Smuggling illegal versus legal goods across the U.S.-Mexico border: a structural equations model approach.
Buehn, Andreas ; Eichler, Stefan
1. Introduction
In this article, we study smuggling across the U.S.-Mexico border
from 1975 to 2004. We contribute to the literature in the following
ways: First, we treat smuggling as an unobservable variable. Using a
Multiple Indicators Multiple Causes (MIMIC) model we capture the latent nature of smuggling and identify its determinants and long run trends.1
Secondly, we argue that the analysis of smuggling has been incomplete so
far; existing studies merely analyze the causes of trade
misinvoicing--illegal trade or smuggling of legal goods--which represent
only a fraction of total illegal trade. To improve the understanding of
illegal trade, we distinguish between smuggling illegal goods versus
smuggling legal goods.
The types of smuggling differ with respect to the goods being
smuggled, the agents involved in smuggling, the smuggling incentive, and
the intensity of law enforcement. Trade misinvoicing occurs when
entrepreneurs misreport the value of legal exports or imports to evade tariffs and taxes and is commonly considered a peccadillo: Smugglers
usually bribe officials or are fined a fee. Smuggling illegal
"freight" such as illicit drugs and illegal immigrants,
however, often involves dangerous criminals who commit serious offenses
and who, if caught, face severe punishment. As a result, their incentive
to smuggle is related to the intensity of law enforcement rather than
tax or tariff evasion.
Studying the U.S.-Mexican case is appropriate, as most illegal
drugs and immigrants enter the United States via the Mexican border. The
large income disparity between the two nations may explain the high U.S.
demand for illegal goods, which relatively poor Mexicans are willing to
meet despite the risks involved. We examine whether the Clinton and Bush
Administrations succeeded in reducing smuggling across the border
through intensified border enforcement.
Using a simple microeconomic framework, we determine which
microeconomic incentives affect the two types of smuggling. The
hypotheses are then tested in a MIMIC model that studies the impact of
observed causes (the microeconomic incentives to smuggle) on the latent
phenomenon, smuggling, as indicated by observable macroeconomic variables. Applying the benchmarking procedure promoted by
Dell'Anno and Schneider (2006) and Dell'Anno (2007), we
calculate a time series for each type of smuggling. We find that
smuggling in illegal goods from Mexico to the United States decreases
when Mexican labor market conditions improve and U.S. border enforcement
is intensified. The Mexican recessions in 1982-1983 and 1995 led to
large temporary increases in smuggling to $113 billion and $87 billion,
respectively. Smuggling in illegal goods decreased overall, however,
from $116 billion in 1984 to $27 billion in 2004; this reduction can be
attributed to stricter U.S. border enforcement and better Mexican job
prospects.
Smuggling legal goods is driven by real exchange rates and tariff
and tax evasion. Export misinvoicing fluctuated between underinvoicing
values of $0.2 billion and overinvoicing values of $0.7 billion, while
import misinvoicing switched from underinvoicing, peaking at $1.6
billion in 1983, to recent overinvoicing--up to $3.8 billion in 2002.
This pattern can be attributed to substantial tariff reductions in
accordance with the GATT in 1987 and the North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA) in 1994.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews
the smuggling literature. Section 3 considers the incentives driving the
two types of smuggling in a microeconomic framework. Section 4 explains
the empirical methodology. Section 5 describes the indicators of
smuggling. Section 6 presents the estimation results and long-term trends for the smuggling of illegal and legal goods. Section 7
concludes.
2. Literature
The existing smuggling literature focuses on trade misinvoicing,
that is, the false declaration of legal imports and exports. One strand of the theoretical literature analyzes the welfare effects of trade
misinvoicing. Bhagwati and Hansen (1973) show that despite the classic
view, smuggling can distort welfare, as legal traders are squeezed out
by smugglers who operate at inferior terms of trade but profit by
circumventing tariffs. Pitt (1981) shows that the welfare consequences
of smuggling are ambiguous. He argues that legal trade and smuggling
coexist as firms camouflage their smuggling activities by also
conducting legal trade.
Another strand of the theoretical literature, initiated by Pitt
(1981), analyzes the determinants of trade misinvoicing. Pitt argues
that smuggling is positively correlated with the price disparity,
defined as the difference between the actual domestic price and the
tariff-inclusive world market price. If, for example, the domestic price
of an exportable good exceeds its world market price, it can only be
exported legally at a loss, indicating that most of the actual exports
are traded illegally. Martin and Panagariya (1984) and Norton (1988)
consider the costs of smuggling. They find that stricter law enforcement
serves as a deterrent to smuggling. Pitt (1984) analyzes the black
market premium (BMP) for foreign exchange as a determinant of smuggling.
He finds that the black market equilibrates the supply of foreign
exchange from illegal exports and its demand to purchase illegal
imports. Biswas and Marjit (2007) find that export (import)
underinvoicing is positively (negatively) correlated with the BMP, since
the foreign exchange from the unreported transaction is sold (paid) on
the black market.
The empirical literature studies the determinants of trade
misinvoicing using data on trade discrepancy. These studies conclude
that if the import figures of the importing country fall short of
(exceed) the export figures of the corresponding exporting country,
import underinvoicing (overinvoicing) must be taking place in the
importing country.2 As the empirical literature is vast, Table 1
provides a comprehensive overview and summarizes the findings of
previous studies.
Bhagwati (1964) analyzes trade data for Turkey and its major
trading partners. He finds import underinvoicing for transport equipment
and machinery. Both product categories feature high tariffs that by far
exceed the BMP and thus motivate import underinvoicing. McDonald (1985)
finds that export underinvoicing is positively correlated with export
taxes and BMP. Pohit and Taneja (2003) conclude that informal trade
between India and Bangladesh results in avoidance of administrative
burden. Fisman and Wei (2007) find that misinvoicing for cultural
properties is highly correlated with the extent of corruption in the
exporting country. Berger and Nitsch (2008) confirm this finding for an
extended set of product categories. Beja (2008) estimates the amount of
China's unreported trade between 2000 and 2005 to be $1.4 trillion.
Farzanegan (2008) estimates export and import misinvoicing in Iran using
a MIMIC approach and finds that the smuggling of legal goods in Iran
accounted for 6-25% of total trade between 1970 and 2002.
3. Micro-Foundations of Smuggling Incentives
We argue that smugglers of illegal goods respond to different
incentives than do smugglers of legal goods. The following uses a simple
microeconomic approach to determine the expected impact of different
determinants on both types of smuggling.3
Determinants of Illegal Goods Smuggling
The representative risk-neutral Mexican smuggler maximizes her
expected profit with respect to the amount of illegal goods or persons
to be smuggled into the United States, [S.sup.ill]. Equation 1 outlines
the revenue from smuggling illegal goods, R([S.sup.ill]):
R ([S.sup.ill] = (1 + v)e[p.sup.US] [S.sup.ill]. (1)
The smuggler sells Sm illegal Mexican goods at price [p.sup.US] in
the United States and converts the dollar-denominated proceeds on the
black market to Mexican pesos, earning BMP v over the official exchange
rate e.4 The expected costs of smuggling, E[C([S.sup.ill])], arise from
the risk of being caught by U.S. Border and Customs Protection,5 as
outlined in Equation 2:
E[C([S.sup.ill])] = prob([S.sup.ill], H)F,
with
[partial derivative]prob([S.sup.ill],H)/[partial
derivative][S.sup.ill] > 0, [[partial derivative].sup.2]prob]
[([S.sup.ill]).sup.2] > 0, [partial
derivative]prob([S.sup.ill],H)/[partial derivative]H > 0. (2)
The smuggler is apprehended with probability prob([S.sup.ill], H)
and faces the punishment cost F. We assume that the probability of
apprehension is a convex function of the amount of illegal goods being
smuggled and depends positively on the exogenous border enforcement, H;
that is, the more officers patrolling the U.S.-Mexico border, the more
likely smugglers are to be caught. If the smuggler is apprehended, she
will be sentenced to prison. The cost of punishment F therefore
represents the opportunity cost of lost labor income, (1 - u)w, during
imprisonment. The higher the Mexican wages, w, and the lower the Mexican
unemployment rate, u, the higher the cost of punishment, F:
F = f[(1 - uw], with [partial derivative]f[(1 - u)w]/[partial
derivative]u < 0, [partial derivative]f[(1 - u)w]/[partial
derivative]w > 0. (3)
Using Equations 1-3, the expected nominal profit from smuggling
illegal goods E([[pi].sup.ill]) is
E ([[pi].sup.ill]) = (1 + v)[ep.sup.US] [s.sup.ill ] - prob
([S.sup.ill,] H)f[(1 - u)w]. (4.1)
To study the determinants of smuggling illegal goods in real terms,
we denominate the expected profit in Mexican goods by dividing Equation
4.1 by the Mexican price index, [p.sup.MEX]. Equation 4.2 shows the
expected real profit from smuggling, whereby the real exchange rate is
defined as e = [ep.sup.US]/[p.sup.MEX]:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII](4.2)
Real profit optimization with respect to the amount of smuggling,
[S.sup.ill], yields the result that the marginal revenue from smuggling
equals the marginal cost of smuggling:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
Equation 5 determines how the optimal amount of illegal goods to
smuggle, [S.sup.ill], reacts to changes in the incentive variables. We
derive the following hypotheses: A higher BMP, v, increases the
incentive to smuggle, d[S.sup.ill]/dv > 0, ceteris paribus, as
converting dollars into pesos on the black market is more profitable. A
higher real exchange rate, that is, a real depreciation of the peso
against the dollar, increases smuggling, d[S.sup.ill]/d[epsilon] > 0,
ceteris paribus, as revenues rise in terms of Mexican goods. (6) Higher
Mexican wages and lower Mexican unemployment reduce the incentive to
smuggle, that is, both d[S.sup.ill]/dw < 0 and d[S.sup.ill]/du > 0
hold. Hence, better Mexican job prospects decrease smuggling by raising
the opportunity costs of imprisonment if apprehended, (1 - u)w. Thus, we
expect smuggling activities to rise during Mexican recessions, when
Mexican labor market conditions worsen. More intense border enforcement
should lead to a decrease in the smuggling of illegal goods,
d[S.sup.ill]/dH < 0, ceteris paribus, as this increases the
probability of apprehension and, thus, the expected cost of smuggling.
