Mortgages and financial expectations: a household-level analysis.
Brown, Sarah ; Garino, Gaia ; Taylor, Karl 等
1. Introduction and Background
Arguably, the purchase of property is one of the most important
investment and consumption decisions an individual or household will
make over a lifetime. Furthermore, such purchases are frequently
financed by mortgages. There has been a phenomenal rise in mortgage debt
over recent years. For example, the growth rate in mortgage debt as a
proportion of GDP in the UK between 1992 and 2002 is estimated at 21%
(Catte et al. 2004). Similarly, the secured debt to income ratio has
increased by 42% between 1995 and 2005 (Council of Mortgage Lenders 2006). Household mortgage debt far outweighs household unsecured debt:
In the UK, average household mortgage debt in 2000 was estimated at
48,300 [pounds sterling and at 73,788 [pounds sterling] for new
mortgages, as compared to 3281 [pounds sterling] for unsecured debt. Not
surprisingly, the extent of household mortgage debt has been of much
concern to policy makers. (1) This is especially problematic as
financial assets are typically low: average annual savings in the UK in
2000 were estimated at 934 [pounds sterling]. (2) It is apparent,
therefore, that savings typically provide insufficient cover for
mortgage debt. Hence, the analysis of mortgage debt is important in
determining the potential financial stress at the household level. As
argued by Hamilton (2003), increases in household borrowing may make
households vulnerable to reductions in their income or to changes in the
interest rate. Consequently, understanding what factors drive the
decision to acquire increasing amounts of mortgage debt and whether or
not such indebtedness is sustainable are important issues for policy
makers.
We contribute to the literature on household mortgage borrowing by
exploring one particular influence on mortgage debt, namely the
financial expectations of the individuals within the household. At the
macroeconomic level, a number of studies have found that consumer
expectations influence household consumption patterns (e.g., Acemoglu
and Scott 1994, for the UK; and Carroll, Fuhrer, and Wilcox 1994, for
the United States). Surprisingly, empirical analysis into how
expectations influence consumption decisions using individual or
household-level data has, however, been somewhat scarce. One reason for
this may be that skepticism about the use of information derived from
subjective survey data may still prevail in the economics literature
(Dominitz and Manski 1997). There are, however, a number of recent
studies that do exploit subjective information on income expectations,
such as the work of Guiso, Jappelli, and Terlizzese (1992, 1996) and
Brown et al. (2005).
We explore the relationship between mortgage debt and financial
expectations from a theoretical and an empirical perspective. Our
theoretical framework predicts a positive association between the
expectations of individuals who are optimistic about their future
financial situation and the level of mortgage debt. Our empirical
analysis based on the British Household Panel Surveys, 1993-2001,
supports our theoretical priors.
The British Household Panel Surveys enable us to explore the level
of mortgage debt at the household level by tracking a sample of
households over the nine-year period ranging from 1993 to 2001. Such an
approach allows us to control for changes experienced by households as a
result of events such as marriage and childbirth, which may influence
the level of mortgage debt. In addition, the time period of our
empirical study is particularly interesting from a macroeconomic
perspective, since by 1993 the growth in annual UK GDP at constant
prices had recovered to around 2.5% (Office for National Statistics)
after the depths of recession in 1991, fueled by inflation and high
interest rates, at which time growth was negative at -1.4%. Over the
period from 1993 to 2001, GDP growth averaged approximately 2.9% per
annum, peaking at 4.7% in 1994 and falling to 2% by 2001.
Our use of household-level data is particularly appropriate since,
as argued by Leece (1995), the use of aggregate time-series data may
mask household responses to changes in the economic environment. Leece
(1995) explores mortgage demand at the household level using
cross-section data from the British Family Expenditure Survey (FES) and
finds that the financial deregulation that occurred during the 1980s
affected mortgage demand during this period. Leece (2000) expands his
earlier work and finds that mortgage demand is influenced by the type of
mortgage undertaken. Cocco and Campbell (2007), who also use the FES,
show that rising house prices may stimulate consumption by increasing
the household's perceived wealth or by relaxing borrowing
constraints. In a U.S. study on household-level data, Crook (2001)
identifies the factors that explain U.S. household debt, incorporating
unsecured and mortgage debt, over the period from 1990 to 1995 using
data from the Survey of Consumer Finances. Income, home ownership, and
family size all have a positive impact on the level of household debt.
Interestingly, expectations of future changes in interest rates do not
influence the level of household debt.
From the theoretical point of view, there exists a large body of
literature that analyzes consumption and housing finance choice based
mostly on life-cycle models with income risk and borrowing constraints.
For example, in Flavin and Yamashita (2002), households maximize a
function of the mean and variance of returns to their asset portfolio
(inclusive of housing) conditional on the current value of a state
variable represented by the ratio of the house value to net worth. In
Cocco (2004), agents living for T periods maximize lifetime expected
utility over housing size and non-durable consumption, with a mortgage
among available financial instruments and labor income risk. Numerical solutions are provided as, generally, closed-form solutions cannot be
obtained. Both papers point to an effect of the portfolio constraint imposed by housing demand and indicate that younger and less well-off
investors have limited financial wealth to invest in stocks: Their net
worth will be used to pay off the mortgage or to buy bonds instead.
Expectations are not explicitly modeled, although their action is
implicitly embodied in labor income risk.
2. Theoretical Underpinnings
Assumptions
Our stylized life-cycle model is the simplest possible and serves
to illustrate our subsequent empirical analysis. We assume two discrete
time periods, t = 1 and t = 2, and demonstrate a positive relationship
between the level of mortgage debt undertaken by consumers and
optimistic financial expectations, represented by a two-point joint
distribution of incomes and house prices. At the start of period 1,
risk-averse consumers earn certain income, y1, and choose, optimally, a
mortgage deposit, D, toward the purchase of one durable and indivisible unit of housing, h, priced [p.sub.1]. To minimize the algebra, and
without loss of generality, consumption prices (of the non-durable
numeraire) in each period are normalized to 1, the safe interest rate is
set to zero, and there is no housing depreciation. The utility function,
U([c.sub.t], h), defined over consumption at time t and housing, is
twice differentiable and strictly concave. Consumption in period 1 is
given by [c.sub.1] = [y.sub.1] - D, yielding utility U([y.sub.1] - D,
1).
