首页    期刊浏览 2025年02月12日 星期三
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Estimating the effect of individual time preferences on the use of disease screening.
  • 作者:Bradford, W. David ; Zoller, James ; Silvestri, Gerard A.
  • 期刊名称:Southern Economic Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:0038-4038
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:April
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Economic Association
  • 摘要:Time preferences are considered a fundamental characteristic of economic behavior. Standard utility theory, set in a dynamic model, has strong predictions about the effect of different rates of discounting on an individual's behavior. In general, we expect that higher rates of discounting for an individual will lead her to more strongly shift consumption of economic goods to the present and economic bads to the future, relative to a person with lower rates of preference for the present. Preventative health care can be categorized into two types: primary prevention and secondary prevention and screening. Primary prevention often requires patients to engage in activities they do not enjoy today (for example, reducing the intake of high-fat and high-sodium foods, exercising, losing weight, consuming pharmaceutical products, etc.) to prevent the onset of disease. Patients who discount the future more heavily should be less likely to demand primary preventative health care than patients with low rates of time discounting. However, secondary prevention involves screening and medical care intended to detect disease that may already be present and to prevent its advancement. Thus, while people who have high rates of discounting would still prefer to shift unpleasant health care into the future, their past neglect of primary prevention may raise the likelihood of disease such that the increased clinical need outweighs the economic tendency toward procrastination. Thus, more complex interactions between time preferences and the use of secondary prevention and screening are possible. Despite the potential importance of this time discounting effect on the demand for preventative medicine, the issue has not been heavily studied to date.
  • 关键词:Cancer;Cancer treatment;Cholesterol;Discount rates;Health screening;Medical research;Medical screening;Medicine, Experimental;Medicine, Preventive;Preventive health services;Preventive medicine

Estimating the effect of individual time preferences on the use of disease screening.


Bradford, W. David ; Zoller, James ; Silvestri, Gerard A. 等


1. Introduction

Time preferences are considered a fundamental characteristic of economic behavior. Standard utility theory, set in a dynamic model, has strong predictions about the effect of different rates of discounting on an individual's behavior. In general, we expect that higher rates of discounting for an individual will lead her to more strongly shift consumption of economic goods to the present and economic bads to the future, relative to a person with lower rates of preference for the present. Preventative health care can be categorized into two types: primary prevention and secondary prevention and screening. Primary prevention often requires patients to engage in activities they do not enjoy today (for example, reducing the intake of high-fat and high-sodium foods, exercising, losing weight, consuming pharmaceutical products, etc.) to prevent the onset of disease. Patients who discount the future more heavily should be less likely to demand primary preventative health care than patients with low rates of time discounting. However, secondary prevention involves screening and medical care intended to detect disease that may already be present and to prevent its advancement. Thus, while people who have high rates of discounting would still prefer to shift unpleasant health care into the future, their past neglect of primary prevention may raise the likelihood of disease such that the increased clinical need outweighs the economic tendency toward procrastination. Thus, more complex interactions between time preferences and the use of secondary prevention and screening are possible. Despite the potential importance of this time discounting effect on the demand for preventative medicine, the issue has not been heavily studied to date.

We investigate the direct impact of higher discount rates for an individual patient on her utilization of secondary prevention health screens using a compensating variations method. We evaluate one standard screening tool for men (prostate exams), two screening tools for women (PAP smears and mammography), and three general screens (dental exams, blood pressure tests, and cholesterol tests). To do this, we conducted a nationally representative survey of 2000 individuals over age 40. In addition to a set of standard demographic and economic questions and respondents' recent utilization of health care screening tests, individual rates of time preference were elicited by asking respondents to imagine they had won a lottery that will pay them $10,000 one year from that day, or some higher value six years from that day. (Respondents were also told the interest rate that a savings account would pay to generate the offered higher future payment.) They were then asked whether they would prefer the one-year delayed payout or the six-year delayed payout. Follow-up questions were asked to permit tighter bounds on the range of discount rates. All payments (and so, interest rates) were randomly assigned uniquely to each respondent.

With the data in hand, we model the joint likelihood that a respondent's latent discount rate lies within the interval indicated by their responses to the survey questions and that the respondent uses each of the six screening services; this model is estimated using a two-step maximum likelihood (LIML) method. We find that respondents have a discount rate of approximately 25.1% per year, on average, and that this discount rate increases with age. We find that discount rates have a generally negative relationship to the likelihood of screening, though a positive relationship is found for one disease screen--that for prostate cancer.

The results from these models should be of interest to economists in general, as well as health policy makers. For economists, this will be one of the few attempts to integrate a direct estimate of individual agents' actual discount rates with their demand for a time-dependant service. Consequently, the results will inform an important, but understudied, intersection between economic theory and empirical estimation. For policy makers, the information gain with respect to the demand for preventative services should be similarly informative. Clinicians are often frustrated by the difficulty in convincing patients to consume preventative health care. This reluctance is typically taken as an indication that patients are poorly informed, and so education programs are proposed as a solution. These results suggest, however, that at least some patients are in part making rational decisions based upon their discounting of the future.

The article proceeds by reviewing the literature on the estimation of individual rates of time preference and on models that predict the demand for preventative health care. Section 3 presents the details of our empirical models. Section 4 presents the results, and section 5 concludes with a discussion of the implications of this work and suggestions for future research.

2. Discount Rates and the Demand for Preventative Medicine

Michael Grossman (1972) introduced the concept of health as a component of human capital, which depreciates and in which investments can be made. Since that seminal contribution, a number of economists have investigated many dynamic aspects of health production and health care demand (Wagstaff 1986; van Doorslaer 1987; Wagstaff 1993; Grossman and Kaestner 1997; Zweifel and Breyer 1997). Theoretically, there have been a number of contributions that have explicitly modeled the role of time preferences on general human capital investments, of which health care is one. The Becker and Murphy (1988) model of rational addiction is perhaps the most successful of these. In that model, agents have foresight, and make human capital (and other consumption) decisions based upon the current utility and future utility generated. They find that higher rates of time preference tend to lead to lower current consumption of goods but will increase current consumption of addictive products. As Grossman (2000) notes, the Becker-Murphy model predicts a discount rate effect only under certain circumstances (the result is generally ambiguous in sign, and uncertain in magnitude). Ehrlich and Chuma (1990) explore the general implications of the Grossman (1972) model more completely and do pay particular attention to the impact of time preference. They find that increasing the rate of discounting the future tends to reduce investments in health capital--though this result holds only on average. The empirical research we present will test these "average" predictions from the Grossman (1972) and Ehrlich and Chuma (1990) models.

While the theoretical guidance is relatively clear with respect to the impact of time preference in health care demand, direct empirical tests of these predictions are notably absent from the literature. A number of authors have tested the effect indirectly, by demonstrating a schooling--health investment relationship that is consistent with an inverse relationship between discounting and human capital investment (Farrell and Fuchs 1982; Berger and Leigh 1989). However, these are only indirect tests and subject to multiple interpretations. Consequently, in the words of Grossman (2000, p. 401): "definitive evidence with regard to the time preference hypothesis is still lacking." While definitive evidence may be long in coming, we will at least present direct evidence in this work.

One paper that does examine time and risk preferences impacts on the use of medical screening exams is Picone, Sloan, and Taylor (2004)--though again the test with respect to time preferences is necessarily indirect. The authors propose a simple two-period model of expected utility maximization over the decision to undergo cancer screening. They predict that higher rates of discounting would lead to a reduction in the demand for screening. However, in their model the likelihood of disease does not depend upon the health state; there is no long-term clinical benefit from early detection (either in terms of likelihood of successful treatment or mortality), and they do not explicitly model time preferences (rather they make inferences about time preferences by assuming specific functional forms for utility). From a data perspective as well, the authors lack a direct measure of time preferences. Using the Health and Retirement Survey, they are only able to categorize individuals into short time-horizon or long time-horizon groups, which may or may not be directly correlated with having high or low time preferences over the long run. Despite these limitations, which the authors discuss, they find that women with longer life expectancies and self-identifying as having a long time horizon are more likely to undergo cancer screening. We will improve upon this work in two areas. Theoretically, we will expand their model to permit more direct assessment of the role of time preferences, which generates a somewhat more complex set of results. Empirically, we will have a direct estimate of each person's underlying discount rate, which we can then use as an explanatory variable in models that track their actual use of several types of screening (not just mammography and PAP smears among women). Unlike Picone, Sloan, and Taylor, though, we will not have a measure of respondents' risk preferences.