Determinants of Legal Goods Smuggling/Trade Misinvoicing
Export Misinvoicing
A Mexican entrepreneur exports a given amount of legal goods, X, to
the United States. In order to save on Mexican income taxes and to
benefit from the BMP, she has an incentive not to report the total
amount of exports. Export underinvoicing, [S.sup.x] > 0, thus means
that the reported amount of exports, X - [S.sup.x], is lower than the
actual amount of exports, X. (7) Equation 6 describes the Mexican
exporter's expected profits, E([[pi].sup.x]):
E([pi].sup.x]) = (1 - t)[ep.sup.US](x- [S.sup.x]) + (1 +
v)[ep.sup.US][S.sup.x] - prob([S.sup.X)]F, (6)
where
[partial derivative] prob([S.sup.x])/[partial
derivative][S.sup.x]>O and [[partial derivative].sup.2]
prob([S.sup.x])/[([partial derivative][S.eup.x]).sup.2] > 0.
Given the total amount of exports, X, the Mexican exporter decides
how many exports to report and how many to underinvoice. She sells the
reported (legal) exports X - [S.sup.x] at [p.sup.US] in the United
States and converts the dollar-denominated proceeds at the official
exchange rate e into pesos, generating a legal after-tax export revenue
of (1 - t)[ep.sup.US](x - [S.sup.x]), where t denotes the income/profit
tax. (8) The unreported (misinvoiced) exports, [S.sup.x], are sold at
[p.sup.US] in the United States. The dollar-denominated smuggling
revenue is then converted into pesos on the black market, where the
misinvoicer profits from the BMP, v, over the official exchange rate, e.
The expected cost of export underinvoicing arises from the risk
that the misinvoicing will be detected by the authorities with
probability prob([S.sup.x]) and that the exporter will subsequently face
the punishment cost F, which represents exogenous expenses for bribes or
fines. The detection probability is assumed to be convex in the amount
of export underinvoicing. Dividing Equation 6 by the Mexican price
index, [p.sup.MEX], and using the definition of the real exchange rate,
[epsilon] = [ep.sup.US]/[P.sup.MEX], yields the Mexican export
underinvoicer's real expected profit:
E([[pi].sup.x]/[p.sup.MEX]) = (1 - t)[epsilon]X + (v +
t)[epsilon][S.sup.x] - prob]([S.sup.x]) F/[p.sup.MEX].
Real profit optimization over the amount of export underinvoicing,
[S.sup.x], again yields the result
that the marginal revenue equals the marginal cost of smuggling:
(v + t)[epsilon] = [partial derivative]prob([S.sup.x])/[partial
derivative][S.sup.x] F/[p.sup.MEX; with [[partial derivative].sup.2]
prob([S.sup.x])/[([partial derivative][S.sup.2]) > 0.(8)
We hypothesize the following effects of smuggling incentives on
export underinvoicing: A higher BMP, v, should cause export
underinvoicing to rise ceteris paribus, d[S.sup.x]/dv > 0, as the
exchange rat--adjusted price spread between unreported and reported
exports increases. A real depreciation of the peso against the dollar
should lead to higher export underinvoicing ceteris paribus,
d[S.sup.x]/d[epsilon] > 0, as Mexican goods become more competitive.
(9) Higher Mexican incomel profit taxes, t, should lead to more export
underinvoicing ceteris paribus, d[S.sup.x]/dt > 0, as illegal/
unreported Mexican exports are not subject to taxation and thus become
more competitive over legal/reported Mexican exports. Tax evasion
therefore appears to be an important motive for export misinvoicing.
Import Misinvoicing
The Mexican entrepreneur imports a fixed amount of legal goods, M,
from the United States and decides how many imports to report, M -
[S.sup.M], and how many to underinvoice, [S.sup.M] > 0. Equation 9.1
describes the Mexican importer's expected profit, E([[pi].sup.M]):
E([[pi].sup.M])=(1 - t)[R(M)-[ep.sup.US](1 + q)(M -[S.sup.M])] -(l
+ v)[ep.sup.US][S.sup.M] - prob([S.sup.M])F, (9.1)
where
[partial derivative]prob([S.sup.M])/[partial derivative][S.sup.M]
> 0 and [[partial derivatie].sup.2] prob([s.sup.M])/[([partial
derivative][S.sup.M]).sup.2] > 0.
The Mexican entrepreneur imports M goods--some reported, some
unreported--from the United States and sells them in Mexico, earning
R(M) pesos. She spends [ep.sup.US](1 + q)(M - [S.sup.M]) pesos to import
the reported (legal) American goods, where q denotes the Mexican import
tariff levied on reported American goods. After paying the Mexican
income/profit tax, t, the Mexican importer makes an after-tax profit of
(1 - t)[R(M) - [ep.sup.US](1 + q)(M - [S.sup.M])] pesos on her reported
transactions. For the unreported (misinvoiced) U.S. imports, [S.sup.M],
she spends (1 + v)[ep.sup.US][S.sup.M] pesos paying the BMP, v, to buy
the required dollars on the black market. The import misinvoicer faces
the expected cost of punishment prob([S.sup.M])F, where prob([S.sup.M])
denotes the probability of being caught and F denotes the subsequent
bribes or fines. Equation 9.2 describes the Mexican importer's real
expected profit:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9.2)
Real profit optimization with respect to the amount of import
underinvoicing, [S.sup.M], yields the result that the marginal benefit
equals the marginal cost of smuggling: (10)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (10)
Intuitionally, the optimal amount of import underinvoicing
[S.sup.M] reacts to changes in incentive in the opposite direction of
the optimal amount of export underinvoicing, thus:
A higher BMP, v, decreases the incentive to underinvoice imports
ceteris paribus, d[S.sup.M]/dv < O, as it becomes more expensive to
buy U.S. dollars for unreported imports on the black market.
A real depreciation of the peso against the dollar, d[epsilon] >
0, should decrease the amount of import underinvoicing ceteris paribus,
d[S.sup.M]/d[epsilon] < 0, as Mexican products gain competitiveness
over misinvoiced American products.
A rise in Mexican incomelprofit taxes should reduce import
underinvoicing ceteris paribus, d[S.sup.M]/dt < 0, as
illegal/unreported Mexican imports cannot be claimed as tax exempt and,
thus, lose profitability compared to legal/reported Mexican imports.
Finally, we expect higher tariff rates to increase import
underinvoicing, ceteris paribus, d[S.sup.M]/dq > 0, as tariff evasion
increases the profitability of unreported imports.