There is second-period uncertainty of both consumer incomes and
house prices, which are jointly distributed with two possible
realizations of each variable, [y.sub.2i] and [p.sub.2j], where i, j =
H, L denote the high and low income and house price realizations,
respectively; and where [y.sub.2H] > [y.sub.2L] and [p.sub.2H] >
[p.sub.2L]. So, in period 2, there are four possible states of nature
(HH, HL, LH, LL) that occur with exogenous probabilities [q.sub.HH],
[q.sub.HL], [q.sub.LH], and [q.sub.LL], respectively, that sum to 1. In
period 1, a competitive risk-neutral lender provides a mortgage of size
([p.sub.1] - D). The mortgage repayment in period 2 is therefore
R([p.sub.1] - D), where, as mentioned, D is saved by the borrower, at an
interest factor R [greater than or equal to] 1, which includes a risk
premium (see Eqn. 2--implying that consumers will always save in D
rather than in the safe interest-yielding asset). The distributions of
second-period incomes and house prices are common knowledge to both the
consumer and the lender. (3)
In order to take up the mortgage in the first period the consumer
expects, on average, to be able to repay it in the second period (4)
[i.e., E([y.sub.2] + [p.sub.2]) [greater than or equal to] R([p.sub.1] -
D), where E([y.sub.2] + [p.sub.2]) = [q.sub.LL]([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L])
+ [q.sub.LH]([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2H]) + [q.sub.HL]([y.sub.2H] +
[p.sub.2L]) + [q.sub.HH]([y.sub.2H] + [p.sub.2H]) and R is defined by
the lender's equilibrium condition] (see Eqn. 1 below). However,
when both income and house price realizations are low (in state LL),
consumers are unable to repay their debt [i.e., [y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L]
< R([p.sub.1] - D)]. In this case, the lender seizes all of the
consumer's resources except an exogenous small amount, e > 0,
yielding utility U(e, 0) to the consumer. Conversely, when second-period
income is high (in states HH and HL), consumers can repay their debt
regardless of the house price realization [i.e., [y.sub.2H] >
R([p.sub.1] - D)]. In this case, consumption is either [c.sub.2H] =
[y.sub.2H] - R([p.sub.1] - D), yielding utility U([y.sub.2H -
R([p.sub.1] - D), 1) if the consumer keeps the house in the second
period, or [c.sub.2Hj] = [y.sub.2H] - [p.sub.2j] - R([p.sub.1] - D),
yielding utility U([y.sub.2H] + [p.sub.2j] - R([p.sub.1] - D), 0) if the
consumer sells the house in the second period for a financial gain
[i.e., if [p.sub.2j] > [p.sub.1], j = H, L). Finally, when
second-period income is low but the house price is high (in state LH),
consumers cannot repay the debt and keep the house since [y.sub.2L] <
R([p.sub.1] - D). However, they can repay the debt by selling the house,
with consumption [c.sub.2LH] = [y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2H] - R([p.sub.1] -
D), yielding utility U([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2H] - R([p.sub.1] - D), 0),
so long as [y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2H] > R([p.sub.1] - D). It is
straightforward to verify that these ex post state-dependent conditions
are compatible with the ex ante requirement that expected incomes and
house prices should be above the debt repayment.
The Model
In equilibrium, the interest factor R is obtained from the
lender's zero expected profit condition:
[p.sub.1] - D = [q.sub.LL] ([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L] - e) + (1 -
[q.sub.LL]) R([p.sub.1] - D). (1)
From our assumptions it is straightforward to verify that
R = 1/1 - [q.sub.LL] - [q.sub.LL] ([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L] - e)/(1
- [q.sub.LL])([p.sub.1] - D) [greater than or equal to] 1. (2)
By substituting R from Equation 2, we can write the reduced form of
the inequality [y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L] < R([p.sub.1] - D) (holding in
state LL), which gives D < [p.sub.1] - ([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L]) +
[q.sub.LL]e, that is, the upper bound to D. Similarly, the inequality
[y.sub.2H] > R([p.sub.1] - D) (holding in states HH and HL) becomes D
> [p.sub.1] - [q.sub.LL]([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L] - e) - (1 -
[q.sub.LL])[y.sub.2H]; the inequality [y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2H] >
R([p.sub.1] - D)(holding in state LH)becomes D > [p.sub.1] -
[q.sub.LL]([y.sub.2L] + [p.sub.2L] - e) - (1 - [q.sub.LL])([p.sub.2H] +
[y.sub.2L]); and the inequality E([y.sub.2] + [p.sub.2]) >
R([p.sub.1] - D) becomes D > [p.sub.1] - [q.sub.LL]([y.sub.2L] +
[p.sub.2L] - e) - (1 - [q.sub.LL])E([y.sub.2] + [p.sub.2]). The greater
right-hand side to these last three reduced-form inequalities gives the
lower bound to D. The domain of the definition of D, the chosen mortgage
deposit, is therefore:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (3)
where both the left-hand side and right-hand side are expressed
solely in terms of exogenous variables and parameters. In this
framework, Equation 3 can be interpreted as the borrowing constraint on
the mortgage size ([p.sub.1] - D) and (1 - [q.sub.LL]) as the overall
probability of being able to repay the loan; that is, the
"optimistic" financial expectation of both parties. It is then
straightforward to show that the effect of (1 - [q.sub.LL]) on the total
amount of mortgage undertaken, ([p.sub.1] - D), is positive [or,
equivalently, that the effect of [q.sub.LL] on ([p.sub.1] - D) is
negative]. Again without loss of generality, we consider the case in
which consumer preferences are such that high-income consumers always
prefer to keep the house in the second period rather than sell it [i.e.,
U([y.sub.2H] - R([p.sub.1] - D), 1) > U([y.sub.2H] + [p.sub.2j] -
R([p.sub.1] - D), 0)].
The consumer chooses the mortgage deposit, D, optimally to maximize
expected lifetime utility subject to Equation 3 and the lender's
zero expected profit condition:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (4)
where the expressions for consumption are defined above, 8 is a
subjective discount factor, and the interest factor is defined by
Equation 1 and (1 - [q.sub.LL] - [q.sub.LH] = [q.sub.HH] + [q.sub.HL]).
At an interior solution, which, given Equation 3, is ensured by
strict concavity, the first-order condition is
(1 - [q.sub.LL])U' ([c.sub.1], 1) = [delta][q.sub.LH]U'
([c.sub.2LH], 0) + [delta](1 - [q.sub.LL] - [q.sub.LH]) U'
([c.sub.2H], 1). (5)
Comparative statics then give:
dD/[dq.sub.LL] =
[q.LH] [U' ([c.sub.2H], 1) - U' ([c.sub.2LH, 0)]/[[(1 -
[q.sub.LL].sup.2] U" ([c.sub.1], 1) + [q.sub.LH] U"
([c.sub.2LH], 0) + (1 - [q.sub.LL] - [q.sub.LH])U" ([c.sub.2H], 1)]
> 0, (6)
which is positive, since both the numerator and the denominator are
negative by concavity. This implies that d([p.sub.1] - D)/[dq.sub.LL]
< 0. Hence, a higher level of (1 - [q.sub.LL]) has a positive effect
on mortgage debt. That is, optimistic financial expectations increase
mortgage debt.
In sum, the above is a stylized model provided to inform our
empirical analysis. In particular, the result encapsulated by Equation 6
is intuitive. Moreover, it is straightforward to verify that it holds
also with non-zero safe interest rate and depreciation parameters, with
different consumption prices in periods 1 and 2, and with consumer
preferences such that the high-income consumer prefers to sell the house
in period 2. (5) Our simplifying assumptions are made purely to minimize
notation and to illustrate the intuition in the clearest possible way in
order to motivate our subsequent empirical analysis.
3. Data and Methodology
In the remainder of the paper, we explore the empirical
determinants of the amount of outstanding mortgage debt at the household
level in Great Britain, focusing on the role of financial expectations.
For the purposes of our empirical study, we exploit information
contained in nine waves of the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS),
1993-2001. Prior to 1993, households were not asked to disclose the
amount of their mortgage in the BHPS. The BHPS is a random-sample
survey, carried out by the Institute for Social and Economic Research,
of each adult member from a nationally representative sample of more
than 5000 private households (yielding approximately 10,000 individual
interviews).
In the 1993-2001 surveys, households were asked "How much is
the total amount of your outstanding loans on all the property you (or
your household) own, including your current home?" The answers thus
provide information on the amount of outstanding mortgage debt. The
defining feature of the BHPS, for the purpose of our study, is that it
contains information on the total amount of mortgage debt over a
relatively long time horizon, 1993-2001, at the household level as well
as information relating to the expectations of household members about
their future financial situation. Our sample includes households with a
head of household aged between 18 and 65 years. We analyze an unbalanced
panel of data such that the average number of observations per household
is 3.7, with the minimum (maximum) being 1 (9). Our sample comprises
11,478 households, over a maximum of nine years, yielding a total of
42,894 observations.
To explore the relationship between the expectations of household
members regarding their future financial situation and the extent of
outstanding mortgage debt, we exploit responses to the following
question: "Looking ahead, how do you think you will be financially
a year from now, will you be: Better off; Worse off; Or about the
same?" Answers to this question implicitly incorporate a synthesis
of a household member's own financial outlook (e.g., pay and job
security) with their expectations about the general economic environment
(e.g., future interest rates, tax changes, inflation, and unemployment
rates).