One reason that direct evidence on the relationship between time preference and health care demand is scarce is the difficulty in measuring time preference. Until fairly recently, the art of estimating individual discount rates has been poorly explored. However, there is currently a strong, and growing, literature on which to draw. (1) There are three primary methodologies for assessing individual discount rates. The first is to use natural experiments in which individuals must choose between alternatives with differential time dimensions, such that a discount rate can be inferred. An example of this literature is Warner and Pleeter (2001), who took advantage of data generated from an early retirement program in the U.S. military to estimate discount rates for enlisted men and officers. A second methodology is to present individuals with hypothetical or real payouts that vary in their time dimension in an experimental setting. Coller and Williams (1999) and Harrison, Lau, and Williams (2002) represent examples of this research. The third methodology employed is to present survey subjects with a set of hypothetical present and future payouts and estimate discount rates using a contingent valuation (CV) method. We will employ this latter approach.

As discussed, economists expect that time preferences will play an important role in medical decisions that have differential effects through time. Physicians have a variety of tools at their disposal to improve health, both current and future. Often, medical care is aimed at changing health behaviors or providing interventions in the present with some hope of reducing the incidence of acute conditions in the future. This type of health care, when no symptoms currently exist, is known as primary prevention. In addition, physicians may screen for diseases that the patient may currently have, though no definitive acute symptoms are present. This type of health care is known as secondary prevention (and is, technically, the sort that our empirical models will evaluate). While clinical tools are well validated, physicians often complain that they cannot convince large numbers of their patients to adopt primary prevention practices. For examples of such discussion in the cardiovascular realm, see reports from the 33rd Bethesda Conference Task Forces #3 (Ades et al. 2002) and #4 (Ockene et al. 2002; Giorgianni, Grana, and Keith 2003).

While there are a large number of potential health screens available to clinicians, a much smaller set have built up such a body of evidence in their favor that clear clinical guidelines exist to promote their use. For men, this set includes annual prostate exams; the American Cancer Society currently recommends that all men over the age of 50 be offered digital rectal exams and prostate specific antigen (PSA) blood tests for the presence of prostate cancer. For women, the American Cancer Society recommends annual PAP smears for women beginning no later than age 21 and mammograms every other year for women aged 40-50 and every year for women over 50. The National Heart Lung and Blood Institute has facilitated development of a set of criteria, including annual screening for blood LDL cholesterol levels (National Heart Lung and Blood Institute 2001). The American Dental Association recommends annual dental exams for caries and gum disease. We will study whether respondents in our survey undertook each of these recommended secondary (and primary, in the case of dental exams and cholesterol tests) health care screens. Despite the clinical evidence and pressure from primary care physicians, low rates of adherence suggest that many patients are not willing to expend effort currently to be screened to secure some potential health gains in the future (reduced future mortality associated with early treatment). The degree to which innate discounting of the future plays a role in this poor adherence is open because evidence suggests that willingness to seek screening for some cancers varies by patient characteristics and financial constraints for example, mammography for breast cancer has been studied by Tudiver and Fuller-Thomson (1999).

Consequently, we examine data generated from a national survey, where utilization of primary and secondary screening, willingness to delay payouts from a hypothetical sweepstakes, and respondent characteristics were collected. We use interval estimation models to estimate each respondents' discount rate and dichotomous choice likelihood models (probits) to estimate the probability of screening (separately for each type of screening) as a function, in part, of the latent discount rates. This work will simultaneously add to the literature that seeks to understand individual time preferences and also to the literature that models patient utilization of preventative services.

3. Theory

For the theoretical underpinnings of this research, we will expand on a simple two-period model of Picone, Sloan, and Taylor (2004). For our version of the model, we consider a two-period game with the following rules. In the first period the agent chooses whether to seek a disease screen. The test is positive with probability [rho](*) [member of][0, 1], which is also the probability that the person suffers from the disease in question (we assume no false positive results); if the test is positive then the patient is treated. One of the distinctions we make in this research is the difference between primary prevention (e.g., exercise, sodium intake control, weight management) and screening for the presence of a disease (e.g., cancer, hypercholesterolemia, cardiovascular disease), in the former case, existing theoretical models predict that increases in an individual's discounting of the future should (on average) decrease the demand for primary prevention (Ehrlich and Chuma 1990). As will be seen, the relationship between discounting and screening is not necessarily the same. People will often only seek screening in response to some symptom that the disease is present. For example, patients may seek a cardiac stress test only after suffering from some initial chest pain or shortness of breath. Thus, the probability that a person has a disease for which they will seek a screening will be a function of their current health, H, and the investments in primary prevention that they have made in the past--which is itself a function of the rate of discounting (in conformity with Grossman 1972; Becker and Murphy 1988; and Ehrlich and Chuma 1990). Thus, we posit this probability to be [rho](H, [beta]),where H represents current known health; [beta] [member of] [0, 1] is the future discount factor (an inverse function of the individual's discount rate); and [[rho].sub.H], [[rho].sub.[beta]] < 0.

Treatment in the first period has a probability of success of [alpha] [member of] [[delta], 1]. If the patient is not screened in the first period, then their disease state is revealed in the second stage, and if they have the disease they are treated, with a probability of success of ([alpha] - [delta]) [member of] [0, 1]. Patients pay for the screening test and any needed disease treatment out of pocket at a cost of c and P, respectively.

We assume that patients will seek to maximize the present value of expected utility. Utility is an increasing function of health state and income. Full health, H, is reduced by amount L when the patient has the disease in question. Income is either spent on some numeraire good, x, or on testing and treatment: U(H, x).

Finally, at the end of the second period the agent receives a payoff that is the present value of all future utility. This residual utility will depend upon the health state that obtains as a result of the two-period game and life expectancy. For simplicity, we will define two residual present value functions: one when the disease state is either not present or resolved through treatment

[PV.sup.0] = [[integral].sup.T.sub.t=3] U(H, x) x [beta](t)dt (3.1)

and one where the disease state is present and unresolved.

[PV.sup.L] = [[integral].sup.T.sub.t=3] U(H - L, x) x [beta](t)dt (3.2)

In this case it is clear that [PV.sup.o] - [PV.sub.L] > 0.

Consistent with expected utility maximization, we assume the agent will choose to purchase a disease screening of the expected utility from doing so

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.3)

is greater than the expected utility of not screening in period one and waiting until period two to resolve the uncertain disease state

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.4)

Thus, the decision rule for whether to purchase screening in period one is whether NB = [EU.sub.s] - [EU.sub.NS] [greater than or equal to] 0. For ease of exposition and seeing the sign of our derivatives of interest, we can rewrite this net benefit of screening function as follows:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (3.5)

where

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.6)

To see what the impact of increasing an individual's discount rate, r, would be, recall that if [beta] is the traditional discount factor, then [[beta].sub.r] < 0 (that is, increasing the discount rate causes the agent to reduce the weight assigned to future utility, which is equivalent to reducing [beta]). Thus,

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3.7)

The second and third terms of this partial derivative are negative; however, the first term is ambiguous in sign. Thus while Ehrlich and Chuma (1990) find that increasing the discount rate should (on average) increase the use of medical care (which corresponds to primary prevention care in this model), we find that the impact of increasing the discount rate on the use of disease screening is uncertain. While one might expect a negative relationship, if the productivity of preventative health care in staving off disease ([[rho].sub.[beta]]) is large and the utility loss from income outlays to secure current treatment is sufficiently outweighed by the expected benefit from current treatment, then the impact of higher rates of discounting may well be to increase the value of current screening for acute disease.