4. Empirical Methodology
The MIMIC model relates observable causal and indicator variables
to a per se unobservable phenomenon. (11) Thus, it allows us to deal
with the multiple causes and the multiple effects of smuggling across
the U.S.-Mexico border. The MIMIC model has two parts: the structural
equation model and the measurement model. 12 In the structural equation
model, smuggling is determined by a set of exogenous causes, in our case
the microeconomic smuggling incentives described above. The structural
equation model is given by
[eta] = [gamma]' + [??], (11)
where each [x.sub.i], i = 1, ..., q in the (q x 1) vector x is a
potential cause of the latent variable rl and [gamma]' =
([[gamma].sub.i], [[gamma].sub.2], ..., [[gamma].sub.q]) is a vector of
coefficients describing the relationships between the latent variable
and its causes. The error term g represents the component of the latent
variable [eta] not explained by the causes. The variance of g is denoted
by [psi]. The measurement model links the latent variable to its
indicators:
y = [lambda][eta][ + [ [[epsilon]. (12)
In this model, y' = ([y.sub.1], [y.sub.2], ..., [y.sub.p]) is
a vector of indicator variables that measures the latent variable
smuggling (see section 5). [lambda] is the vector of regression
coefficients, and [epsilon]' is a (1 x p) vector of white noise
disturbances, that is, [epsilon] ~ (0, [[THETA].sub.[epsilon]]).
The structural and the measurement model equations can be used to
derive a reducedform multivariate regression model:
y = [product] x + z, (13)
where [product] = [[lambda].sub.[gamma]' is a matrix with rank
equal to 1. The endogenous variables [y.sub.j], j = 1, ..., p are the
latent variable [eta]'s indicators, and the exogenous variables [x.sub.i], i = 1, ..., q are its causes. The error term z =
[lambda][zeta] + [epsilon] is a (p x 1) vector of linear combinations of
the white noise error terms [??] and [epsilon] from the structural
equation and the measurement model, that is, z - (0, [OMEGA]). The
covariance matrix [OMEGA] is given by Cov(z) = E[[[lambda].sub.[??]] +
[epsilon])] = [lambda][lambda]' [psi] + [[THETA].sub.[epsilon] and
is constrained like If. The estimation of the model therefore requires
the normalization of one of the elements of the vector X to an a priori value (Bollen 1989).
The model's parameters are estimated using the variances and
covariances among the observable causal and indicator variables.
Assuming that an unobservable variable generates this pattern, the
decomposition of the MIMIC model's covariance matrix yields the
structure between the observed variables and the latent variable (see
Bollen [1989] for details). The values for the parameters and
covariances are then estimated to produce a MIMIC model covariance
matrix that is as close as possible to the sample covariance matrix of
the observed causes and indicators.
5. Measurement of Smuggling
In the measurement model, the indicators are regressed on a--per se
undefined--latent variable. After defining each type of smuggling, we
select indicators to measure each type appropriately. Thus, the meaning
of the latent variable depends on how well the indicators correspond to
the operational definition.
Of course, indicators are often only imperfectly linked to the
latent variable (Bollen 1989), but it is obvious from Equation 12 that
all of them are alternative measures of the same latent variable: That
is, a change in the latent variable affects its indicators. This can be
clarified further by taking the structural model into account. Within
the theoretical framework from section 3, we identify the microeconomic
incentives that determine the profitability of each type of smuggling.
If, for example, border enforcement is intensified, the cost for
smugglers of illegal goods increases, and the latent macroeconomic
amount of illegal goods smuggled should decrease. Thus, a change in the
microeconomic incentive structure transmits uniformly to the
macroeconomic aggregate of all types of smugglers of illegal goods be it
smugglers of illegal drugs or illegal immigrants. The indicators
discussed below all measure the total amount of each type of smuggling,
as determined by the microeconomic incentive structure.
Indicators for Smuggling of Illegal Goods
Our conceptual definition of illegal goods smuggling comprises the
inflow of illegal drugs and illegal immigrants from Mexico to the United
States. We do not consider smuggling in other types of illegal goods,
for example, alcohol or bootlegs. The reasons for this are that illegal
drugs and immigrants are at the center of the political debate on
whether to increase U.S. border patrol and estimates about the size of
these types of smuggling necessary to calculate the time trend--are
available.
To explain illegal goods smuggling in the measurement model, in
particular illegal drugs and immigrants, we use the following
macroeconomic indicators: linewatch and non-linewatch apprehensions,
real drug seizures, and availability of drugs in the United States.
Smugglers of illegal drugs and illegal immigrants have in common that
they have to cross the U.S.-Mexico border to bring their illegal
"freight" to the United States. To stop this illegal inflow,
the U.S. border patrol makes an enormous effort to apprehend smugglers
crossing the border. One of the objectives of the National Border Patrol
Strategy of 2004 (Office of Border Patrol 2004) is to "detect,
apprehend, and deter smugglers of humans, drugs, and other
contraband." If illegal goods smuggling increases the number of
apprehensions should also increase, ceteris paribus. Thus, we expect
that linewatch and non-linewatch apprehensions, that is, the number of
persons apprehended at the U.S.-Mexico border and inside the United
States, are positively correlated with the smuggling of illegal goods.
Another indicator of illegal goods smuggling is drugs seized by the
border control. Given the efforts of the United States to fortify the
border against the inflow of illegal goods, we expect drug seizures to
increase as illegal goods smuggling rises, ceteris paribus. Of course,
several smugglers successfully cross the border and succeed in their
smuggling activities. Thus, we also include the availability of drugs as
another indicator in order to account for illegal goods that have been
smuggled into the United States successfully (that is, undetected). We
expect drug availability to increase as illegal goods smuggling rises,
ceteris paribus.
Indicators for Smuggling of Legal Goods
In contrast to smugglers of illegal goods, smugglers of legal goods
break the law from their offices rather than at the border. As no data
on convicted misinvoicers are available, we employ balance of payments
data--in particular trade discrepancies and data on errors and
omissions--to proxy legal goods smuggling as common in the literature.
Assuming that industrialized countries like the United States correctly
report trade figures, discrepancies between U.S. figures and Mexican
figures result from misreporting by Mexican importers/ exporters. Export
underinvoicing by Mexican exporters is the difference between U.S.
imports from Mexico (reported by the United States) and Mexican exports
to the United States (reported by Mexico).13 Import underinvoicing by
Mexican importers is the difference between U.S. exports to Mexico
(reported by the United States) and Mexican imports from the United
States (reported by Mexico).
Data on errors and omissions are included in the Mexican balance of
payments and are used as a second indicator of legal goods smuggling.14
Unreported Mexican exports (export underinvoicing) lead to inflows of
foreign exchange. These exports do not appear in the trade balance but
rather increase the errors and omissions of the Mexican balance of
payments by the amount of export underinvoicing. We therefore conclude
that the higher the export underinvoicing, the higher the errors and
omissions, ceteris paribus. Likewise, the lower the import
underinvoicing, the higher the errors and omissions.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
6. Empirical Analysis
This section presents the results of our MIMIC model estimations
and the long-term trends in the smuggling of illegal goods and legal
goods (export and import misinvoicing) across the U.S.-Mexico border.
Recognizing these different types of smuggling as outlined in section 3,
we estimate three different MIMIC models.
The first model tests whether the microeconomic causal variables
affect the smuggling of illegal goods, as hypothesized in section 3.
Figure 1 illustrates the path diagram of illegal goods smuggling using
the indicators explained in section 5. Table A1 in the Appendix presents
the empirical identification, data sources, and definitions of the
theoretical variables.
The second and third models test the determinants of legal goods
smuggling, also hypothesized in section 3 using the indicators outlined
in section 5. Figure Al in the Appendix displays the path diagrams for
export and import misinvoicing.
Data
To estimate the MIMIC models, we use monthly data from 1975 to
2004. Because data on the BMP are available only through December 1998
(the date of the last issue of Pick's World Currency Report) and
data on errors and omissions in the Mexican balance of payments are
available only from January 1980, however, some of our estimations are
limited to the 1980-1998 time period.
We test for unit roots, as MIMIC models with nonstationary time
series produce misleading estimates. We therefore examine each time
series for those periods subsequently used in the estimations under the
null hypothesis of a unit root against the alternative of stationarity
using the Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) test. The Kwiatkowski, Phillips,
Schmidt, and Shin test, which tests stationarity against the alternative
of the presence of a unit root, is used to cross-check the ADF
test's results.