Response rates for heads of households are shown in Table 1A. From
the responses to this question, we create a Financial Expectations Index
(FEI), as in Brown et al. (2005), where individuals who answer
"Worse off" to the above question are coded as 0, those who
answer neither "Worse off or Better off" are coded 1, and
individuals who answer "Better off" are coded as 2. Thus, the
index ranks individuals according to their financial expectations from
having a bleak outlook to being optimistic about their financial future.
From Table 1A, it is apparent that over the period heads of households
tend to be financially optimistic rather than pessimistic, which may
reflect the start of the economic recovery following the recession of
the early 1990s.
We also explore whether financial expectations vary over time,
since it is possible that any correlation between financial expectations
and mortgage debt might simply be capturing a household fixed effect
rather than predictions about future income. Table 1B shows the number
of times household heads are optimistic, pessimistic, or expect no
income change over the time period, including the proportion of
households that are always optimistic and always pessimistic. Clearly,
there is variation in households' financial expectations over time,
with only a small proportion of individuals always in the same category
for all years and more than 50% of respondents only reporting two years
(out of nine) in which financial expectations do not change.
In order to explore the relationship between mortgage debt and
financial expectations, we proceed in two stages. First, we estimate a
housing tenure model, since it is apparent that the housing tenure of
households will influence the level of mortgage debt. The housing tenure
variable is defined as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The responses to this variable over time are shown in Table 1C. The
percentage of households owning a home with a mortgage has fallen over
time, while, conversely, the percentage renting privately has risen. We
model housing tenure by specifying a multinomial logit (MNL) model in
which the unit of observation is the head of household h at time t. In
the set of explanatory variables, we include labor market status, a
quadratic in age, gender, ethnicity, number of children, household size,
household income, educational attainment, household savings, and
investments. We also include the financial expectations of the head of
household, [FEI.sub.ht], to control for differences in financial
optimism across tenure types. We then use the predicted values from the
MNL framework to calculate an inverse mills ratio term relating to
selection into category 1 (i.e., owner occupiers with a mortgage,
[htc.sub.ht] = 1), which is then included in our mortgage debt equation.
(6)
Given that our focus is on the relationship between financial
expectations and the level of mortgage debt, we select those households
in which [htc.sub.ht] = 1, and, in the second stage of our analysis, we
explore the determinants of the logarithm of the amount of outstanding
mortgage debt. (7) Figure 1 illustrates the distribution of the
logarithm of the amount of outstanding mortgage debt across the sample
of owner occupiers with a mortgage. We estimate the following
reduced-form mortgage equation:
ln ([m.sub.ht]) = [[beta]'.sub.1][X.sub.ht] +
[[beta]'.sub.2][FEI.sub.ht] + [v.sub.ht], (7)
where
[v.sub.ht] = [[alpha].sub.h] + [[eta].sub.ht]. (8)
Our notation is defined as follows. The mortgage debt of household
h at time t is given by [m.sub.ht] such that t = 1,..., 9, where h =
1,..., [n.sub.h]; [X.sub.ht] denotes a vector of head of household and
household characteristics, including the inverse mill ratio term derived
from the housing tenure model to control for potential sample selection
into category [htC.sub.ht] = 1; [[alpha].sub.h] represents the
"household" specific unobservable effect; and [[eta].sub.ht]
is a random error term, [[eta].sub.ht] ~ IN(0, [[sigma].sup.2.sub.h]).
Our theoretical framework (i.e., Eqn. 6) predicts [[beta].sub.2] > 0.
We assume that [[alpha].sub.h] is IN(O, [[sigma.sup.2.sub.[alpha]) and
independent of [[eta].sub.ht] and [X.sub.ht]. Hence, the correlation
between the error terms of households over time is a constant given by
[rho] = corr([v.sub.tl], [v.sub.tk]) =
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.[alpha]]/[[sigma].sup.2.sub.[alpha]] +
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.[eta]] l [not equal to] k, (9)
where [rho] represents the proportion of the total unexplained variance in the dependent variable contributed by the panel-level
variance component. Thus, the magnitude of [rho] yields information
pertaining to the intra-household correlation of mortgage debt over
time. As a result of issues pertaining to identification restrictions,
we regard our mortgage debt equation as a reduced-form specification
potentially capturing demand and supply influences.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
In waves 1993 to 2001 of the BHPS, homeowners are asked:
"About how much would you expect to get for your home if you sold
it today?" We use the responses to this question to derive a
measure of house value, which is used to weight the level of mortgage
debt. Figure 2 represents the distribution of mortgage debt as a
proportion of the house value. Not surprisingly, the majority of
households with a mortgage do not have a mortgage value greater than the
value of the house; only 1.5% of mortgagees fall into this latter group.
We repeat the analysis represented by Equations 7 and 8 with the
weighted level of mortgage debt as the dependent variable in order to
explore the robustness of our findings.
In addition to exploring the influence of the head of
household's financial expectations, we also investigate the role
played by the expectations of other household members. Hence, we repeat
the analysis described above and replace [FEI.sub.ht] with the sum of
the financial expectations index across all household members, HFEI =
[summation] over (i[member of]h)] FEI.
Although the focus of our paper lies in the role of financial
expectations, we include a number of additional controls in our
econometric analysis for personal and demographic characteristics in the
vector [X.sub.ht]. We control for household income, highest educational
qualification of the head of household, and the logarithm of total
savings and investments to proxy household wealth. Demographic controls
include the marital status of the head of household, the number of
children (aged less than 18 years), region of residence, and household
size. We also control for whether the household has an endowment or
repayment mortgage and whether the household has a mortgage protection
plan or structural or contents insurance. Reasons for having an
additional mortgage are also included, which include an extension to the
house, home improvements, car purchase, or another unspecified reason.
Table 2 presents summary statistics for the variables used in our
empirical analysis.
4. Results
Housing Tenure and Financial Expectations
Before focusing on the determinants of the level of mortgage debt,
we will briefly comment on the characteristics that influence housing
tenure. Table 3A, B report the determinants of housing tenure, where we
consider the influence of individual (i.e., the head of household) and
household expectations, respectively. The findings presented in Table 3A
indicate that the head of household's expectations are important in
influencing housing tenure. For example, a 1-point move up the financial
expectations index (i.e., becoming more financially optimistic) yields
just under a 1% increase in the probability that the head of household
will be an owner occupier with a mortgage rather than own the property
outright (the reference category), ceteris paribus. Other factors of
interest are that younger heads of household are more likely to rent
property, as are students, the unemployed, and those not in the labor
market. For example, for heads of household not in the labor market,
there is a 21.6% higher probability of renting from the council rather
than owning a property outright. Higher income, savings, and investment
are all associated with a lower probability of renting relative to
owning a property without a mortgage. Married or cohabiting individuals
and those with some education (relative to those with no educational
qualifications) also have a lower probability of renting. (8)
Mortgage Debt and Financial Expectations
Turning our focus to the determinants of the level of mortgage
debt, our aim is to verify whether the empirical evidence corresponds
with our theoretical priors. Since we focus solely on mortgagees (i.e.,
[htc.sub.ht] = 1), we include an inverse mills ratio term in our set of
explanatory variables to control for potential sample selection bias.
(9) The determinants of the level of mortgage debt and the determinants
of the proportion of mortgage debt relative to the estimated house value
are shown in Table 4A, based on individual financial expectations, and
in Table 4B, based on household financial expectations. Throughout the
results, [rho] is large, indicating relatively high intra-household
correlation of mortgage debt over time.