Thus, this theoretical model has three implications for how we will empirically model the marginal effects of individual discount rates on health decisions.

1. As can be seen in the previous discussion, the marginal effect of the benefit of screening (and so the decision to screen) will depend on the price of the screening technology itself, though the direction of the effect is uncertain. Empirically, this implies an interaction term between the opportunity cost of screening and the individual discount rate. While we do not have measures of screening prices, we do have measures of whether the respondent is insured with a traditional (fee for service) insurance policy, insured with an HMO, or uninsured (excluded category); consequently, we include interactions between the discount rate and insurance indicators in the second stage model discussed later.

2. The marginal effect of the discount rate on the benefit of screening will depend positively on the productivity of screening in leading to treatments that prevent, or at least quickly cure, the underlying disease. Thus, the marginal effect of discounting will be positive (less negative) as the effectiveness of the screening in health production increases. Because the effectiveness of these screens will change with age, we will include an interaction term between the imputed discount rate and age.

3. Finally, the marginal effect of the imputed discount on the screening benefit will depend on the underlying likelihood of the disease being screened for. Consequently, we will include interaction effects between the imputed discount rate and measures of the age gender--race adjusted likelihood of the respective diseases (e.g., the probability of breast cancer for mammography).

We will test the net effect of discounting on the rates of screening for breast cancer (mammography), cervical cancer (PAP smears), prostate cancer (prostate screening), dental caries, hypercholesterolemia (cholesterol screening), and hypertension (blood pressure exams). Given the interaction effects that we must include according to our theoretical model, estimating marginal effects are complicated. As a result, we will examine the parameters of the model for significance and then calculate empirical marginal effects by predicting the estimated probability of each screen separately for each observation as we change the imputed discount rate from 0.01 to 1.0.

4. Methods

Survey

We conducted a randomized telephone survey of 2000 adults (over 40 years of age) during the second half of 2002 and the first half of 2003. Random digit dialing was employed. The only exclusion restriction was age. In addition, we oversampled current and former smokers. After eliminating observations with incorrect survey administration, and observations from Alaska and Hawaii (due to outlier status with regard to costs of living and market interest rate options), we retained a sample of 1878 individuals. Table 1 presents the demographic information on our sample.

Contingent valuation (CV) is a widely used method to assess the valuation for goods not traded in the marketplace. While it has often been used to value environmental resources, it has also found a home in health economics in assigning dollar values to many things that are not traded in the market (such as life-years in the future) and services that are traded in the market, but for which patients do not naturally pay the full marginal cost out-of-pocket. The earliest utilized approach was to survey people, asking how much they would be willing to pay for a particular good. Often, however, the survey respondents have no direct experience with purchasing the service being evaluated. Consequently, answers may be noisy. Additionally, when the survey offered several examples of value, the responses may also suffer from framing, in that the value offered by the survey may influence the respondent's actual expressed valuation (see, for example, Diamond and Hausman 1994).

Many of the problems of this simple survey method can be avoided by using the dichotomous choice approach. In this approach, participants are asked whether they would pay a certain amount for the good in question. The amount asked is varied across participants. In this way, the question is less strongly "framed" for respondents--at least they are not asked to consider whether the offered amount corresponds to their maximum willingness to pay. Further, by asking whether they will pay $x, respondents can perceive no signal as to whether "Yes" or "No" is the "preferred" answer that the surveyor desires. Thus, the elicited response can be expected to better represent the choices of the survey participant (see Boardman et al. 1996, pp. 347 9). Typically, the actual dollar amount offered varies across a small number of values. Less commonly, the value is varied randomly for each respondent (a method that significantly raises the difficulty of administering the survey). However, because there is a potentially large increase in the precision of the estimates by varying offer amounts for each individual, that is the approach we take in this study. In addition, rather than asking about willingness to pay, we will ask about preferences for receiving a payout, where the magnitude of the payout varies inversely with the time delay in receiving it.

One disadvantage of a single-bound dichotomous choice method is that if someone answers "Yes" to the question "Would you be willing to accept $x in six years rather than $10,000 in one year?", then the implied discount rate can only be seen as an upper bound to their true underlying discount rate (or a lower bound, if they answer "No"). An alternative approach, which has recently been applied to health economics, takes the elicitation process one step further (Bradford et al. 2004). This method is known as double-bounded dichotomous choice contingent valuation (DBDC) (Hanemann 1985; Cameron and James 1987). When employing the DBDC method, a survey poses follow-up questions to the initial willingness to pay (WTP) query. If a person responds "Yes" to the willingness to accept question, then they are asked a follow-up question where the implied discount rate is lowered. If the person responds "No" to the first question, then they are asked the question again, this time with a higher implied discount rate. Thus, the DBDC approach generates more information because either the upper or lower bounds are defined more precisely or the true WTP is clearly bounded on both sides. This information gain implies that the DBDC approach may be significantly more efficient than the single-bound method (Hanemann, Loomis, and Kanninen 1991; Kanninen 1993).

The actual discounting questions were as follows:

I want you to imagine that you have just won a sweepstakes prize. Imagine that you have been offered two choices for how you will take your prize. Which of the following two choices would you select?

A. In $10,000 cash paid to you one year from now?

B. In $[x.sub.1] cash paid to you six years from today. (This is like having a savings account that pays an interest rate of [r.sub.1]% per year.)

The dollar amount $[x.sub.1] was randomized for each survey respondent, and the respondents were told the implied interest rate, [r.sub.1], which was calculated based upon the randomly assigned dollar amount and a five-year time frame (because the second prize, which is paid in six years, is to be compared to the first prize, which is paid in one year). The rationale behind the year-long delay in any reward is to avoid confounding the estimated discount rate if individuals discount the future differently for payouts that are imminent compared with payouts that are further in the future. (2)

If the underlying discount rate for the person lies below the offered rate, [r.sub.1], then this means the money will grow faster by delaying the prize than the person's rate of discounting the future--in which case the respondent will choose to delay payment. On the other hand, if the respondent's innate discount rate is above [r.sub.1], then he or she will discount the future more quickly than the prize will grow, and so the person would choose the $10,000 in one year. Consequently, if the respondent chose to take the $10,000 payment in one year, an identical question was asked with a new dollar amount, $[x.sub.2], that was higher (by a random factor) than the initial one, corresponding to a higher interest rate, [r.sub.2]. Contrarily, if the person selected the future payment, a new question with a randomly lower dollar amount, $[x.sub.3], and interest rate, [r.sub.3], was asked. Figure 1 presents this process schematically, noting the average offer rates at each node and the numbers (and percentage) of respondents who followed each of the four possible paths.

In addition to the usual set of socioeconomic characteristics, the survey also elicited information on respondents' health maintenance behaviors over the recent past. In particular, the survey asked respondents whether they had had any of the following health services within the past two years: mammography, PAP smear, prostate exam, dental visit or exam, blood pressure check, and cholesterol test (mammography and PAP smears were only asked of women, and prostate exams were only asked of men). To be consistent with the range of clinical guidelines, we measure health habits as dichotomous indicators for whether the respondent had any of the listed services within the past two years.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Econometric Model

Considering each health behavior separately, we assume that there exist two latent variables, which are defined as

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.1)

where [beta] and [theta] are vectors of unknown parameters, [alpha] is an unknown scalar, [[epsilon].sub.1i] and [[epsilon].sub.i,2] are vectors of (correlated) errors, and the subscript i references the individual. The latent individual discount rate, [R.sup.*], and the health screening behavior demand, [S.sup.*], depend upon a set of explanatory factors X and Z, respectively, where X contains elements that are not present in Z, which is necessary for identification.