We find that most variables, except for the BMP and the real
exchange rate from 1975-1998 and 1975-2004, are not stationary in
levels. However, for 1980-1998 and 1980-2004, we cannot reject the null
hypothesis of a unit root for the BMP, as both unit root tests produce
divergent results. Consequently, we use the BMP in first differences in
our estimations covering these time periods. Other variables found
nonstationary in levels are also transformed in this way and re-tested.
As the null hypothesis of a unit root is now rejected, we use the first
difference of all variables except for the BMP and real exchange rate
from 1975-1998 and 19752004 in the MIMIC model estimations. (15)
Estimation Results
Tables 2 and 3 present the results of our MIMIC model estimations
for smuggling illegal and legal goods. (16) As explained in section 4,
the estimation of a MIMIC model requires the normalization of one
indicator for each latent variable that also determines the unit of
measurement of the latent variable (Bollen 1989). (17) In the illegal
goods smuggling estimations, we set the coefficient of linewatch
apprehensions to 1. In the case of legal goods smuggling, we set the
variable errors and omissions to 1 for export misinvoicing and to -1 for
import misinvoicing. (18)
For the smuggling of illegal goods, we estimate seven different
MIMIC model specifications by varying either the time period or the set
of indicator variables. We include all causal variables considered in
section 3 except for the BMP, which is not included in estimations for
1999-2004. (19) In the four model specifications for the smuggling of
legal goods, we vary the time period only.
The MIMIC model estimations for the smuggling of illegal goods show
that this kind of smuggling reacts only to changes in smuggling costs.
Thus, the unemployment rate, real wages, and border enforcement are the
major causes and have the theoretically expected impact on smuggling.
Higher wages and lower unemployment increase opportunity costs during
imprisonment and, thus, reduce smuggling in illegal goods. More intense
border enforcement significantly deters illegal goods smuggling for all
specifications estimated. This variable approximates the probability of
being caught smuggling at the border. The higher this probability, the
higher the expected costs for smugglers and, thus, the lower the
smuggling of illegal goods, ceteris paribus. By contrast, changes in the
variables affecting revenues from smuggling illegal goods do not
significantly influence smuggling: That is, the BMP and the real
exchange rate are not significant for any specification. It seems that
smugglers live at the subsistence level and have to smuggle illegal
goods to earn a living for their families. The decision whether or not
to engage in smuggling is then based on the opportunity cost, that is,
on the employment opportunities in the official economy and on the
probability of being apprehended.
Turning to the indicators, we find a strongly significant, positive
relationship between illegal goods smuggling and the number of
apprehensions, which confirms our hypothesis that the number of failed
smuggling attempts indicates the level of illegal goods smuggling. The
relationship between drug seizures/drug availability and smuggling is
only sometimes statistically significant. While we find the hypothesized
positive sign for all specifications, drug seizures are significant for
specifications 1 and 3 only while drug availability is not significant.
In the MIMIC models for the smuggling of legal goods, all causal
variables except for the BMP are statistically significant at
conventional significance levels and have the expected sign. Hence, the
data confirm the theoretical hypotheses in section 3. A real
depreciation of the peso against the U.S. dollar leads to higher export
underinvoicing as the competitiveness of Mexican goods increases.
Moreover, the higher Mexican income/profit taxes are, the stronger the
incentive is to underinvoice exports, as illegal/unreported Mexican
exports are not taxed and ate thus more competitive. Again, an important
motive to underinvoice exports is tax evasion. In the case of import
misinvoicing, real peso depreciation against the U.S. dollar decreases
the amount of import underinvoicing as Mexican products gain
competitiveness over misinvoiced U.S. imports. A rise in Mexican
income/profit taxes lowers import underinvoicing. Illegal/ unreported
Mexican imports cannot be claimed as tax exempt and thus lose
profitability compared to legal/reported Mexican imports, which confirms
our tax evasion argument. In contrast, a higher tariff rate increases
import underinvoicing, supporting the common view that import
underinvoicing is motivated by tariff evasion.
All estimated MIMIC models show satisfactory goodness-of-fit
statistics, as shown in Tables 2 and 3. The models fit the data fairly
well, and the q-plots demonstrate a sufficiently normal distribution of
the standardized residuals, that is, of the difference between the
observed and the fitted covariance matrix. Thus, we can accept the
validity of the estimated models and conclude that all specifications
are suitable to calculate long-term trends in the smuggling of illegal
and legal goods.
Long-Term Trends in Illegal Goods Smuggling
The estimated MIMIC coefficients allow us to determine the
dimensionless time pattern of smuggling only. To obtain the market value
of smuggling over time, we convert the MIMIC index into
"real-world" figures measured in U.S. dollars. In the first
step, we calculate an exogenous base value for illegal goods smuggling
across the U.S.-Mexico border in 2000 using expert estimates. As
mentioned in section 5, we focus on the two types of smuggled illegal
"goods" prominently discussed in the media: illegal immigrants
and illegal drugs. In the second step, this base value is used to
calibrate a time series of smuggling by applying the benchmarking
procedure promoted by Dell'Anno and Schneider (2006),
Dell'Anno (2007), and Dell'Anno and Solomon (2008).
The average inflow of illegal (unauthorized) adult Mexican
immigrants to the United States is estimated at about 330,000 per year
between 2000 and 2007 (Hoefer, Rytina, and Baker 2008; Passel and Cohn
2008). Because we cannot assess the "market value" of these
illegal immigrants, we calculate the average wage earned while working
in the United States illegally using the Mexican Migration Project (MMP)
database. Since 1982, the MMP has conducted annual surveys of (illegal)
Mexican immigrants. Using data on the employment characteristics of
Mexicans who entered the United States illegally, including data on
their duration of stay, we calculate the average salary an illegal
Mexican immigrant earns during her stay in the United States. Table 4
illustrates that illegal Mexican immigrants, on average, worked in the
United States for 20.08 months and earned $26,325. Based on this, we
calculate that the 330,000 illegal Mexican immigrants earn wages
amounting to $8.7 billion each year.
To calculate the base value of illegal drugs smuggled across the
U.S.-Mexico border, we employ expert estimates, as illustrated in Table
5. According to Rhodes et al. (2001), Americans spent $61.2 billion on
illegal drugs in 2000. Using the estimated "Mexican" share of
these drugs, (20) we quantify the market value of drugs smuggled across
the U.S.-Mexico border at $31.4 billion in 2000. Aggregating the
calculated size of illegal immigration and illegal drugs smuggling, we
obtain an exogenous estimate for illegal goods smuggling across the
U.S.-Mexico border of $40.1 billion in 2000.
This base value allows us to calculate a time series for illegal
goods smuggling by applying a benchmarking procedure. Unfortunately, no
consensus exists in the literature with regard to which benchmarking
procedure to use. We use the methodology promoted by Dell'Anno and
Schneider (2006), Dell'Anno (2007), and Dell'Anno and Solomon
(2008). In the first step, the MIMIC model index of smuggling is
calculated by multiplying the coefficients of the significant causal
variables by the respective raw time series. For the numerical example
of specification 4 the structural equation is given as (21)
[[??].sub.t]/[Smugglers.sub.2000] = 0.05 x [x.sub.1t] - 0.05 x
[x.sub.2t] - 0.64 x [x.sub.3t] (14)
and measures illegal goods smuggling per apprehended smuggler in
2000 according to the MIMIC model's identification rule. (22) Next,
this index is converted into a time series of illegal goods smuggling,
which takes up the base value of $40.1 billion in 2000. Thus, the annual
U.S. dollar amount of illegal goods smuggling tit at time t is given as
follows:
[[??].sub.t]/[Smugglers.sub.2000]
[Smugglers.sub.2000]/[[??].sub.2000] [[eta].sup.*.sub.2000] =
[[??].sub.t]/ [[??].sub.t] [[??].sup.*.sub.2000] = [[??].sub.t], (15)
where ([[??].sub.t]/[Smugglers.sub.2000]) denotes the value of the
MIMIC index at t according to Equation 14,
([[??].sub.2000]/[Smugglers.sub.2000]) is the base value of this index
in 2000, and [[eta].sup.*.sub.2000] is the exogenous estimate of illegal
goods smuggling, amounting to $40.1 billion in 2000.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The final estimates of illegal goods smuggling over the last three
decades are calculated using specifications 4 through 7. (23) As shown
in Figure 2, all calculated indices have a similar pattern. (24) Table
A2 in the Appendix presents selected annual estimates for illegal goods
smuggling.
Illegal goods smuggling seems to be driven largely by macroeconomic
conditions in Mexico and by changes in U.S. border enforcement policy.