Our empirical findings accord with our theoretical priors in that
the head of household's financial expectations index is
characterized by a positive and significant estimated coefficient,
indicating that the more optimistic the head of household is about their
financial situation in the following year, the greater is the amount of
mortgage debt, as shown in Table 4A, column 1.
Turning to the other explanatory variables, the level of
outstanding mortgage debt is positively associated with the head of
household's age, albeit at a decreasing rate. Other factors that
have a positive and significant influence on the level of mortgage debt
are household income, whether the head of household is married or
cohabiting, and the educational attainment of the head of household. For
example, heads of household with a degree have around a 31% higher level
of mortgage debt than those with no education, ceteris paribus.
Household size and having structural insurance, on the other hand, are
associated with lower levels of mortgage debt. For those mortgagees with
an endowment or repayment mortgage, the level of mortgage debt is
significantly higher at around 6% and 7%, respectively. Having contents
insurance or other types of insurance are also associated with higher
levels of mortgage debt.
The second column of Table 4A reports consistent findings with the
alternative dependent variable--mortgage debt as a proportion of house
value. Clearly, the head of household's financial expectations
index is characterized by a significant positive estimated coefficient
and, hence, supports the previous findings--although the size of the
estimated coefficient is marginally smaller than that for the previous
dependent variable. Mortgage debt as a proportion of house value is also
positively related to household income, being a male head of household,
having an endowment mortgage, and contents insurance. Conversely, older
heads of household, household size, the number of children, higher
levels of savings and investments, having an additional mortgage for
home improvements, or an extension are all negatively associated with
the amount of mortgage debt relative to house value.
Table 4B presents the results from estimating Equation 7, including
the sum of financial expectations of all individuals within the
household. Our findings indicate that the summation of expectations
within the household is characterized by a positive and significant
estimated coefficient for both the amount of mortgage debt and mortgage
debt as a proportion of house value. Thus, our results indicate that,
even when controlling for household size, households with higher levels
of financial optimism amongst their members are associated with greater
levels of mortgage debt.
The coefficients on the regional dummy variables reported in Table
4A, B show that the two areas that have the lowest mortgage debt
relative to London, the reference category, are the North East and
Wales. Such a finding is not surprising given the relatively low house
prices in these two regions. With respect to mortgage debt as a
proportion of house value, all regions have a mortgage amount that is
closer to the estimated value of the house than that in the London
region. Although all monetary figures have been deflated, as compared to
the reference category, 2001, mortgage debt relative to house value was
significantly lower in the earlier years. (10,11)
Robustness Checks
We explore the robustness of our empirical findings in three ways.
First, we replace the financial expectations index with dummy variables denoting financial optimism and pessimism. Second, we control for the
truncation of the sample using a Tobit model rather than a sample
selection correction. Finally, we distinguish between household
expectations and aggregate expectations in order to further explore the
issue of household fixed effects.
We replace the financial expectations index with two dummy
variables for whether the head of household is financially optimistic or
financially pessimistic to see how robust the results are to an
alternative definition of our key variable of interest. (12) The results
are shown in Table 5, panel A, where the same set of control variables
is employed as in Table 4A. Both financial optimism and financial
pessimism are statistically significant in influencing the level of
mortgage debt and mortgage debt as a proportion of house value. A
financially optimistic head of household has 2.1% (5%) higher mortgage
debt (mortgage debt as a proportion of house value) than those who
predict that their financial situation will stay the same (i.e., the
reference category), ceteris paribus. Similarly, financial pessimism
works in the opposite direction, with a financially pessimistic head of
household having 3.1% (3.4%) lower mortgage debt (mortgage debt as a
proportion of house value) than those who predict that their financial
situation will stay the same, ceteris paribus. (13) For household
financial expectations, we replace the index with four dummy variables
capturing (i) whether one individual within the household is optimistic;
(ii) whether one individual within the household is pessimistic; (iii)
whether two or more individuals within the household are optimistic; and
(iv) whether two or more individuals within the household are
pessimistic. The results, which are presented in Table 5, panel B,
reiterate the finding that financial optimism is associated with a
higher level and proportion of mortgage debt.
We explore the robustness of our findings further by dealing with
the truncation of the sample in an alternative way by, specifically, a
Tobit model in which mortgage debt is truncated at zero:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (10)
The results of estimating Equation 10 are presented in Table 6,
panel A, based on individual financial expectations, and in Table 6,
panel B, based on household financial expectations. In Table 6, panel A,
the financial expectations index is positively related to mortgage debt
and mortgage debt as a proportion of house value, indicating that the
more financially optimistic individuals are the higher is the level of
mortgage debt. This result also holds when we consider the aggregate
expectations of individuals within the household (see Table 6, panel B).
Finally, one could argue that the positive correlation found
between financial expectations and mortgage debt stems from optimistic
aggregate expectations about future income rather than
household-specific effects. To separate the aggregate effects from the
household specific effects, we explore household financial expectations
relative to the average level of aggregate household expectations in
each year. (14) Thus, we create an index [FEI.sub.rt], which represents
the head of household's expectations relative to aggregate
expectations (calculated at the mean for each year), and we also define
[HFEI.sub.rt] for sum of the FEI across all household members relative
to the aggregate mean expectations. (15) The mean values for
[FEI.sub.rt] and [HFEI.sub.rt] are given by 1.0227 and 0.9949,
respectively. Table 7 presents the results from weighting the FEI by
aggregate expectations for heads of household (panel A) and for all
individuals within the household (panel B). The results indicate that
higher household financial expectations relative to the yearly average
are positively associated with higher mortgage debt.
Mortgage Debt and Income
Finally, we compare the relative magnitude of the mortgage level as
a proportion of household income across optimistic and pessimistic heads
of households over the period ranging from 1993 to 2001. Figures 3 and 4
show the annual median actual and predicted mortgage level as a
proportion of income, respectively, for both financially optimistic and
pessimistic heads of households. The percentage growth in GDP
year-on-year is also plotted on the right-hand vertical axis in each
figure (United Kingdom Office of National Statistics 2007).
The predicted mortgage level is derived by estimating separate
mortgage debt equations for financially optimistic and financially
pessimistic heads of households. We then use these results to calculate
predicted mortgage debt for each group and year. Overall the model
accurately predicts the trend in mortgage level as a proportion of
income over time, although it does overpredict actual year-on-year
values. Clearly, growth in GDP peaked in 1994 at 4.7% and started to
fall after 1997. Correspondingly, there is also evidence of the actual
and predicted mortgage levels relative to income falling after 1998 for
optimistic heads of households. It appears that the proportion of
outstanding mortgage debt relative to household income for optimistic
individuals lags the business cycle by one year, based on actual and
predicted values. This is despite the Bank of England's base
interest rate being at its peak in 1998, averaging 6.94%, and falling
thereafter to an average of 4.96% in 2001. As such, the trends depicted in Figures 3 and 4 indicate that the level of mortgage debt may not be
inversely related to the price of debt. In general, it is apparent that
the mortgage debt series of optimistic heads of households lies clearly
above that of pessimistic heads of households, providing further
evidence indicating that financial optimism is associated with higher
levels of mortgage debt at the household level.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
5. Concluding Remarks
In this paper we have explored an issue that is extremely topical among both economists and policy makers--namely, mortgage debt at the
household level. Given that the UK (along with a number of other
countries) currently has high, and arguably unsustainable, rates of
house price inflation and growing household debt, gaining an insight
into what factors influence mortgage debt is a very important issue
(Nickell 2002). Our main focus has been on the influence of financial
expectations on the level of mortgage debt. To be specific, our
theoretical framework predicts an intuitively positive association
between optimistic financial expectations and mortgage debt. In order to
test our theoretical predictions we have explored the determinants of
the level of outstanding mortgage debt using data derived from nine
waves of the BHPS, 1993-2001. Our findings indicate that the
expectations of household members regarding their future financial
situation are an important determinant of mortgage debt.