It is possible that the very act of offering CV questions with explicit discount rates can frame the responses and further complicate the process of inferring [R.sup.*] (Frederick, Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue 2002). To confront this, we will model the framing process directly. First, assume that the underlying latent variable [R.sup.*] is stable, but that the answers to the CV questions may be affected by the values that are offered. In essence, the CV hypothetical questions are based upon a perceived discount rate, which is a function of the true underlying rate and the rates offered in the hypothetical situations. To operationalize this, assume that the first response is based upon the underlying latent rate [R.sup.*], but that the second response is based on a perceived discount rate, which is a linear combination of the true latent rate and the first round offer rate, [r.sub.1] as in:

[R.sup.1] = [lambda][R.sup.*] + (1 - [lambda])[r.sub.1], (4.2)

where [lambda] [member of] [0,1]. Once the framing has occurred, the respondent is then offered a second discount rate. This rate is lower ([r.sub.2]) if the person responded "Present" to the first CV question; the rate is higher ([r.sub.3]) if they responded "Future" to the first CV question.

Because the final answer is dependent on this hybrid latent rate [R.sup.1], the probability that the person has responded to the second question that they want the money in one year rather than the payoff $[x.sub.2], which is associated with an annual return of [r.sub.2], is equal to the probability that

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.3)

which, with the appropriate substitution of terms, can be expressed as:

[r.sub.2] < [X.sub.i][beta] + [[epsilon].sub.li] + [delta] x r < [infinity], (4.4)

where [DELTA]r [equivalent to] ([r.sub.1] - [r.sub.2]). This describes the interval under which the true discount (X[beta] + [epsilon]) must fall if the person prefers $10,000 in one year to $[x.sub.2] in six years.

Using similar arguments, the intervals for the four possible responses to the iterated CV time preference questions are as follows:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.5)

These responses can be summarized into the following regression relationship:

[r.sup.1] < [X.sub.i] [beta] + [delta] x [DELTA]r + dPF x [delta][r.sub.1] + dFP x [delta][r.sub.2] + [[epsilon].sub.1i] < [r.sup.u] (4.6)

where dPF = 1 if the respondent answers ("Present", "Future") to the CV questions and = 0 otherwise; dFP = 1 if the respondent answers ("Future", "Present") to the CV questions and = 0 otherwise; and the upper ([r.sup.u]) and lower ([r.sup.l]) bounds on the discount rate are defined by which response category described earlier the person falls into.

For the latent health screening demand, the observed responses are the typical dichotomous dependent variable:

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.7)

The full log-likelihood function for this two-equation model can be represented generally as

[ln] L = [N.summation over(i=1)] f([r.sup.l.sub.t], [r.sup.u.sub.i], [s.sub.i] | [X.sub.i] [Z.sub.i], [beta], [theta] , [alpha], [delta]) (4.8)

However, deriving the joint likelihood for the interval defined and dichotomous dependent variables is complex and so limits the attractiveness of a full information maximum likelihood approach. Rather, we will implement a limited information maximum likelihood (LIML) procedure on our triangular structure by first maximizing

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.9)

where i [member of] LC are those observations for which the implied rate is below [r.sup.l.sub.i] (and so are bounded above 0 by construction), i [member of] RC are those observations for which the implied rate is above [r.sup.u.sub.i] (and so are right censored), and i [member of] I are those observations for which the implied rate is between [r.sup.l.sub.i] and [r.sup.u.sub.i] (and so are interval bounded). After solving the first likelihood function, we then maximize

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.10)

where [??] and [??] are the estimated parameters from the first stage of the two-step ML (LIML) procedure. Because the joint distribution was not derived, the standard errors for the two-step ML estimates are generated using a bootstrap procedure. (3)

Finally, the structure of this latent discount rate model provides a natural set of instruments for identifying the imputed latent discount rate from the preventative service use models discussed earlier. As an instrument, we need variables that are related to the revealed discount rate but are unrelated to the latent demand for preventative services. Given the framing arguments derived earlier, we must include [DELTA]r, dPF x [r.sub.1], and dFP x [r.sub.2] in the grouped regression likelihood function for the latent discount rate model. Because all of the offered rates are randomly constructed for the survey questions only, they must be unrelated to the process that determines the past actual use of preventative services. Note that if all of our observations were within the i [member of] I set, then the [delta] x [DELTA]r + dPF x [Sr.sub.1] + dFP x [delta][r.sub.2] term would be subtracted out of each observation and thus not identify the model (because these terms would then not effectively appear in the imputed value, which would then be perfectly collinear with [Z.sub.i]). However, with the interval regression model, the expected value of the latent dependent variable (discount rate) is only equal to the linear projection through the right-hand side variables when the latent rate is bounded on both sides. For the observations where [??] is outside the interval [[r.sub.1], [r.sub.2]], the expected value of the latent rate is a nonlinear function of the bounds and the right-hand side variables. Let [??] [equivalent to] [X.sub.i][??] + [??] x [DELTA]r + dPF x [??][r.sub.1] + dFP x [??][r.sub.2] be the predicted dependent variable from our first stage, then the imputed discount rate is

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4.11)

Thus, these three variables serve as natural identifying variables, and they pass the usual tests for weak instruments. (4)

Explanatory Variables

We include explanatory variables that fall into several classes. These are as follows:

* Characteristics of the individual that are expected to influence general preferences: respondent age, gender, race (indicators for whether the respondent is African American, and other race if respondent is not Caucasian or African-American; Caucasian is the excluded category), marital status, and educational attainment (indicators for whether the respondent graduated from high school or attended some college or graduated; did not graduate from high school is the excluded category).

* Characteristics that reveal underlying preferences with respect to risk: self-reported health status (an indicator variable for whether the respondent reported she was in good or excellent health); self-reported cancer risk (an indicator variable for whether the respondent reported that she believed herself to have a high or very high risk of cancer); and smoking status (indicator variables for whether the respondent has smoked in past, but not in present, and whether the respondent is a current smoke--never smoked is the excluded category).

* Characteristics that affect the opportunity costs of medical care: insurance status (indicator variables for whether the respondent is covered by Medicare, Medicaid, private, nongroup insurance, HMO coverage, or some other form of insurance; noninsured is the excluded category); employment status (indicator variables for whether the respondent is currently employed or currently retired; nonemployed is the excluded category); and income (indicator variables for six discrete income level indicators, plus an indicator variable for whether the respondent refused to answer the income question; income over $100,000 per year is the excluded category).

* Characteristics required because of the theoretical model: age x imputed discount rate ([R.sup.*.sub.i]) interaction; individual probability of breast cancer, cervical cancer, prostate cancer, and oral cancer (imputed by age, race, and gender using DevCan 6.3.1 from the National Cancer Society SEER database), and cardiovascular disease (imputed by age, race, and gender using the National Heart Lung and Blood 10-Year Risk Assessment Tool [NHLBI 2001] based on data from the Adult Treatment Panel III study); and imputed discount rate ([R.sup.*.sub.i] x disease risk interaction terms.

The variables listed are expected to affect both the demand for preventative medical care and the returns to health investments. Additionally, we include variables that are expected to affect individuals generally. These include a year indicator for 2003 and a set of census region indicators (mid-Atlantic is the excluded region).

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics of the variables discussed.

5. Results

Results from the First Step ML Discount Rate

The interval regression estimates of the discount rate model appear in Table 2. We generate predictions of the latent discount rate for each individual in the data as outlined in section 4. Figure 2 graphs the histogram of the imputed individual discount rates. The model yields an average predicted discount rate of 25.1% per year. While 25% per year is high relative to market rates of interest paid to savings, CD, or high quality corporate paper, it is in fact not high relative to the rates charged for much consumer debt on credit cards. Further, the value of 25.1% falls squarely in the midrange of previous estimates of individual discount rates (Frederick, Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue 2002).

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

As Table 2 shows, men had statistically significantly lower average discount rates than women--with mean predicted annual discount rates that were about 1.4% lower than those of women in the sample. (While perhaps surprising to some readers, this is commonly found in the literature.) Respondents in good health had imputed rates significantly lower than those who did not report good health (by 3.6% per year). In general, individuals with higher socioeconomic standing more education and higher income had statistically and economically lower discount rates than individuals with lower socioeconomic standing.