The two major Mexican recessions, triggered by a debt crisis in
1982-1983 and by a currency crisis in 1994-1995, resulted in a
significant increase in the smuggling of illegal goods to $113 billion
in 1983 and $87 billion in 1995. Both economic downturns were associated
with rising unemployment and falling real wages in Mexico and were a
push factor for Mexican smugglers. As Mexican labor market conditions
worsened, many Mexicans chose to engage in illegal smuggling activities
as an alternative source of income.
We also find evidence that a stricter U.S. border enforcement
policy since the Immigration Reform and Control Act of 1986 may have
contributed to a long-term decline in the smuggling of illegal goods,
which fell from $116 billion in 1986 to $27 billion in 2004. The number
of person-hours spent by U.S. border patrol policing the U.S.-Mexico
border increased from 2.7 million in 1986 to 9.7 million in 2004. This
rise in border enforcement activities effectively raised the probability
of apprehension, thereby reducing smuggling. In 2003, the pattern of
illegal goods smuggling reversed as an unintended consequence of a
change in U.S. drug policy (Carpenter 2005). U.S. officials believed
that by focusing on the drug cartels' top figures, rather than on
petty smugglers at the border, they could achieve huge decreases in drug
trafficking. But the new policy led only to a decentralization of the
drug trade: Instead of the kingpins who had controlled it before, there
are now more than 300 small groups engaged in illegal drug smuggling
(Carpenter 2005).
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Long-Term Trends in Legal Goods Smuggling
As with illegal goods smuggling, Equation 15 is applied to convert
the MIMIC index into a time series of legal goods smuggling using the
significant causal variables in specifications 9 (export misinvoicing)
and 11 (import misinvoicing). The base values for benchmarking are taken
from Eggerstedt, Hall, and van Wijnbergen (1995), who present estimates
for misinvoicing in the U.S.-Mexican trade using U.S. Department of
Commerce and Banco de Mexico data. We use the overinvoicing estimate of
$588.3 million in 1984 as the base value for export misinvoicing and the
underinvoicing value of $914.4 million in 1984 for import misinvoicing.
Figure 3 shows the estimated time series for legal goods smuggling.
While export misinvoicing exhibits temporary fluctuations but no time
trend, import misinvoicing is permanently affected by U.S.-Mexican trade
integration. The reduction of Mexican tariffs on U.S. imports after
Mexico's accession to GATT in 1987 and to NAFTA in 1994 resulted in
a permanent switch from import underinvoicing--motivated by tariff
evasion--to import overinvoicing--motivated by tax evasion.
7. Summary and Conclusion
This article examines the determinants of and long-term trends in
smuggling across the U.S.-Mexico border, distinguishing between the
smuggling of illegal and legal goods. Working out the microeconomic
incentives of the two types of smuggling, we hope to improve
understanding of this phenomenon. It seems reasonable to assume that
smugglers who traffic illegal drugs or illegal immigrants respond to
different incentives than do trade misinvoicers. As smuggling is an
illegal and, thus, unobservable, activity, we use a MIMIC approach in
our analysis and calculate the long-term trends in illegal and legal
goods smuggling across the U.S.-Mexico border.
The results of the MIMIC model are robust and confirm most of our
theoretical hypotheses. We find that illegal goods smuggling declines
when Mexican labor market conditions improve or when U.S. border
enforcement activities are intensified, as the cost of smuggling rises
in this context. Confirming the competitiveness argument, export
(import) misinvoicing is positively (negatively) correlated with real
peso depreciation. Import misinvoicing is positively correlated with
Mexican import tariffs, pointing to the incentive of tariff evasion.
Export (import) misinvoicing is positively (negatively) correlated with
Mexican taxes on income and profit, pointing to the incentive of tax
evasion.
The estimated long-term trends for both types of smuggling show the
sensitivity of smuggling to major macroeconomic events. Import
misinvoicing has switched from underinvoicing to overinvoicing over the
last 20 years as a result of reduced import tariffs, following
Mexico's accession to GATT in 1987 and to NAFTA in 1994. Illegal
goods smuggling rose temporarily during the Mexican recessions in
1982-1983 and 1995, but the overall trend is negative, decreasing by
almost $90 billion from 1984 to 2004; this decline can be attributed to
improved labor market conditions in Mexico and a successful U.S. border
enforcement policy. Indeed, the increase in U.S. border patrol hours has
increased the probability of apprehension and strengthened the deterrent
to smuggle.
Analyzing smuggling using a MIMIC model has some shortcomings that
are, however, widely accepted in other fields that involve the study of
unobservable phenomena, such as the shadow economy or corruption. First,
although the model tracks the development of smuggling over time, the
estimations for the volume of smuggling depend on the exogenous estimate
used for calibration. Researchers can carefully check its size and
reliability, but the final estimate remains an approximation. Second,
difficulties arise for MIMIC applications to time-series data because of
the limitations in the ability to check the residuals' properties.
Finally, other variables for which data are not available, such as tax
morality or socioeconomic factors, may influence smuggling.
Nevertheless, this article contributes to the understanding of
smuggling, and the results have important implications for the policy
debate. The smuggling of illegal drugs and immigrants across the
U.S.-Mexico border remains a major issue for U.S. national security.
Illegal drug abuse leads to casualties, rising health care costs, and
lower employment in the United States (French, Roebuck, and Alexandre
2001). In addition, illegal immigration not only affects labor market
conditions in the United States but represents a serious humanitarian
crisis. It is unbearable that myriad Mexicans die when attempting to
cross the border illegally. (25)
Despite the successful border enforcement policy, several options
are available to further reduce illegal goods smuggling. Increased
bilateral trade and U.S. aid and foreign direct investment to Mexico,
for example, would improve Mexican labor market conditions, thereby
reducing the incentive to smuggle. The United States could also further
increase linewatch hours or invest in border patrol technologies.
Finally, the United States could provide financial and/or technical
support to intensify patrolling activities on the Mexican side of the
border.
Trade misinvoicing seems to be a less serious problem, given that
it is a relatively small-scale financial crime with no loss of human
life. Also, the scope for political intervention is limited. Tariffs
have already been reduced significantly, and it is unlikely that
exchange rate policy would be used to combat trade misinvoicing.
Appendix
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
Table Al. Data Sources and Definitions
Variable Definition
BMP (black (Black market exchange rate--official
market premium) exchange rate)/official exchange rate
Real exchange rate Nominal official exchange rate
(peso/$U.S.) x U.S.
Consumer Price Index (CPI)/Mexican
(MX) CPI
MX unemployment Unemployed persons as % of total labor
rate force, seasonally adjusted
MX real wages Nominal wage in manufacturing deflated
with MX CPI, seasonally adjusted
U.S. border enforcement Number of person-hours spent
by the U.S. Customs and
Border Protection (CBP) for border
patrols/total apprehensions, seasonally
adjusted
U.S. linewatch Individuals apprehended by the
apprehensions CBP at international
boundaries of the United
States, seasonally adjusted
U.S. non-linewatch Individuals apprehended by the CBP
apprehensions inside the United States
at traffic checkpoints, raids on
businesses, or interior patrols,
seasonally adjusted
U.S. real drug seizures Illegal drugs seized by the CBP,
in million $U.S., deflated by
U.S. CPI
U.S. drug availability % of U.S. 12th-graders
reporting that "marijuana is
fairly or very easy" to obtain
MX taxes on % of GDP
income/profit
MX taxes on % of imports
international trade
MX errors and Balance of payments position,
omissions million $U.S.
Import misinvoicing [U.S. exports--MX imports
(CIF, FOB adjusted)]
Export misinvoicing [U.S. imports (CIF, FOB
adjusted)--MX exports]
Variable Source
BMP (black 1975-1982: Pick (1955-1982),
market premium) various issues; 1983-1998:
Pick (1983-1998), various issues
Real exchange rate Nominal exchange rate:
International Monetary Fund
(IMF) International Financial Statistics;
MX CPI: Banco de
Mexico; U.S. CPI: Bureau of
Labor Statistics
MX unemployment 1975-1984: Fleck and Sorrentino
rate (1994); 1985-2004: DECD Main
Economic Indicators
MX real wages 1975M1-1998M5: Hanson and
Spilimbergo (1999),
1998M6-2004M4: Instituto
National de Estadfstica,
Geografia e Informatica (INEGI)
U.S. border enforcement Unpublished records of the U.S.