Received March 2006; accepted March 2007.
References
Acemoglu, D., and A. Scott. 1994. Consumer confidence and rational
expectations: Are agents' beliefs consistent with economic theory?
Economic Journal 104:1-19,
Brown, S., G. Garino, K. Taylor, and S. Wheatley Price. 2005. Debt
and financial expectations: An individual and household level analysis.
Economic Inquiry 43:100-20.
Carroll, C., J. Fuhrer, and D. Wilcox. 1994. Does consumer
sentiment forecast household spending? If so, why? American Economic
Review 84:1397-408.
Catte, Pietro, Nathalie Girouard, Robert Price, and Christophe Andre. 2004. Housing markets, wealth and the business cycle. In OECD economic outlook, IV, n. 75: 514-43.
Cocco, J. 2004. Portfolio choice in the presence of housing. Review
of Financial Studies 18:535-67.
Cocco, J., and J. Y. Campbell. 2007. How do house prices affect
consumption? Journal of Monetary Economics 54:591 621.
Council of Mortgage Lenders. 2006. "A trillion pounds success
story." Housing Finance, April. Accessed July 2007. Available
http://www.cml.org.uk/cml/publications/research.
Crook, J. 2001. The demand for household debt in the USA: Evidence
from the 1995 survey of consumer finance. Applied Financial Economics
11:83-91.
Dominitz, J., and C. Manski. 1997. Using expectations data to study
subjective income expectations. Journal of the American Statistical
Association 92:855-67.
Flavin, M., and T. Yamashita. 2002. Owner-occupied housing and the
composition of household portfolio. American Economic Review 92:345-62.
Gale, D., and M. Hellwig. 1985. Incentive compatible debt
contracts: The one period problem. Review of Economic Studies 52:647-63.
Greenspan, A. 2004. Understanding household debt obligations.
Remarks, Credit Union National Association Governmental Affairs
Conference, Washington, DC, February 23. Available
http://www.federalreserve.gov/
boardDocs/speeches/2004/20040223/default.htm.
Guiso, L., T. Jappelli, and D. Terlizzese. 1992. Earnings
uncertainty and precautionary saving. Journal of Monetary Economics
30:307-37.
Guiso, L., T. Jappelli, and D. Terlizzese. 1996. Income risk,
borrowing constraints and portfolio choice. American Economic Review
86:158-72.
Hamilton, R. 2003. Trends in households' aggregate secured
debt. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin Q1:271-80.
Jost, P. 1996. On the role of commitment in a principal-agent
relationship with an informed principal. Journal of Economic Theory
68:510-30.
Krasa, S., and A. P. Villamil. 2000. Optimal contracts when
enforcement is a decision variable. Econometrica 68:119-34.
Leece, D. 1995. Rationing, mortgage demand and the impact of
financial deregulation. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics
57:43-66.
Leece, D. 2000. Choice of mortgage instrument, liquidity
constraints and the demand for housing debt in the UK. Applied Economies
32:1121-32.
Mookherjee, D., and I. Png. 1989. Optimal auditing, insurance and
redistribution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104:397-415.
Nickell, S. 2002. House prices, household debt and monetary policy.
Household Debt and Monetary Policy Speech Glasgow. Accessed July 2007.
Available http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/speeches/speech187.pdf.
Papademos, L. 2004. The economic outlook and the ECB's
monetary policy: Some key issues. Speech, Nomura Annual Euro Conference,
Tokyo, November 11.
Townsend, R. 1979. Optimal contracts and competitive markets with
costly state verification. Journal of Economic Theory 21:265-93.
United Kingdom Office of National Statistics. "GDP
Growth." Accessed July 2007. Available http://www.statistics.
gov.uk/cci/nugget.asp?id = 192.
(1) For example, the accumulation of debt has been noted by the
European Central Bank (ECB), which has reported that falling interest
rates have allowed households to borrow more and accumulate more debt.
Consequently, household debt in the euro area has increased
significantly in recent years. In 2004, it was estimated at 54% of GDP.
See http:// www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2004/html/sp041111.en.html for
the speech by Lucas Papademos, Vice-President of the ECB, delivered at
the Nomura Annual Euro Conference, "A Challenging Future for
Europe," Tokyo, November 11, 2004. In the United States, remarks on
the amount of household debt relative to assets were made by the
Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board Alan Greenspan,
"Understanding Household Debt Obligations," at the Credit
Union National Association, Governmental Affairs Conference, Washington,
D.C., February 23, 2004 (Greenspan 2004).
(2) The figures for average household mortgage debt, unsecured
debt, and savings are calculated from the British Household Panel
Survey, 2000.
(3) Exploring cases in which the lender is not informed about the
realization of the consumer's resources is beyond the scope of this
paper, as it requires the incorporation of the appropriate incentive
constraints into a "mortgage contract" between consumer and
lender. There is a large and established theoretical literature on loan
contracts with costly state verification; see, for example, Townsend
(1979), Gale and Hellwig (1985), Mookherjee and Png (1989), Jost (1996),
and Krasa and Villamil (2000).
(4) We are grateful to an anonymous referee for highlighting this
point.
(5) Algebraic proofs of these results are available from the
authors on request.
(6) Our over-identifying instruments are the following labor market
status dummy variables: employed; self employed; unemployed; not in the
labor market; and being a full-time student. These are intuitively
appealing instruments, given that obtaining a mortgage is conditional on
labor market status. Since the choice of over-identifying instruments is
always a contentious issue, we have explored changes to the set of
instruments as well as validity tests for our choice of instruments and
different approaches to allowing for sample selection. We discuss these
issues further in section 4.
(7) Zero reported mortgage debt is included as zero in our
dependent variable, as there is no reported mortgage debt between zero
and unity.
(8) Both individual and household financial expectations are
positively associated with renting a property from the council. We have
explored this further and find that a possible explanation relates to
the fact that council renting is concentrated among younger individuals
who tend to be more financially optimistic. If the financial
expectations index is interacted with age, the marginal effect on the
interaction term is negative and significant. Mortgage Debt and
Financial Expectation
(9) The inverse mills ratio term has a positive estimated
coefficient, indicating that its exclusion would bias our results
downward. In general, the sample selection equation is well specified,
with the chi-squared statistic being significant at the 1% level. We
have also explored the robustness of our findings by omitting the
inverse mills ratio term. Our findings with respect to the relationship
between financial expectations and the level of mortgage debt are
largely unchanged. To test for the validity of the instruments we test
the joint significance of the labor market status variables in the
sample selection equation. We find that these variables are jointly
significant in all models,
supporting the use of these instruments. Secondly, we regress the
residual from the mortgage equation on the over-identifying instruments.
Our findings indicate an insignificant relationship between the
residuals and the labor market status variables in all models, thereby
further endorsing the validity of this set of over-identifying
instruments.
(10) To explore the robustness of our findings, we replicated the
analysis of Table 4A, B, replacing regional dummy variables with
regional average house prices in each year and replacing the year dummy
variables with the Bank of England base interest rate. The significant
estimated coefficient of financial expectations remains across each
specification, with the magnitude of the impact being largely unaffected
in comparison to those reported in Table 4A, B. For example, for
individual financial expectations, the estimated coefficients were
0.0242 and 0.0249 for LMORT and PMORT, respectively. For household
financial expectations, the corresponding estimated coefficients were
0.0138 and 0.0094. The full results are omitted for brevity, but are
available on request.