One characteristic of the imputed discount rate that is apparent in Figure 3 is the steady increase in imputed rates with age. Annual discount rates for the oldest age group (70 years old) are more than 10% higher than the rates for the youngest age group (40 year olds). This is borne out in the parameter estimates, where age is uniformly a positive and significant predictor of the latent rate. That older individuals would be less patient is consistent with findings in the literature (Frederick, Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue 2002) and is often explained as a risk effect: Older individuals may perceive the likelihood that they will be alive in six years to collect the award to be lower, and therefore exhibit less patience with respect to the timing of the reward.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

The steepness of the age or discount rate curve has another implication for our model. The discount rates in excess of 50% per year for the oldest respondents imply that individuals in these age groups will substantially devalue benefits occurring more than five years in the future. This is reinforced because the clinical benefits of screening for prostate, cervical, or breast cancer fall significantly with advanced age. For this reason, the National Comprehensive Cancer Network guidelines call for prostate cancer screening only in men with at least 10 years of remaining life expectancy. Similarly, the NCCN recommends discontinuing cervical cancer screening (PAP smears) at age 70 for women who have had no abnormal screens in the previous 3 years and suggests that all women over age 70 discuss with their physician whether they would benefit from screening (NCCN 2004). While there is no explicit age limit on breast cancer screening with mammography, the benefits are clearly lower as life expectancy declines. Consequently, given the clinically questionable value of many preventative screening programs in the oldest populations, we will only estimate our models on the aged 40 to 70 subsample.

Results from Second Step ML Preventative Screening Use

As a baseline for comparison, we estimated our second stage models assuming separability between the discount and screening decisions, using a standard probit model for each screening choice. These coefficients for the key variables (discount rate, disease probabilities, and interactions) are presented in Table 3 (and the coefficients for the remaining variables are presented in Appendix Table A3). Using these naive estimates, we find that the coefficients on the imputed discount rates have the expected negative and significant sign for two of the screening tools (PAP smears and cholesterols checks), while the effect of higher discount rates are positive for prostate exams.

However, the potential for endogeneity of the discount measure in the screening decision cannot be ruled out. Consequently, our full model is presented in Table 4, where screening is estimated using a two-stage least squares (using the method of two-stage residual inclusion [Terza, Basu, and Rathouz 2008]) model to account for the potential correlation in the error terms between the first and second stages. Table 4 presents the coefficients (not marginal effects) and t-statistics for the key variables of the screening models, where each column represents separate implementations of our discount rate-screening LIML model. (Again, the coefficients for the remaining variables are presented in Appendix Table A4.) While one may expect correlations between the errors between the different screening use variables, such that a seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) framework would be more efficient, constructing a full-information maximum likelihood version of our model is beyond the scope of this work; consequently, our bootstrapped standard errors will be somewhat larger than they would be for a FIML version, and our t-tests should be seen as conservative.

The primary results of interest are the parameters on estimated discount rates and the discount x age and discount x disease probability interactions. First, for PAP smears and cholesterol tests we find that the main effect of discounting is negative and significant; however, for prostate exams the main effect is positive and significant. The interaction terms between discount and the risk of cervical cancer (for PAP smear use) and discount and the risk of prostate cancer (for prostate exams) are significant. (Note, the magnitude of the parameters attached to the probability of cervical cancer are not anomalous because even for women in the age range we study, this cancer is quite rare.) Finally, approximately half of the interactions between the induced discount rate and insurance indicators are significant. Thus, individual discount rates would appear to have a significant effect on the likelihood of screening use.

What is the actual marginal effect of discounting on screening? Unfortunately, given the multiple interaction terms required by the theoretical model, calculating the marginal effect becomes complex. As Ai and Norton (2003) indicate, when interaction terms are present, the actual marginal effect cannot be calculated using standard methods (for example, implementing the 'mfx' command in Stata) because both the sign and net significance may differ from the parameter of the main effects. Therefore, to illustrate the magnitude of the marginal effects of imputed discount rates on the probability of screening use, we predict the likelihood of adopting each screening technology for each observation in the data, setting the imputed discount rate at 1%, while keeping the remaining characteristics of each person unaltered, and then calculating the average likelihood of screening use across all observations. This process was repeated by replacing the actual imputed discount with 2%, 3%, and so forth. In this way, we can map out the density function of screening use as the imputed discount rate moves through the 1% to 100% per year range, simultaneously accounting for all interaction terms.

The relationship between the discount rate and screening probabilities are presented in Figure 4. From this figure, two results are striking. First, there is the obvious difference in response to higher individual discount rates between men seeking prostate exams and all other screening exams studied. Whereas higher discount rates are associated with lower probabilities of all other screening tests, the association between discount rates and the probability of prostate screening is positive. This positive association is stronger for men with higher probabilities of prostate cancer. Recall that the theoretical model does permit a positive relationship between individual discounting and disease screening when the interaction between disease likelihood and testing efficacy are taken into account. The greater the efficacy of treatment (in this case, the reduction in mortality from catching aggressive prostate cancer early), the greater the chance that the marginal effect of discounting on screening is positive. It is also the case that the chances of prostate cancer for men in the sample were among the highest of any--and also had the broadest range, with the largest upper bound. The second striking result is the magnitude of the discounting response. Mammography had the lowest range of implied behavior but still ranged from a probability of around 80% with the lowest discount rate (1% per year) to a low of around 35% probability of screening when the discount rate is 100% per year. The probability of prostate exams essentially spanned the entire [0, 1] range. (Again, recall that these imputed probabilities take all interaction effects into account.) Thus, it seems that the economic magnitude of the complete (fully interactive) impact of individual time discounting on the probability of disease screening is quite substantial.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

As a practical matter, these results suggest that providers who wish to persuade high discounting individuals to increase their adherence to screening recommendations will need some other message than simply emphasizing the future health benefits. However, it is not at all clear that increasing the rate of screening among these individuals is efficient. Because these people care relatively little about future payoffs, they might be made worse off if society could somehow coerce them to increase their adherence to screening guidelines. More attention to theoretical issues surrounding the consistency of choices across time, the stability of time preferences through the life cycle, or the importance of such forces as regret in intertemporal decision making is needed before the welfare consequences of artificially increasing screening adherence in a high discount population could be stated unambiguously.

6. Conclusions

Preventative health care is often cited as one solution to the aging population and the growing share of health care spending in U.S. gross domestic product. To the extent that individuals can be persuaded to consume efficacious preventative services today, then their need for acute services in the future should be reduced. However, one significant barrier to patient adoption of preventative regimens is that they generally require the person to forego consumption and activities (or lack thereof) that they enjoy today for the promise of some future payoff. The degree to which a person prefers the present relative to the future should therefore be an important determinant in their decisions with respect to the consumption of preventative medicine. Despite this relatively obvious observation, there have been few attempts in the economic literature to directly assess how individuals' time preferences affect the demand for preventative service.

This article addresses this gap in the literature by analyzing data collected in a nationwide survey of adults over the age of 40. In this survey, we used a contingent valuation method to elicit responses to questions designed to reveal the individual's rate of time preference and the utilization of five common disease screens (prostate exam, PAP smear, mammogram, dental exams, and cholesterol testing). The results suggest that the average respondent in the survey has an underlying discount rate of around 25% per year. The likelihood of screening within the past two years was modeled as a function of the discount rate (directly and interacted with respondent age) and other patient characteristics. Completely interacted results indicate that higher rates of discount are associated with lower use of all studied screening technologies except prostate exams, where the effect was positive.

This research has significant implications for clinical care and for policy making. First, if the estimated discount rates are accurate (and they are consistent with past literature), one might expect relatively few patients will voluntarily undertake preventative activities that entail positive costs if the benefits accrue many years in the future. Given the average estimated discount rates, even very large benefits to the individual will be discounted heavily in present value terms. Consequently, clinical attempts to alter patients' behavior by stressing the health benefits accruing 10, 15, or 20 years in the future may not be the most effective messages.