Immigration and
Naturalization Service (INS),
Hanson (2006)
U.S. linewatch Unpublished records of the INS, Hanson
apprehensions (2006)
U.S. non-linewatch Unpublished records of the INS, Hanson
apprehensions (2006)
U.S. real drug seizures Department of Homeland Security, Hanson
(2006)
U.S. drug availability Johnston et al. (2007)
MX taxes on 1975-2000 IMF Government
income/profit Statistics, 2001-2004 OECD
Revenue Statistics.
MX taxes on 1975-2000 IMF Government
international trade Statistics, 2001-2004 OECD
Revenue Statistics.
MX errors and IMF, International Financial
omissions Statistics
Import misinvoicing 1975-1980: IMF Directions of
Trade Statistics (DOTS)
Historical, 1981-2004: IMF DOTS
Export misinvoicing 1975-1980: IMF DOTS Historical, 1981-2004:
IMF DOTS
Table A2. Estimates for Illegal and Legal Goods Smuggling
Year Illegal Goods Export Import
Smuggling Misinvoicing Misinvoicing
(billion $U.S.) (billion $U.S.) (a) (billion $U.S.) (a)
1976 75.52
1977 84.68
1978 84.16
1979 78.81
1980 69.45 -0.03 0.l9
1981 71.99 -0.18 0.00
1982 74.24 -0.51 0.73
1983 113.11 -0.69 1.66
1984 115.99 -0.59 0.91
1985 114.36 -0.66 1.03
1986 116.36 -0.36 -0.59
1987 81.69 -0.47 -0.31
1988 86.58 -0.36 -0.71
1989 68.11 -0.19 -0.93
1990 76.20 -0.23 -0.18
1991 77.28 -0.29 0.52
1992 79.42 0.00 -1.17
1993 73.16 0.22 -3.30
1994 62.32 0.06 -3.50
1995 97.23 -0.51 -0.83
1996 79.77 -0.61 -0.32
1997 62.12 -0.36 -1.66
1998 50.07 -0.18 -2.59
1999 39.92 -0.02 -3.36
2000 40.10 -0.08 -3.03
2001 29.61 0.04 -3.77
2002 22.86 0.03 -3.83
2003 23.43 -0.06 -3.47
2004 27.36 -0.30 -2.28
The indices for illegal goods smuggling, export misinvoicing, and
import misinvoicing are calculated using specifications 4, 9, and
11, respectively.
(a) Positive values indicate underinvoicing; negative values
indicate overinvoicing.
References
Beja, Edsel L. 2008. Estimating trade mis-invoicing from China:
2000-2005. China & Worm Economy 16:82-92.
Berger, Helge, and Volker Nitsch. 2008. Gotcha! A profile of
smuggling in international trade. CESifo Working Paper No. 2475.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N. 1964. On the under-invoicing of imports.
Bulletin of the Oxford University, Institute of Economics and Statistics
26:389-97.
Bhagwati, Jagdish N., and Bent Hansen. 1973. A theoretical analysis
of smuggling. The Quarterly Journal of Economies 87:172-87.
Biswas, Amit K., and Sugata Marjit. 2007. Preferential trade and
mis-invoicing: Some analytical implications. International Review of
Economies & Finance 16:13-8.
Bollen, Kenneth A. 1989. Structural equations with latent
variables. New York: John Wiley & Sons Publishing.
Bratsberg, Bernt. 1995. Legal versus illegal U.S. immigration and
source country characteristics. Southern Economic Journal 61:715-27.
Browne, Michael W., and Robert Cudeck. 1993. Alternative ways of
assessing model fit. In Testing structural equation models, edited by
Kenneth A. Bollen and J. Scott Long. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, pp. 445 55.
Buehn, Andreas, Alexander Karmann, and Friedrich Schneider. 2009.
Shadow economy and do-it-yourself activities: The German case. Journal
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. In press.
Buehn, Andreas, and Friedrich Schneider. 2008. MIMIC models,
cointegration and error correction: An application to the French shadow
economy. CESifo Working Paper No. 2200.
Carpenter, Ted G. 2005. Mexico is becoming the next Colombia. Cato
Institute Foreign Policy Briefing 87:1 8.
Dell'Anno, Roberto. 2007. The shadow economy in Portugal: An
analysis with the MIMIC approach. Journal of Applied Economics
10:253-77.
Dell'Anno, Roberto, and Friedrich Schneider. 2003. The shadow
economy of Italy and other OECD countries: What do we know? Journal of
Public Finance and Public Choice 21:97 120.
Dell'Anno, Roberto, and Friedrich Schneider. 2006. Estimating
the underground economy: A response to T. Breusch's critique.
Johannes Kepler University Linz, Department of Economics Working Paper
06/07.
Dell'Anno, Roberto, and Offiong H. Solomon. 2008. Shadow
economy and unemployment rate in USA: Is there a structural
relationship? An empirical analysis. Applied Economies 40:2537 55.
Drug Availability Steering Committee. 2002. Drug availability
estimates in the United States. Washington, DC: Office of National Drug
Control Policy.
Eggerstedt, Harald, Rebecca B. Hall, and Sweder van Wijnbergen.
1995. Measuring capital flight: A case study of Mexico. Worm Development
23:211-32.
Farzanegan, Mohammad R. 2008. Illegal trade in the Iranian economy:
Evidence from a structural model. CESifo Working Paper No. 2397.
Fausten, Dietrich K., and Brett Pickett. 2004. Errors &
omissions in the reporting of Australia's cross-border
transactions. Australian Economic Papers 43:101-15.
Fisman, Raymond, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2007. The smuggling of art, and
the art of smuggling: Uncovering the illicit trade in cultural property
and antiques. NBER Working Paper No. 13446.
Fleck, Susan, and Constance Sorrentino. 1994. Employment and
unemployment in Mexico's labor force. Monthly Labor Review 117:3
31.
Ford, Jess T. 2008. U.S. assistance has helped Mexican
counternarcotics efforts, but the flow of illicit drugs into the United
States remains high. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Accountability
Office.
French, Michael T., M. Christopher Roebuck, and Pierre K.
Alexandre. 2001. Illicit drug use, employment, and labor force
participation. Southern Economic Journal 68:349 68.
Hanson, Gordon H., and Antonio Spilimbergo. 1999. Illegal
immigration, border enforcement, and relative wages: Evidence from
apprehensions at the U.S.-Mexico border. American Economic Review
89:1337-57.
Hanson, Gordon H. 2006. Illegal migration from Mexico to the United
States. Journal of Economic Literature 44:869-924.
Hoefer, Michael, Nancy Rytina, and Bryan C. Baker. 2008. Estimates
of the unauthorized immigrant population residing in the United
States." January2007. Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Homeland
Security Office of Immigration Statistics.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1993. A guide to direction of
trade statistics. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.
Johnston, Lloyd D., Patrick M. O'Malley, Jerald G. Bachman,
and John E. Schulenberg. 2007. Monitoring the future national survey
results on drug use. 19752006. Volume l: Secondary, school students, NIH Publication No. 07-6205. Bethesda, MD: National Institute on Drug Abuse.
Joreskog, Karl G. 1970. A general method for analysis of covariance structures. Biometrika 57:239-51.
Martin, Lawrence, and Arvind Panagariya. 1984. Smuggling, trade and
price disparity: A crime-theoretic approach. Journal of International
Economics 17:201-17.
McDonald, Donogh C. 1985. Trade data discrepancies and the
incentive to smuggle. IMF Staff Paper 4:668-92.
Norton, Desmond A. G. 1988. On the economic theory of smuggling.
Economica 55:107-18.
Office of Border Patrol. 2004. "National border patrol
strategy." Accessed 24 November 2008. Available http://www.cbp.gov.
Passel, Jeffrey S., and D'Vera Cohn. 2008. Trend in
unauthorized immigration: Undocumented inflow now trails legal inflows.
Washington, DC: Pew Hispanic Center.
Pick, Franz. 1955-1982. Pick's currency yearbook, Various
issues. New York: Pick Publishing Corporation,
Pick, Franz. 1983-1998. Worm Currency Reports, Various issues. New
York: International Currency Analysis Inc.
Pitt, Mark M. 1981. Smuggling and price disparity. Journal of
International Economics 11:447 58.
Pitt, Mark M. 1984. Smuggling and the black market for foreign
exchange. Journal of International Economics 16:243-57.
Pohit, Sanjib, and Nisha Taneja. 2003. India's informal trade
with Bangladesh: A qualitative assessment. The Worm Economy 26:1187-214.