(11) We have also investigated how well the financial expectations
index predicts future income. The summary statistics presented in Table
1B indicate that household expectations vary over time. When we regress
future household income on lagged income, the financial expectations
index, and the demographic variables used in Table 4A, the coefficient
on the financial expectations index is positive and statistically
significant, although it is outweighed by the coefficient on lagged
household income. This result is confirmed regardless of housing tenure
and for mortgagees only; the respective coefficients (t-statistics) are
0.0333 (3.64) and 0.0166 (2.45). We also regress household income growth
on the financial expectations index. Once again, expectations about
future income have predictive power, with estimated coefficients
(t-statistics) of 0.0286 (2.79) and 0.0253 (2.02). Such findings
indicate that financial expectations are not capturing a household fixed
effect and that the index does help predict future income and income
growth at the household level.
(12) We are grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting this
robustness check.
(13) The effect of financial optimism remains if the omitted
category is financial pessimism.
(14) We are grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting this
approach.
(15) A ratio equal to unity implies that the financial expectations
of the household are equal to the yearly average. If the ratio is
greater than unity, financial expectations of the household are higher
than the mean; conversely, a ratio less than unity implies that
household financial expectations are lower than the mean.
Sarah Brown, Department of Economics, University of Sheffield, 9
Mappin Street, Sheffield S1 4DT, United Kingdom.
Gaia Garino, Department of Economics, University of Leicester,
University Road, Leicester, Leicestershire LE1 7RH, United Kingdom;
E-mail
[email protected]; corresponding author.
Karl Taylor, Department of Economics, University of Sheffield, 9
Mappin Street, Sheffield S1 4DT, United Kingdom.
We are grateful to the Data Archive at the University of Essex for
supplying data from the British Household Panel Surveys 1993 to 2000. We
would like to thank two anonymous referees for constructive comments. We
are also grateful to Professor Gianni De Fraja and Professor Stephen
Pudney for helpful comments and advice as well as to the seminar
participants at the University of Birmingham. The normal disclaimer applies.
Table 1A. Financial Expectations Over Time
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997
Better off (%) 26.53 28.14 29.70 31.38 31.04
Worse off (%) 22.36 19.36 16.17 14.23 13.21
Or about the same? (%) 51.11 52.50 54.13 54.39 55.75
1998 1999 2000 2001
Better off (%) 32.65 31.70 32.49 29.41
Worse off (%) 11.77 12.37 11.83 10.57
Or about the same? (%) 55.58 55.93 55.68 60.02
Table 1B. Persistence of Financial Expectations Over Time
About the Same
Worse Off (%) (%) Better Off (%)
1 years/9 years 62.24 (2645) 35.69 (9121) 46.27 (6054)
2 years/9 years 21.53 (915) 21.51 (5499) 23.60 (3088)
3 years/9 years 8.85 (376) 14.82 (3788) 13.21 (1729)
4 years/9 years 4.05 (172) 10.11 (2583) 7.67 (1003)
5 years/9 years 1.91 (81) 7.25 (1852) 4.62 (605)
6 years/9 years 0.89 (38) 4.89 (1250) 2.63 (344)
7 years/9 years 0.42 (18) 3.27 (837) 1.31 (171)
8 years/9 years 0.09 (4) 1.74 (444) 0.51 (67)
9 years/9 years 0.02 (1) 0.72 (185) 0.18 (24)
Italic numbers in parentheses are the number of times
household heads hold a particular type of expectation.
Note: Italic numbers in parentheses are the number of
times household heads hold a particular type of expectation.
Table 1C. Housing Tenure Over Time
1993 1994 1995 1996 1997
Owned outright (%) 23.03 22.04 19.84 20.47 18.26
Owned mortgage (%) 47.45 48.97 50.94 49.62 46.63
Rented council (%) 10.81 11.05 11.91 12.33 12.57
Rented private (%) 18.41 17.94 17.32 17.58 22.54
1998 1999 2000 2001
Owned outright (%) 19.67 23.01 22.84 24.01
Owned mortgage (%) 46.73 43.75 44.79 44.40
Rented council (%) 11.89 10.80 10.79 10.98
Rented private (%) 21.70 22.43 21.58 20.61
Table 2. Summary Statistics
Full Sample
1993-2001
Mean SD Max Min
LMORT 4.714 4.977 14.876 -0.423
PMORT 0.207 0.456 46.154 0
FEI 1.206 0.601 2 0
HFEI 1.505 0.879 4 0
Age 42.186 12.186 65 18
[Age.sup.2] 1928.171 1050.790 4225 324
Male 0.714 0.452 1 0
White 0.919 0.273 1 0
Married 0.545 0.498 1 0
Cohabiting 0.119 0.325 1 0
No. of children 0.721 1.049 8 0
Household size 1.972 0.835 9 1
Employed 0.682 0.466 1 0
Self-employed 0.112 0.316 1 0
Unemployed 0.052 0.222 1 0
Not in labor market 0.028 0.164 1 0
Student 0.056 0.231 1 0
L(savings+investments) 1.431 2.030 8.722 -0.550
L(household income) 6.896 0.959 10.709 -3.017
Degree 0.154 0.361 1 0
Further education 0.230 0.421 1 0
A Level 0.117 0.321 1 0
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) 0.176 0.381 1 0
GCSE (grades < C) 0.036 0.187 1 0
Other education 0.045 0.208 1 0
Mortgage type
Endowment mortgage -- -- -- --
Repayment mortgage -- -- -- --
Type of insurance
Mortgage protection
plan -- -- -- --
Structural insurance -- -- -- --
Contents insurance -- -- -- --
Other insurance -- -- -- --
Reason for extra
mortgage payments
Building extension -- -- -- --
Home improvements -- -- -- --
Car purchase -- -- -- --
Other reason -- -- -- --
42,894
Mortgagees Only
1993-2001
Mean SD Max Min
LMORT 9.889 0.884 14.876 -0.423
PMORT 0.574 0.586 46.154 0
FEI 1.244 0.608 2 0
HFEI 1.592 0.909 4 0
Age 40.608 9.993 65 18
[Age.sup.2] 1748.890 844.259 4225 324
Male 0.825 0.380 1 0
White 0.928 0.259 1 0
Married 0.660 0.474 1 0
Cohabiting 0.129 0.335 1 0
No. of children 0.797 1.025 7 0
Household size 2.079 0.768 8 1
Employed 0.800 0.400 1 0
Self-employed 0.129 0.335 1 0
Unemployed 0.023 0.150 1 0
Not in labor market 0.010 0.097 1 0
Student 0.015 0.123 1 0
L(savings+investments) 1.824 2.149 8.722 -0.550
L(household income) 7.229 0.722 10.709 -2.852
Degree 0.196 0.397 1 0
Further education 0.280 0.449 1 0
A Level 0.130 0.337 1 0
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) 0.176 0.381 1 0
GCSE (grades < C) 0.037 0.189 1 0
Other education 0.034 0.180 1 0
Mortgage type
Endowment mortgage 0.424 0.494 1 0
Repayment mortgage 0.189 0.391 1 0
Type of insurance
Mortgage protection
plan 0.313 0.463 1 0
Structural insurance 0.402 0.490 1 0
Contents insurance 0.208 0.406 1 0
Other insurance 0.034 0.180 1 0
Reason for extra
mortgage payments
Building extension 0.068 0.252 1 0
Home improvements 0.156 0.362 1 0
Car purchase 0.016 0.124 1 0
Other reason 0.062 0.242 1 0
19,941
For brevity, we have omitted summary statistics for year and
region. SD = standard deviation; Max = maximum; Min = minimum.