These results suggest that advocacy and education that emphasizes the future benefits of prevention may not be universally effective tools at reducing burdens on the health care sector from preventable diseases or disease states. Further, from a public welfare perspective, individuals seem to reveal that they discount the future much more heavily than many market interest rates. While this is a consistent finding in the literature, why such a state of affairs would persist over time deserves attention. High rates of discount are consistent with preferences toward current consumption of health capital and expectations that any future acute episodes will be treated when they arise, rather than prevented.

Of course, much research remains to be conducted. It remains to be seen if the demand for other types of secondary preventative services is inversely related to individuals' discount rates--or whether other primary prevention or acute care demand is also related to discounting. Much research into individual discounting of the future has focused on potential time inconsistencies. These issues must also be resolved before the welfare implications of any negative discount--screening demand relationship are understood. Finally, while this research did indicate a significant relationship between an individual's rate of discount for financial instruments (sweepstakes prizes) and some components of health care demand, if people discount health care itself at a different rate than they discount money, these results may be misleading. Nonetheless, the current results do suggest that more attention should be paid to the consistency between public policies toward encouraging disease screening and individual preferences that might work to undermine such evidence-based clinical guidelines. Aligning public and private preferences in this area should be a matter of high policy significance.

Appendix
Table A3. Probability of Screening Exams within Past Two Years
Separate Probit Estimator

                    Mammography               PAP Smear

Constant        -0.7472     [-0.427]     6.8896 ***    [4.293]
male
age             -0.0036     [-0.068]    -0.0561 ***   [-2.584]
goodhealth      -0.1760     [-0.962]    -0.0660       [-0.331]
currsmoke       -0.1586     [-1.085]    -0.0227       [-0.121]
formersmoke      0.0111      [0.089]    -0.0063       [-0.040]
selfcnrisk       0.2559      [1.245]    -0.0127       [-0.056]
black            0.0137      [0.083]     1.5081 **     [2.496]
otherrace       -0.0357     [-0.142]     1.6018 *      [1.948]
married          0.2010 *    [1.714]     0.2979 **     [2.040]
hschool         -0.2806     [-1.307]    -0.1289       [-0.519]
somecoll        -0.0181     [-0.081]    -0.1336       [-0.522]
insure           0.3135      [0.618]     0.1440        [0.258]
hmo              0.1687      [0.573]     0.1908        [0.482]
employed         0.0035      [0.025]     0.0895        [0.577]
incl            -0.4765     [-1.413]    -0.1726       [-0.438]
inc2            -0.3246     [-0.954]    -0.4887       [-1.260]
inc3            -0.5222     [-1.619]    -0.2903       [-0.749]
inc4            -0.0939     [-0.314]     0.1862        [0.511]
inc5            -0.2765     [-0.914]    -0.3381       [-0.929]
inc6            -0.1262     [-0.384]     0.1550        [0.363]
unknowninc      -0.2966     [-1.090]     0.0956        [0.286]
newengl         -0.3056     [-1.163]     0.1724        [0.418]
southeast        0.0271      [0.193]     0.0184        [0.104]
midwest         -0.0076     [-0.051]    -0.1347       [-0.735]
plains           0.0393      [0.143]     0.1360        [0.335]
west            -0.0019     [-0.011]     0.1108        [0.489]

Observations   909                      909

                   Prostate Exam              Dental Visit

Constant       -8.7201 ***   [-4.640]     1.2990        [1.525]
male                                     -0.1224       [-0.894]
age             0.2126 ***    [5.273]    -0.0173       [-1.015]
goodhealth     -0.4264 **    [-2.232]     0.5286 ***    [4.520]
currsmoke      -0.3864 ***   [-2.855]    -0.0786       [-0.780]
formersmoke     0.0770        [0.519]    -0.1799 *     [-1.816]
selfcnrisk     -0.0399       [-0.209]    -0.4149 ***   [-3.258]
black           0.2361        [1.499]    -0.1392       [-1.298]
otherrace      -0.4214 **    [-2.300]    -0.4575 ***   [-3.425]
married         0.0478        [0.391]     0.1708 **     [1.997]
hschool         0.0134        [0.067]     0.1265        [0.933]
somecoll        0.4564 **     [2.264]     0.4658 ***    [3.314]
insure         -0.5133       [-1.140]     0.0987        [0.315]
hmo            -1.4161 ***   [-4.698]     0.0650        [0.298]
employed       -0.3941 **    [-2.121]     0.0596        [0.557]
incl           -0.1730       [-0.466]    -0.2954       [-1.173]
inc2            0.2701        [0.661]    -0.1802       [-0.704]
inc3           -0.2020       [-0.600]    -0.2963       [-1.245]
inc4           -0.2337       [-0.788]     0.2107        [0.934]
inc5           -0.2921       [-0.992]     0.1777        [0.780]
inc6           -0.4911       [-1.614]     0.4164        [1.622]
unknowninc     -0.4574 *     [-1.667]     0.1027        [0.495]
newengl        -0.2088       [-0.796]    -0.0753       [-0.361]
southeast      -0.0549       [-0.373]    -0.1257       [-1.153]
midwest        -0.0690       [-0.410]    -0.2089 *     [-1.756]
plains          0.1946        [0.716]    -0.1052       [-0.508]
west           -0.1626       [-0.916]    -0.2134       [-1.632]

Observations   726                       1635

                Blood Pressure Check        Cholesterol Check

Constant        3.4366 *      [1.959]     2.0559 ***    [3.041]
male           -0.6471 ***   [-3.129]
age            -0.0226       [-0.637]    -0.0035       [-0.276]
goodhealth     -0.6230 **    [-2.182]    -0.7137 ***   [-5.051]
currsmoke      -0.5701 ***   [-3.031]    -0.2955 ***   [-3.364]
formersmoke    -0.0785       [-0.347]    -0.1471 *     [-1.678]
selfcnrisk      0.3941        [1.445]     0.0951        [0.717]
black           0.4759 *      [1.844]    -0.2748 ***   [-2.993]
otherrace       0.0478        [0.228]    -0.2990 **    [-2.522]
married        -0.0952       [-0.567]     0.0771        [0.978]
hschool         0.3700        [1.559]    -0.1710       [-1.211]
somecoll        0.4248 *      [1.750]     0.1731        [1.197]
insure         -0.1987       [-0.317]     0.4371        [1.395]
hmo             0.6597        [1.393]    -0.6315 ***   [-3.220]
employed        0.1717        [0.873]    -0.0623       [-0.609]
incl           -0.5307       [-1.193]    -0.2636       [-1.121]
inc2            0.1963        [0.381]     0.2891        [1.152]
inc3            0.3242        [0.710]    -0.0646       [-0.294]
inc4            0.3382        [0.817]     0.0520        [0.264]
inc5           -0.1424       [-0.368]     0.1151        [0.583]
inc6           -0.0724       [-0.176]    -0.0609       [-0.298]
unknowninc      0.1095        [0.295]    -0.0837       [-0.468]
newengl         0.2808        [0.696]    -0.0611       [-0.350]
southeast       0.0573        [0.277]    -0.1224       [-1.257]
midwest        -0.1325       [-0.595]    -0.1061       [-1.008]
plains          0.0060        [0.016]    -0.1266       [-0.693]
west           -0.3703 *     [-1.691]    -0.4421 ***   [-3.942]

Observations   1635                      1635

Value of t-statistics in brackets.

* Significant at 10%.

** Significant at 5%.

*** Significant at 1%.

Parameters on the key discount variables, interactions and disease
probabilities are presented in Table 3.