Rhodes, William, Mary Layne, Anne-Marie Bruen, Patrick Johnston,
and Lisa Becchetti. 2001. What America's users spend on illegal
drugs. Washington, DC: Office of National Drug Control Policy.
Schneider, Friedrich. 2005. Shadow economies around the world: What
do we really know? European Journal of Political Economy 21:598-642.
Schneider, Friedrich, and Dominik Enste. 2000. Shadow economies:
Size, causes, and consequences. The Journal of Economic Literature 38:77
114.
Schneider, Friedrich, and Dominik Enste. 2002. The shadow economy:
Theoretical approaches, empirical studies, and political implications.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
* Faculty of Business and Economics, Technische Universitaet
Dresden, Chair for Economics, esp. Monetary Economics, 01062 Dresden,
Germany: E-mail
[email protected]: corresponding author.
[dagger] Faculty of Business and Economics, Technische Universitaet
Dresden, Chair for Economics, esp. Monetary Economics, 01062 Dresden,
Germany; E-mail
[email protected]. We thank Gordon Hanson for
providing the data on Mexican wages and U.S. border enforcement. We are
also grateful to Alexander Karmann, Sunshine Moore, the editor, and two
anonymous referees for their many useful comments and suggestions on
this article. We also benefited from comments of participants of the
Lunchtime Seminar at Technische Universitaet Dresden. All remaining
errors are the authors' responsibility.
Received July 2008; accepted January 2009.
(1) MIMIC approaches were previously applied to estimate the
development of the shadow economy (see, for example, Dell'Anno and
Schneider [2003]; Schneider [2005]: and Dell'Anno [2007]). A
comprehensive overview of such studies is provided in Schneider and
Enste (2000, 2002).
(2) Analogously, export underinvoicing (overinvoicing) occurs in
the exporting country if the export figures of the exporting country
fall short of (exceed) the import figures of the importing country.
(3) Biswas and Marjit (2007) use a similar approach to study the
rationale for trade misinvoicing.
(4) The exchange rate, e, is defined as the price of 1 $U.S. in
terms of Mexican pesos. Thus, a rise in the exchange rate corresponds to
a depreciation of the peso against the dollar.
(5) Until 2003, the U.S. Customs Service. !!! BEGIN AUTH-ABST
(6) Per definition, v > - 1 holds, and thus,
d[S.sup.ill]/d[epsilon] > 0 generally applies.
(7) We define misinvoicing as underinvoicing, that is, as the
difference between the actual and the reported export/import figures.
Defining misinvoicing as overinvoicing would just reverse the
theoretical hypotheses.
(8) The variable t denotes the Mexican profit/income tax.
Obviously, only legal transactions are subject to taxation. For
simplicity, we do not consider any production or procurement costs.
(9) [dS.sup.x]/dv > 0 is true, as v + t > 0 holds in our
sample.
(10) The profit-maximizing Mexican importer focuses on minimizing
costs. Underinvoicing imports, [S.sup.M] > 0, therefore means cutting
back on legal expenditures (1 - t)(1 + q)[epsilon][S.sup.M] but
increasing illegal expenditures (1 + v)[epsilon][S.sup.M]. Thus, the
importer underinvoices if avoided legal costs exceed additional illegal
costs, (1 - t)(1 + q) - (1 + v) > 0.
(11) Joreskog (1970) first introduced structural equation models
into economics.
(12) A similar presentation of the MIMIC methodology can be found
in Buehn and Schneider (2008) and Buehn, Karmann, and Schneider (2009).
(13) The export figures are in FOB (Free on Board) prices, and the
import figures are in CIF (Cost, Insurance, and Freight) prices. In
order to make them comparable, we divide the export figures by an
adjustment factor of 1.1, as suggested by the International Monetary
Fund (IMF 1993), taking into account transport and insurance costs.
(14) In addition to trade misinvoicing, errors and omissions
reflect misreporting of capital flows and different schedules for
reporting goods in transit (see, for example, Fausten and Pickett
[2004]). However, trade misinvoicing is a popular instrument to
camouflage capital flight, and therefore, we assume the size of errors
and omissions to be mainly driven by trade misinvoicing (Eggerstedt,
Hall, and van Wijnbergen 1995).
(15) The unit root test results are available upon request. We also
tested for cointegration between I(l) indicators and the corresponding
causes but could not confirm any unambiguous cointegration relation.
(16) All calculations have been carried out with LISREL[R] Version
8.80. Tables 2 and 3 show the unstandardized coefficients, which are
used in section 6 to calculate the indices for illegal and legal goods
smuggling. As a robustness check, we also calculate these indices using
standardized coefficients. Neither the estimation results nor the
calculated indices are sensitive to the choice of coefficients.
(17) The choice of the indicator to fix the scale of the latent
variable does not affect the results.
(18) To calculate the smuggling indices in section 6, we use the
fixed indicator as an index variable, the value of which is expressed
relative to the base year value. Linewatch apprehensions are therefore
used as an index variable equal to (linewatch apprehensions at
t)/(linewatch apprehensions 2000), while errors and omissions are used
as an index equal to (errors and omissions at t)/(errors and omissions
1984).
(19) We could not estimate specification 3 by varying the set of
indicators because the variable drug availability still exhibits a unit
root for 1980-1998, even after taking the first difference.
(20) According to expert estimates shown in Table 5, most of the
cocaine and marijuana available in the United States is smuggled via the
Mexican border.
(21) [x.sub.1t], [x.sub.2t], and [x.sub.3t] represent the
unemployment rate, real wages, and border enforcement, respectively.
(22) As outlined in section 6, linewatch apprehensions are used as
an index variable, where the denominator equals linewatch apprehensions
in the base year 2000. As the latent variable is measured in units of
the fixed indicator, illegal goods smuggling is measured per apprehended
smuggler at the border in 2000.
(23) Specifications 1 through 3 cannot be used as they do not cover
the base year 2000.
(24) The pattern of the illegal goods smuggling index is not
dominated by one or two of the causes; although, the variable
"probability of apprehension" has a large coefficient and thus
influences the dynamics the most.
(25) The U.S.-Mexico case seems to be especially relevant in our
context, as illegal immigration is typically more likely the poorer and
the less distant the source country (see, for example, Bratsberg
[1995]).