Table 3A. Housing Tenure and Head of
Household's Financial Expectations
Owner Occupier
(Mortgage)
M.E. TSTAT
FEI 0.0096 (2.96)
Age 0.0477 (22.02)
[Age.sup.2] -0.0007 (25.53)
Male 0.1170 (14.91)
White 0.0694 (6.72)
Married 0.1593 (17.68)
Cohabiting 0.0844 (7.85)
No. of children -0.0199 (5.97)
Household size -0.0386 (8.86)
Employee 0.0567 (3.51)
Self-employed 0.0595 (3.12)
Unemployed -0.1308 (5.93)
Not in labor market -0.1237 (4.24)
Student -0.1844 (8.37)
L(savings+investments) 0.0128 (8.68)
L(household income) 0.1351 (25.51)
Degree 0.1489 (13.45)
Further education 0.1535 (18.09)
A Level 0.1388 (13.45)
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) 0.1106 (12.03)
GCSE (grades < C) 0.0983 (5.82)
Other education 0.0871 (6.02)
Observations 42,894
[chi square] (120) 25,689.65 p = [0.000]
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.2378
Rent Rent
(Council) (Private)
M.E. TSTAT M.E. TSTAT
FEI 0.0121 (4.58) -0.0019 (0.55)
Age -0.0239 (21.92) -0.0219 (16.55)
[Age.sup.2] 0.0002 (17.55) 0.0003 (16.53)
Male 0.0103 (2.80) -0.0936 (15.85)
White -0.0072 (1.23) 0.0329 (5.24)
Married -0.1029 (18.71) -0.0787 (12.66)
Cohabiting -0.0376 (10.19) -0.0252 (3.91)
No. of children -0.0153 (7.28) 0.0498 (23.34)
Household size 0.0114 (4.80) 0.0174 (5.73)
Employee 0.0350 (3.73) 0.0471 (5.46)
Self-employed 0.0683 (4.13) -0.0828 (10.08)
Unemployed 0.0748 (4.05) 0.1752 (9.21)
Not in labor market 0.2187 (7.24) -0.0174 (1.15)
Student 0.0713 (3.81) 0.1575 (8.67)
L(savings+investments) -0.0018 (2.09) -0.0203 (16.85)
L(household income) -0.0352 (16.82) -0.0810 (28.30)
Degree 0.0117 (2.06) -0.1864 (53.97)
Further education -0.0150 (3.21) -0.1364 (35.14)
A Level -0.0293 (6.03) -0.1262 (33.29)
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) -0.0300 (6.58) -0.0898 (22.35)
GCSE (grades < C) -0.0313 (4.75) -0.0629 (9.28)
Other education -0.0255 (3.41) -0.0625 (10.42)
Observations
[chi square] (120)
Pseudo [R.sup.2]
(i) Other controls: year and region dummies in each panel;
(ii) M.E. denotes marginal effect and TSTAT denotes the
t-statistic; (iii) The base category is owned outright.
Table 3B. Housing Tenure and Household Financial Expectations
Owner Occupier
(Mortgage)
M.E. TSTAT
HFEI 0.0037 (1.13)
Age 0.0476 (21.98)
[Age.sup.2] -0.0007 (25.51)
Male 0.1167 (14.87)
White 0.0696 (6.73)
Married 0.1591 (17.62)
Cohabiting 0.0846 (7.86)
No. of children -0.0199 (6.00)
Household size -0.0395 (8.96)
Employee 0.0569 (3.52)
Self-employed 0.0599 (3.14)
Unemployed -0.1302 (5.90)
Not in labor market -0.1230 (4.22)
Student -0.1844 (8.38)
L(savings+investments) 0.0128 (8.67)
L(household income) 0.1353 (25.54)
Degree 0.1491 (15.05)
Further education 0.1538 (18.13)
A Level 0.1389 (13.46)
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) 0.1108 (12.06)
GCSE (grades < C) 0.0985 (5.83)
Other education 0.0872 (6.02)
Observations 42,894
[chi square] (120) 25,680.22 p = [0.000]
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.2377
Rent (Council) Rent (Private)
M.E. TSTAT M.E. TSTAT
HFEI 0.0076 (3.96) 0.0011 (0.43)
Age -0.0240 (22.02) -0.0219 (16.34)
[Age.sup.2] 0.0002 (17.67) 0.0003 (16.38)
Male 0.0102 (2.78) -0.0937 (15.74)
White -0.0072 (1.24) 0.0327 (5.21)
Married -0.1046 (18.89) -0.0787 (12.58)
Cohabiting -0.0381 (10.34) -0.0256 (3.98)
No. of children -0.0154 (7.32) 0.0498 (22.93)
Household size 0.0099 (4.12) 0.0172 (5.58)
Employee 0.0350 (3.74) 0.0470 (5.45)
Self-employed 0.0689 (4.16) -0.0831 (10.06)
Unemployed 0.0759 (4.09) 0.1743 (9.17)
Not in labor market 0.2160 (7.19) -0.0161 (1.06)
Student 0.0711 (3.81) 0.1578 (8.67)
L(savings+investments) -0.0018 (2.11) -0.0203 (16.66)
L(household income) -0.0352 (16.80) -0.0811 (27.40)
Degree 0.0122 (2.14) -0.1865 (47.85)
Further education -0.0147 (3.14) -0.1366 (33.52
A Level -0.0292 (6.02) -0.1262 (31.71)
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) -0.0298 (6.53) -0.0900 (21.92)
GCSE (grades < C) -0.0311 (4.71) -0.0630 (9.28)
Other education -0.0254 (3.39) -0.0626 (10.39)
Observations
[chi square] (120)
Pseudo [R.sup.2]
(i) Other controls: year and region dummies; (ii) M.E. denotes
marginal effect and TSTAT denotes the t-statistic; (iii) The
base category is owned outright.
Table 4A. Mortgage Debt and Individual Financial
Expectations (Sample: [htc.sub.ht] = 1)
LMORT PMORT
FEI 0.0245 (3.85)# 0.0239# (4.40)
Age 0.0832 (12.91)# -0.0082# (2.14)
[Age.sup.2] -0.0014 (17.08)# -0.0001# (2.46)
Male 0.1014 (3.84)# 0.0366# (3.01)
White -0.0226 (0.58)# 0.0189# (1.18)
Married 0.0654 (3.25)# -0.0059# (0.46)
Cohabiting 0.0754 (3.64)# 0.0620# (4.39)
No. of children 0.0022 (0.32)# -0.0153# (3.71)
Household size -0.0176 (2.08)# -0.0343# (5.96)
L(savings+investments) -0.0021 (0.99)# -0.0069# (4.19)
L(household income) 0.1017 (10.27)# 0.0471# (6.75)
Degree 0.3102 (11.21)# 0.0046# (0.33)
Further education 0.1379 (5.92)# 0.0104# (0.81)
A Level 0.1091 (3.94)# -0.0106# (0.71)
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) 0.0767 (2.94)# -0.0062# (0.45)
GCSE (grades < C) 0.1318 (2.90)# 0.0150# (0.65)
Other education 0.0790 (1.67)# 0.0112# (0.48)
Endowment mortgage 0.0613 (4.96)# 0.0424# (4.92)
Repayment mortgage 0.0751 (5.02)# -0.0095# (0.93)
Mortgage protection plan 0.0167 (1.85)# 0.0117# (1.57)
Structural insurance -0.0361 (3.33)# -0.0167# (1.92)
Contents insurance 0.0563 (4.19)# 0.0409# (3.88)
Other insurance 0.0030 (0.15)# 0.0056# (0.32)
Building extension -0.0311 (1.44)# -0.0276# (1.84)
Home improvements 0.0101 (-0.66)# -0.0334# (3.17)
Car purchase 0.0019 (0.05)# 0.0086# (0.30)
Other reason for extra
mortgage 0.1822 (8.57)# 0.0614# (4.04)
South East 0.1789 (5.73)# 0.0614# (4.10)
South West 0.1105 (2.65)# 0.0647# (3.47)
East Anglia -0.0222 (0.41)# 0.0428# (1.75)
East Midlands -0.1594 (3.80)# 0.0504# (2.66)
West Midlands -0.1448 (3.42)# 0.0424# (2.25)
North West -0.1726 (4.37)# 0.0544# (3.12)
York and Humberside -0.1800 (4.20)# 0.0761# (4.10)
North East -0.3777 (7.26)# 0.0640# (3.00)
Wales -0.2037 (5.85)# 0.0674# (4.04)
Scotland -0.1202 (3.73)# 0.1249# (8.24)
1993 -0.1390 (8.50)# 0.0603# (4.50)
1994 -0.1134 (7.26)# 0.0377# (2.88)
1995 -0.1035 (6.85)# 0.0865# (6.66)
1996 -0.1103 (7.55)# 0.0499# (3.89)
1997 -0.0806 (5.73)# 0.0749# (6.04)
1998 -0.0743 (5.47)# 0.0627# (5.09)
1999 -0.0834 (6.75)# 0.0277# (2.47)
2000 -0.0216 (1.85)# 0.0119# (1.08)
Inverse mills ratio term 0.1718 (4.70)# 0.0969# (4.08)
[rho] 0.7272 0.1383
[chi square] (47) 2626.81 p = [0.000] 2601.34 p = [0.000]
Observations 19,941
Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
Note: Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics indicated with #.
