984:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1]
[[beta].sub.1][[sigma].sup.2.sub.t-1] + [omega]t + [gamma] Dummy,
where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1984:I; 0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda] [a.sub.0]
0.4432 * 0.2361 * 0.1889 * 0.0476 1.0756 *
(0.1301) (0.0731) (0.0673) (0.1618) (0.5134)
[a.sub.1] [[beta].sub.2] [omega] [gamma]
0.1058 0.0747 0.0002 -0.9623 *
(0.0910) (0.4091) (0.0011) (0.4950)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.1568 4.0880 1.2042 6.4179
[0.5404] [0.6647] [0.7519] [0.3780]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0653 0.2568 0.8232 26.1636 *
[0.6827] [0.4254] [0.6625] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -62.2309
ARCH-M Results with Time Trend and Structural Break at 1984:I
[y.sub.t] = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1][y.sub.t-1] +
[a.sub.2][y.sub.t-2] + [lambda][[sigma].sub.t] +
[[epsilon].sub.t]; and [[sigma].sup.2.sub.t] =
[[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-1] +
[[alpha].sub.2][[epsilon].sup.2.sub.t-2] + [omega]t + [gamma]
Dummy, where Dummy = 1 for t [greater than or equal to] 1984:I;
0 otherwise.
[a.sub.0] [a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [lambda] [a.sub.0]
0.4374 * 0.2589 * 0.1808 * 0.0515 1.0512 *
(0.1377) (0.0708) (0.0750) (0.1619) (0.2188)
[a.sub.1] [a.sub.2] [omega] [gamma]
0.0935 0.0809 0.0001 -0.9106 *
(0.0838) (0.1075) (0.0011) (0.2268)
LB
LB [Q.sup.2]
LB Q(3) LB Q (6) [Q.sup.2](3) (6)
2.7064 5.0671 0.4301 5.1829
[0.4391] [0.5352] [0.9339] [0.5205]
Skewness Kurtosis Jarque-Bera LR
0.0756 0.1906 0.5823 22.0962 *
[0.6374] [0.5558] [0.7473] [0.0000]
Maximum log-likelihood function value: -62.7692
Standard errors appear in parentheses; p values appear in brackets;
LB Q(k) and LB [Q.sup.2](k) equal Ljung-Box Q-statistics, testing
for standardized residuals and squared standardized residuals for
autocorrelations up to k lags. LR equals the likelihood ratio
statistic, following a [chi square] distribution with one degree
of freedom that tests for [[alpha].sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] = 1 or
[[alpha].sub.1] + [[alpha].sub.2] = 1.
* 5% significance level.