Table 1. Review of the Empirical Literature on Trade Misinvoicing
Study Subject of Investigation
Bhagwati Import
(1964) underinvoicing
in Turkey
McDonald Incentives for
(1985) export
misinvoicing
Pohit and Informal trade
Taneja between
(2003) India and
Bangladesh
Fisman and Illicit trade in
Wei (2007) cultural
properties
in the
United States
Beja (2008) Trade
misinvoicing
in China
Berger and Bilateral trade
Nitsch discrepancies
(2008) at the 4-digit
product level
Farzanegan Illicit trade
(2008) in Iran
Study Approach
Bhagwati Descriptive analysis of trade
(1964) from Turkey to its major
trading partners: France,
Germany, Italy, the
Netherlands, and
the United States
McDonald Ordinary least squares (OLS)
(1985) regressions for 10 developing
countries; dependent
variable: trade discrepancies;
independent variables: BMP
and export taxes
Pohit and Direct survey approach
Taneja encompassing 100 traders
(2003) in each country
Fisman and Worldwide unbalanced panel
Wei (2007) for 1996-2005; dependent
variable: trade discrepancies
in cultural object and
antiques; independent
variables: corruption,
GDP per capita, dummies
Beja (2008) Descriptive analysis of trade
discrepancies
Berger and OLS regressions for
Nitsch misinvoicing in bilateral
(2008) trade with the United States,
Germany, China, the United
Kingdom, and Japan;
dependent variable: trade
discrepancies; independent
variables: corruption,
GDP per capita, distance
measure, dummy variables
Farzanegan MIMIC approach; causes:
(2008) fines, black market and
official exchange rate,
unemployment rate, tariffs;
indicators: government
revenues, import price
index, BMP, petroleum
consumption
Study Main Findings
Bhagwati Import underinvoicing in
(1964) transport equipment
and machinery
McDonald Mediocre statistical
(1985) evidence that the BMP
and export taxes
explain variations in
trade discrepancies
Pohit and Anonymous trading
Taneja transactions
(2003) characterize informal
trade; motivations are
the quick realization of
payments, less
paperwork, and
procedural delay
Fisman and Highly positive
Wei (2007) correlation between
trade discrepancies and
corruption (i.e., more
corrupt countries are
more likely to
misreport data)
Beja (2008) Trade misinvoicing
occurs mainly between
Hong Kong and the
United States
Berger and Trade discrepancies
Nitsch differ widely across
(2008) importers; export
underinvoicing
is prevalent in antiques
and bulky products;
strong positive
correlation with
corruption in the
source country
Farzanegan Illicit trade is related
(2008) positively to tariffs and
negatively to fines and
the unemployment
rate; adverse effects on
government revenues,
the import price index;
variation between 6%
and 25% of total trade
(1970-2002)
Table 2. MIMIC Model Estimations for Illegal Goods Smuggling
Specification
1 2
Time Period
1975-1998 1975-1998
Causes
BMP (through 1998) .02 (.99) .02 (.99)
Real exchange rate -.02 (-.80) -.02 (-.57)
Unemployment rate .05 ** (2.20) .05 *** (2.34)
Real wages -.03 ** (-2.26) -.05*** (-3.25)
Border enforcement -2.02 *** (-16.11) -2.01 *** (-16.27)
Indicators
Linewatch
apprehensions (fixed) 1.00
Non-linewatch
apprehensions 1.02***(9.33) 1.03 *** (9.23)
Drug seizures .12 ***
Drug availability .02 (.58)
Goodness-of-fit indices
Observations 282 282
Degrees of freedom 25 25
Chi-square (P-value) 5.27 (.99) 14.88 (.94)
RMSEA .00 .00
3 4
Time Period
1980-1998 1975-2004
Causes
BMP (through 1998) -.01 (-.61)
Real exchange rate -.02 (-.68) 0.02
Unemployment rate .05 ** (2.24) .05 * (1.69)
Real wages -.05 *** (-3.18) -.05 * (-1.91)
Border enforcement -2.05 *** (-15.87) -.64 *** (-9.15)
Indicators
Linewatch
apprehensions (fixed) 1.00
Non-linewatch
apprehensions 1.09 *** (9.57) .49 *** (13.66)
Drug seizures .09 * (1.68) .00 (.05)
Drug availability
Goodness-of-fit indices
Observations 223 358
Degrees of freedom 25 18
Chi-square (P-value) 2.79 (.97) 5.22 (.99)
RMSEA .00 .00
5 6
Time Period
1975-2004 1980-2004
Causes
BMP (through 1998)
Real exchange rate .02 (.44) .03
Unemployment rate .05 * (1.73) .06 ** (2.00)
Real wages -.05 ** (-2.20) -.06 *** (-2.36)
Border enforcement -.63 *** (-9.18) -.63 *** (-9.01)
Indicators
Linewatch
apprehensions (fixed) 1.00 1.00
Non-linewatch
apprehensions .50 *** (13.34) .48 *** (13.34)
Drug seizures .00 (.08)
Drug availability .04 (.75)
Goodness-of-fit indices
Observations 358 300
Degrees of freedom 18 18
Chi-square (P-value) 9.96 (.93) 4.91 (.99)
RMSEA .00 .00
7
Time Period
1980-2004
Causes
BMP (through 1998)
Real exchange rate .02
Unemployment rate .07 ** (2.05)
Real wages -.06 *** (-2.67)
Border enforcement -.61 *** (-8.99)
Indicators
Linewatch
apprehensions (fixed) 1.00
Non-linewatch
apprehensions .49 *** (12.95)
Drug seizures
Drug availability .04 (.76)
Goodness-of-fit indices
Observations 300
Degrees of freedom 18
Chi-square (P-value) 9.34 (.95)
RMSEA .00
z-statistics in parentheses. If the model fits the data
perfectly and the parameter values are known, the sample
covariance matrix equals the covariance matrix implied by the model
[i.e., S = [SIGMA]([theta])]. The null hypothesis of perfect fit
corresponds to a p-value of I . The root mean squared error of
approximation (RMSEA) measures the model's fit based on the difference
between the estimated and the actual covariance matrix. RMSEA values
smaller than 0.05 indicate a good fit (Browne and Cudeck 1993).
* Significance at the 10% level.
** Significance at the 5% level.
*** Significance at the 1% level.
Table 3. MIMIC Model Estimations for Legal Goods Smuggling
Export Misinvoicing
Specification
8 9
Time Period
1980-1998 1980-2004
Causes
BMP (through 1998) -.02 (-.46)
Real exchange rate .16 *** (2.82) .17 *** (3.52)
Taxes on income/profit .11 *** (2.54) .14 *** (3.15)
Taxes on international
trade
Indicators
Errors and omissions
(fixed) 1.00 1.00
Import misinvoicing
Export misinvoicing .19 (.52) .06 (.19)
Goodness-of-fit indices
Observations 228 305
Degrees of freedom 8 4
Chi-square (p-value) 1.85 (.98) .91 (.92)
RMSEA .00 .00
Import Misinvoicing
Specification
10 11
Time Period
1980-1998 1980-2004
Causes
BMP (through 1998) -.01 (-.27)
Real exchange rate -.13 *** (-2.45) -.16 *** (-3.45)
Taxes on income/profit -.10 *** (2.79) -.13 *** (-3.24)
Taxes on international
trade .06 ** (1.96) .06 * (1.68)
Indicators
Errors and omissions
(fixed) -1.00 -1.00
Import misinvoicing .17 (.67) .23 (.97)
Export misinvoicing
Goodness-of-fit indices
Observations 228 305
Degrees of freedom 9 8
Chi-square (p-value) 5.38 (.80) 1.74 (.98)
RMSEA .00 .00
z-statistics in parentheses. If the model fits the data perfectly and
the parameter values are known, the sample covariance matrix equals
the covariance matrix implied by the model [i.e., S = E(8)]. The null
hypothesis of perfect fit corresponds to a p-value of 1. RMSEA
measures the model's fit based on the difference between the estimated
and the actual covariance matrix. RMSEA values smaller than 0.05
indicate a good fit (Browne and Cudeck 1993).
* Significance at the l0% level.
** Significance at the 5% level.
*** Significance at the 1% level.
Table 4. Employment Characteristics of an Average Illegal Mexican
Immigrant during Her Stay in the United States
Duration in the
United States Months Worked Hours Worked
(in Months) per Year per Week
20.08 9.41 46.51
Duration in the
United States Hourly Wage Illegal Wages Earned in the
(in Months) (in $U.S.) United States (in $U.S.)
20.08 8.62 26,325
Source: Mexican Migration Project (MMP) database. The MMP data are
available online at http://mmp.opr.princeton.edu.
These average characteristics are drawn from a subsample of 270 survey
respondents who entered the United States illegally, that is, with or
without false documents, between 2000 and 2006.
Table 5. Base Value for Illegal Drugs Smuggled across U.S.-Mexico
Border in 2000
Cocaine Heroin
Total U.S. expenditures on
illegal drugs in 2000
(in billion $U.S.) (a) 35.3 10.0
Estimated average percentage
arriving in the United States
through U.S.-Mexico border 66 (b) 18 (c)
Estimated value of illegal drugs
smuggled through the U.S.-Mexico
border in 2000 (in billion $U.S.) 23.3 1.8
Marijuana Methamphetamine
Total U.S. expenditures on
illegal drugs in 2000
(in billion $U.S.) (a) 10.5 5.5
Estimated average percentage
arriving in the United States
through U.S.-Mexico border 55.6 (d) 9.1 (e)
Estimated value of illegal drugs
smuggled through the U.S.-Mexico
border in 2000 (in billion $U.S.) 5.8 0.5
Total
Total U.S. expenditures on
illegal drugs in 2000
(in billion $U.S.) (a) 61.2
Estimated average percentage
arriving in the United States
through U.S.-Mexico border
Estimated value of illegal drugs
smuggled through the U.S.-Mexico
border in 2000 (in billion $U.S.) 31.4
(a) Source: Rhodes et al. (2001, p. 31).
(b) The Interagency Assessment of Cocaine Movement estimates that 66%
of cocaine in the United States flows through Mexico (Ford 2008, p. 7).
(c) According to the Drug Availability Steering Committee (2002,
p. 61), 16-20% of heroin in the United States in 2000 originated in
Mexico.
(d) The Drug Availability Steering Committee (2002, p. 106, 119)
estimates that 4651 metric tons of Mexican marijuana arrived on the
U.S. market in 2000. The total amount of marijuana in the United
States in 2000 is estimated at between 5577 and 16,731 metric tons,
which corresponds to a Mexican market share of between 27.8% and
83.4%.
(e) According to the Drug Availability Steering Committee (2002,
pp. 82-5), 8.6-9.6% of methamphetamines in 2000 came from Mexico.