Table A4. Probability of Screening Exams within Past
Two Years--2SLS Estimator

                  Mammography         PAP Smear

Constant         0.3965 [0.14]     8.8738 [3.35] ***
male
age              0 [0.00]         -0.0547 [2.39] *
goodhealth      -0.3199 [1.24]    -0.3114 [1.00]
currsmoke       -0.1136 [0.71]     0.0333 [0.14]
formersmoke      0.0528 [0.39]     0.0556 [0.36]
selfcnrisk       0.3714 [1.47]     0.1914 [0.58]
black            0.0878 [0.48]     1.5844 [2.63] **
otherrace        0.0928 [0.31]     1.7433 [2.01] *
married          0.1637 [1.17]     0.2312 [1.22]
hschool         -0.4847 [1.64]    -0.5059 [1.40]
somecoll        -0.2372 [0.73]    -0.5187 [1.41]
insure           0.4931 [0.871     0.4472 [0.67]
hmo              0.0556 [0.19]     0.0113 [0.02]
employed        -0.0519 [0.31]     0.0154 [0.08]
inc1            -0.4716 [1.01]    -0.1443 [0.13]
inc2            -0.2056 [0.48]    -0.2563 [0.22]
inc3            -0.5111 [1.32]    -0.2455 [0.23]
inc4            -0.2178 [0.471    -0.0148 [0.01]
inc5            -0.4095 [0.85]    -0.538 [0.46]
inch            -0.2057 [0.43]     0.0393 [0.04]
unknowninc      -0.5069 [1.051    -0.2276 [0.21]
newengl         -0.0716 [0.19]     0.5341 [1.17]
southeast        0.0118 [0.08]     0.0087 [0.05]
midwest         -0.0103 [0.07]    -0.1282 [0.661
plains           0.1917 [0.54]     0.3681 [0.92]
West             0.0081 [0.03]     0.1465 [0.55]
Observations   909               909

                  Prostate Exam          Dental visit

Constant       -10.6613 [4.06] ***      3.8097 [3.45] **
male                                   -0.1448 [0.98]
age              0.2122 [4.42] **      -0.0189 [1.13]
goodhealth      -0.2097 [0.92]          0.2357 [1.71]
currsmoke       -0.3766 [2.59] **      -0.06 [0.59]
formersmoke      0.0486 [0.34]         -0.1227 [1.19]
selfcnrisk      -0.2678 [0.99]         -0.1435 [0.881
black            0.1533 [0.83]         -0.0365 [0.34]
otherrace       -0.5979 [2.62] **      -0.261 [1.68]
married          0.0998 [0.68]          0.1037 [0.94]
hschool          0.3061 [1.03] *       -0.2534 [1.36]
somecoll         0.7826 [2.42]          0.0689 [0.41]
insure          -0.8282 [1.17]          0.4453 [1.05]
hmo             -1.3292 [3.70] **      -0.0932 [0.47]
employed        -0.2722 [1.53]         -0.0408 [0.31]
inc1            -0.1496 [0.39]         -0.2888 [1.02]
inc2             0.122 [0.331]          0.0574 [0.16]
inc3            -0.1885 [0.56]         -0.2785 [0.921
inc4            -0.0051 [0.02]         -0.0424 [0.20]
inc5            -0.0258 [0.08]         -0.108 [0.41]
inch            -0.3395 [1.06]          0.258 [0.91]
unknowninc      -0.125 [0.36]          -0.2958 [1.13]
newengl         -0.5341 [1.88]          0.3419 [1.35]
southeast       -0.0334 [0.24]         -0.1432 [1.001
midwest         -0.081 [0.52]          -0.2026 [1.54]
plains          -0.0713 [0.22]          0.1915 [0.69]
West            -0.1972 [1.14]         -0.1814 [1.49]
Observations   726                   1635

                 Blood Pressure       Cholestereol
                     Check               Check

Constant          5.995 [2.49] **      1.7313 [1.90] *
male             -0.6859 [3.69] **    -0.0431 [0.42]
age              -0.029 [1.41]        -0.0042 [0.31]
goodhealth       -0.8443 [2.66] **    -0.6716 [3.93] **
currsmoke        -0.5731 [2.77] **    -0.2893 [3.22] **
formersmoke      -0.0243 [0.10]       -0.156 [1.89]
selfcnrisk        0.6594 [2.22] *      0.0469 [0.29]
black             0.5683 [1.85]       -0.2943 [2.67] **
otherrace         0.1977 [0.79]       -0.3301 [2.93] **
married          -0.1603 [0.901        0.0881 [0.79]
hschoo1          -0.0192 [0.05]       -0.1132 [0.63]
somecoll          0.001 [0.00]         0.2365 [1.26]
insure            0.1371 [0.22]        0.3743 [0.981
hmo               0.5595 [1.33]       -0.6173 [3.20] **
employed          0.0605 [0.28]       -0.0391 [0.31]
inc1             -0.4825 [0.25]       -0.2673 [1.02]
inc2              0.4013 [0.20]        0.2436 [0.82]
inc3              0.3127 [0.16]       -0.0678 [0.29]
inc4              0.0413 [0.02]        0.0927 [0.43]
inc5             -0.4576 [0.24]        0.1638 [0.73]
inch             -0.2215 [0.12]       -0.0315 [0.14]
unknowninc       -0.2441 [0.13]       -0.021 [0.10]
newengl           0.6334 [1.59]       -0.1278 [0.58]
southeast         0.0648 [0.271       -0.1189 [1.28]
midwest          -0.1019 [0.50]       -0.1084 [0.94]
plains            0.3188 [0.78]       -0.1761 [0.77]
West             -0.3327 [1.53]       -0.4457 [3.24] **
Observations   1635                 1635

z statistics in brackets.

Parameters on the key discount variables, interactions,
and disease probabilities are presented in Table 4.

* p significant at 5%.

** p significant at 1%.


References

Ades, Philip, Thomas E. Kottke, Nancy Houston Miller, John C. McGrath, N. Burgess Record, and Sandra S. Record. 2002. Task Force #3: Getting results: Who, where, how? Journal of the American College of Cardiology 40(4):615-30.

Ai, C., and E. Norton. 2003. Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economic Letters 80(1):123-9.

Becker, G., and K. Murphy. 1988. A theory of rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy 96(4):675-700.

Berger, M., and J. Leigh. 1989. Schooling, self-selection, and health. Journal of Human Resources 24(3):433-55.

Boardman, A, D. Greenberg, A. Vining, and D. Weimer. 1996. Cost-benefit analysis: Concepts and practices. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.

Bradford, W. David, Andrew N. Kleit, Marie A. Krausel-Wood, and Richard N. Re. 2004. Double-bounded dichotomous choice method to assess willingness to pay for telemedicine. Journal of Telemedicine and Telecare 10(6):325-30.

Cameron, T., and M. James. 1987. Efficient estimation methods for use with "closed ended" contingent valuation survey data. Review of Economics and Statistics 69:269-76.

Coller, M., and M. Williams. 1999. Eliciting individual discount rates. Experimental Economics 2(1):107-27.

Diamond, Peter, and Jerry Hausman. 1994. Contingent valuation: Is some number better than no number? Journal of Economic-Perspectives 8(4):45-64.

Ehrlich, I., and H. Chuma. 1990. A model of the demand for longevity and the value of life extension. Journal of Political Economy 98(4):761-82.

Farrell, P., and V. Fuchs. 1982. Schooling and health: The cigarette connection. Journal of Health Economics 1(3):217-30.

Frederick, Shane, George Loewenstein, and Ted O'Donoghue. 2002. Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature XL:351-401.

Giorgianni, S., J. Grana, and J. Keith. 2003. Heart disease: An all-out attack. Pfizer Journal 7(4):1-49.

Greene, William H. 2002. Econometric analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Grossman, M. 1972. On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy 80(2):223-55.

Grossman, M. 2000. The human capital model. In Handbook of health economies, edited by A. Culyer and J. Newhouse. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science B.V.

Grossman, M., and R. Kaestner. 1997. Effects of education on health. In The social benefits of education, edited by J. Behrman and N. Stacey. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, pp. 69-123.