Table 4B. Mortgage Debt and Household Financial
Expectations (Sample: [htc.sub.ht] = 1)
HFEI 0.0067 (2.61)# 0.0098# (2.70)
Age 0.0810 (12.60)# -0.0092# (2.42)
[Age.sup.2] -0.0014 (16.78)# -0.0001# (2.22)
Male 0.0989 (3.73)# 0.0356# (2.92)
White -0.0254 (0.66)# 0.0180# (1.13)
Married 0.0633 (3.14)# -0.0078# (0.61)
Cohabiting 0.0742 (3.59)# 0.0611# (4.32)
No. of children 0.0027 (0.39)# -0.0154# (3.72)
Household size -0.0177 (2.08)# -0.0358# (6.14)
L(savings+investments) -0.0021 (1.02)# -0.0069# (4.20)
L(household income) 0.0973 (9.88)# 0.0456# (6.54)
Degree 0.3118 (11.25)# 0.0057# (0.41)
Further education 0.1379 (5.91)# 0.0110# (0.86)
A Level 0.1090 (3.93)# -0.0105# (0.70)
GCSE (grades [greater
than or equal to] C) 0.0769 (2.94)# -0.0061# (0.44)
GCSE (grades < C) 0.1307 (2.87)# 0.0149# (0.64)
Other education 0.0797 (1.68)# 0.0112# (0.48)
Endowment mortgage 0.0610 (4.93)# 0.0416# (4.82)
Repayment mortgage 0.0763 (5.11)# -0.0095# (0.92)
Mortgage protection plan 0.0171 (1.89)# 0.0118# (1.59)
Structural insurance -0.0362 (3.34)# -0.0168# (1.93)
Contents insurance 0.0565 (4.21)# 0.0411# (3.90)
Other insurance 0.0031 (0.16)# 0.0055# (0.31)
Building extension 0.0308 (1.43)# -0.0280# (1.87)
Home improvements -0.0101 (0.66)# -0.0335# (3.17)
Car purchase 0.0024 (0.06)# 0.0091# (0.32)
Other reason for extra
mortgage 0.1823 (8.58)# 0.0619# (4.07)
South East 0.1768 (5.65)# 0.0611# (4.07)
South West 0.1113 (2.67)# 0.0650# (3.48)
East Anglia -0.0227 (0.42)# 0.0431# (1.76)
East Midlands -0.1587 (3.78)# 0.0506# (2.66)
West Midlands -0.1452 (3.42)# 0.0426# (2.26)
North West -0.1742 (4.40)# 0.0540# (3.09)
York and Humberside -0.1810 (4.22)# 0.0756# (4.07)
North East -0.3798 (7.28)# 0.0633# (2.96)
Wales -0.2017 (5.78)# 0.0678# (4.06)
Scotland -0.1206 (3.73)# 0.1252# (8.25)
1993 -0.1413 (8.64)# 0.0586# (4.37)
1994 -0.1150 (7.37)# 0.0365# (2.78)
1995 -0.1054 (6.98)# 0.0853# (6.58)
1996 -0.1113 (7.62)# 0.0494# (3.85)
1997 -0.0818 (5.83)# 0.0745# (6.01)
1998 -0.0749 (5.52)# 0.0625# (5.07)
1999 -0.0834 (6.75)# 0.0278# (2.48)
2000 -0.0217 (1.86)# 0.0120# (1.10)
Inverse mills ratio term 0.1554 (4.23)# 0.0902# (3.81)
[rho] 0.7291 0.1397
[chi square] (47) 2600.87 p = [0.000] 2581.41 p = [0.000]
Observations 19,941
Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
Note: Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics indicated with #.
Table 5. Mortgage Debt and Financial
Expectations (Sample: [htc.sub.ht] = 1)
Panel A: Individual LMORT PMORT
Whether optimistic 0.0212 (2.47) 0.0503 (5.67)
Whether pessimistic -0.0314 (-2.50) -0.0342 (2.45)
Inverse mills ratio term 0.1150 (3.35) 0.0439 (2.83)
[rho] 0.7376 0.1301
[chi square] (48) 2180.26 p = [0.000] 2181.05 p = [0.000]
Observations 19,941
Panel B: Household
Whether 1 person optimistic 0.0221 (2.63) 0.0430 (4.83)
Whether [greater than or
equal to] 2 people
optimistic 0.0105 (0.56) 0.0815 (3.87)
Whether 1 person
pessimistic 0.0120 (1.24) -0.0277 (-2.55)
Whether [greater than or
equal to] 2 people
pessimistic -0.0145 (-0.91) -0.0662 (-3.71)
Inverse mills ratio term 0.1205 (3.51) 0.0453 (1.89)
[rho] 0.7375 0.1299
[chi square] (50) 2179.99 p = [0.000] 2184.83 p = [0.000]
Observations 19,941
(i) Other controls as in Table 4;
(ii) italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
Table 6. Mortgage Debt and Financial
Expectations--Tobit Model (Sample: All)
Panel A: Individual LMORT PMORT
FEI 0.1384 (3.24)# 0.0186 (3.20)#
[rho] 0.5093 (7.81)# 0.3766 (6.77)#
[chi square] (47) 22,315.46 p = [0.000] 12,075.80 p = [0.000]
Observations 42,894
Uncensored
(i.e., mortgagees) 19,941
Left censored 22,953
Panel B: Household
HFEI 0.0368 (2.28)# 0.0031 (2.89)#
[rho] 0.5094 (3.88)# 0.3769 (6.81)#
[chi square] (47) 22,317.75 p = [0.000] 12,062.59 p = [0.000]
Observations 42,894
Uncensored
(i.e., mortgagees) 19,941
Left censored 22,953
Controls as in Table 4, excluding the inverse mills ratio
term. Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
Note: Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics
indicated with #.
Table 7. Mortgage Debt and Relative Financial
Expectations (Sample: [htC.sub.ht] = 1)
Panel A: Individual LMORT PMORT
[FEI.sub.rt] 0.0296 (3.82)# 0.0310 (3.81)#
Inverse mills ratio term 0.1627 (4.51)# 0.0721 (2.71)#
[rho] 0.7274 0.1385
[chi square] (47) 2623.36 p = [0.000] 2268.87 p = [0.000]
Observations 42,894
Panel B: Household
[HFEI.sub.rt] 0.0122 (2.83)# 0.0162 (2.24)#
Inverse mills ratio term 0.1763 (4.82)# 0.0893 (3.34)#
[rho] 0.7291 0.1763
[chi square] (47) 2610.09 p = [0.000] 2263.32 p = [0.000]
Observations 42,894
Controls as in Table 4. Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.
Note: Italic numbers in parentheses are t-statistics indicated with #.