Hanemann, M. 1985. Some issues in continuous-and discrete response contingent valuation studies. Northeast Journal of Agricultural Economics 14(1):5-13.

Hanemann, M., J. Loomis, and B. Kanninen. 1991. Statistical efficiency of double-bounded dichotomous choice contingent valuation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(4):1255-63.

Harrison, G., M. Lau, and M. Williams. 2002. Estimating individual discount rates in Denmark. American Economic Review 92(5): 1606-17.

Kanninen, B. 1993. Optimal experimental design for double-bounded dichotomous choice contingent valuation. Land Economics 69(2): 138-46.

National Comprehensive Cancer Network (NCCN). 2004. Practice guidelines in oncology screening. Fort Washington, PA: National Comprehensive Cancer Network.

National Heart Lung and Blood Institute (NHLBI). 2001. Third report of the national cholesterol education program expert panel on detection, evaluation, and treatment of high blood cholesterol in adults (adult treatment panel iii). Washington, D.C.: National Institute of Health, National Heart Lung and Blood Institute.

Ockene, Ira S., Laura L. Hayman, Richard C. Pasternak, Eleanor Schron, and Jacqueline Dunbar-Jacob. 2002. Task Force #4: Adherence issues and behavior changes: Achieving a long-term solution. Journal of the American College of Cardiology 40(4):365-83.

Picone, Gabriel, Frank Sloan, and D. Taylor. 2004. Effects of risk and time preference and expected longevity on demand for medical tests. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 28(1):39-53.

Terza, Joseph V., Anirban Basu, and Paul J. Rathouz. 2008. Two-stage residual inclusion estimation: Addressing endogeneity in health econometric modeling. Journal of Health Economics 27(3):531-43.

Tudiver, F., and E. Fuller-Thompson. 1999. Who has screening mammography: Results from the 1994-1995 national population health survey. Canadian Family Physician 45:1901-7.

Van Doorslaer, E. 1987. Health, knowledge, and the demand for medical care: An econometric analysis. Maastricht, The Netherlands: van Gorcum and Comp.

Wagstaff, A. 1986. The demand for health: Some new empirical evidence. Journal of Health Economics 5(2):195-233.

Wagstaff, A. 1993. The demand for health: An empirical reformulation of the Grossman model. Health Economics 2(2):189-98.

Warner, J., and S. Pleeter. 2001. The personal discount rate: Evidence from military downsizing programs. American Economic Review 91(1):33 53.

Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2002. Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Zweifei, P., and F. Breyer. 1997. Health economics. New York: Oxford University Press.

W. David Bradford, James Zoller, [dagger] and Gerard A. Silvestri [double dagger]

* Department of Public Administration and Policy, University of Georgia, 201C Baldwin Hall, University of Georgia, Athens, GA 30602, USA; E-mail [email protected]; corresponding author.

[dagger] Department of Health Professions, Medical University of South Carolina, P.O. Box 250961, Charleston, SC 29425, USA; E-mail [email protected].

[double dagger] Department of Medicine, Medical University of South Carolina, MSC 630, 812 CSB, 96 Jonathan Lucas Street, Charleston, SC 29425, USA; E-mail [email protected].

This research was supported by a grant from the U.S. Department of Defense. The authors would like to thank David Bishai, Richard Lindrooth, and Peter Thompson, participants at the 3rd Annual Southeaster Health Economic Study Group meeting held in Miami, Florida, in October 2006, and participants at the Center for Health Economic and Policy Studies seminar series at the Medical University of South Carolina for comments on an earlier version of this research. Michael Kunz and Olena Verbenko provided able research assistance.

Received February 2008; accepted March 2009.

(1) For a summary of this literature, see Frederick, Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue (2002).

(2) There is a growing literature that suggests that people may in fact discount the distant future less heavily than they discount the proximate future. Most commonly this has been discussed in terms of hyperbolic discounting. For a summary of the measurement and implications of nonconstant discounting, including hyperbolic discounting, see Frederick, Loewenstein, and O'Donoghue (2002).

(3) More complete discussions of the two-step ML method (and the entire class of M-estimators) can be found in Wooldridge (2002) and Greene (2002). Note that the LIML model is not subject to the "forbidden regression" issue--where predicted values from a first stage are inappropriately inserted into a nonlinear second stage discussed in Wooldridge (2002, p. 236) for 2SLS applied to nonlinear models.

(4) The Wald chi-square statistic on a first stage regression including only the three candidate instruments is 1716 (the nonlinear analogue to a partial F statistic), and the individual t statistics on each of the instruments are significant at better than the 1% level.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics

                                      Number of               Standard
Variable                             Observations    Mean     Deviation

Imputed discount rate                    1635        0.251     0.105
Mammogram within past two years          1635        0.423     0.494
PAP smear within past two years          1635        0.498     0.500
Prostate within past two years           1635        0.188     0.391
Dental visit within past two years       1635        0.791     0.406
Blood pressure exam within the
  past two years                         1635        0.966     0.182
Cholesterol test within past two
  years                                  1635        0.684     0.465
Pr[Breast cancer I age, race]            909         0.014     0.006
Pr[Cervical cancer age, race]            909         0.0006    0.0002
Pr[Prostate cancer age, race]            726         0.012     0.015
Pr[Oral cancer I age, race,
  gender]                                1635        0.0008    0.0007
Pr[Cardiovascular disease I age,
  gender]                                1635        0.014     0.019
Gender (male = 1)                        1635        0.444     0.497
Age                                      1635       51.832     9.013
Respondent in good health                1635        0.888     0.315
Respondent a current smoker              1635        0.303     0.460
Respondent a former smoker               1635        0.245     0.430
High perceived cancer risk               1635        0.095     0.294
Race (African American = 1)              1635        0.172     0.377
Race (other race = 1)                    1635        0.096     0.295
Respondent married                       1635        0.663     0.473
Respondent graduated high school         1635        0.374     0.484
Respondent has some college              1635        0.547     0.498
Respondent has fee for service
  insurance                              1635        0.168     0.374
Respondent has HMO insurance             1635        0.554     0.497
Respondent is employed                   1635        0.735     0.442
Income: under $20,000                    1635        0.075     0.263
Income: $20,000-$30,000                  1635        0.048     0.213
Income: $30,000-$40,000                  1635        0.067     0.250
Income: $40,000-$60,000                  1635        0.127     0.333
Income: $60,000-$80,000                  1635        0.121     0.326
Income: $80,000-$100,000                 1635        0.082     0.274
Income: unknown                          1635        0.438     0.496
New England region                       1635        0.045     0.207
Southeast region                         1635        0.321     0.467
Midwest region                           1635        0.229     0.420
Plains region                            1635        0.042     0.200
West region                              1635        0.152     0.359
Rate1--Rate2                             1635       -0.066     0.144
dPF x Rate1                              1635        0.027     0.077
dFP x Rate2                              1635        0.023     0.092

                                     Minimum   Maximum
Variable                              Value     Value

Imputed discount rate                 0.019     0.540
Mammogram within past two years       0         1
PAP smear within past two years       0         1
Prostate within past two years        0         1
Dental visit within past two years    0         1
Blood pressure exam within the
  past two years                      0         1
Cholesterol test within past two
  years                               0         1
Pr[Breast cancer I age, race]         0.005     0.256
Pr[Cervical cancer age, race]         0.0005    0.001
Pr[Prostate cancer age, race]         0.0003    0.620
Pr[Oral cancer I age, race,
  gender]                             0.0001    0.277
Pr[Cardiovascular disease I age,
  gender]                             0.005     0.080
Gender (male = 1)                     0         1
Age                                  40        70
Respondent in good health             0         1
Respondent a current smoker           0         1
Respondent a former smoker            0         1
High perceived cancer risk            0         1
Race (African American = 1)           0         1
Race (other race = 1)                 0         1
Respondent married                    0         1
Respondent graduated high school      0         1
Respondent has some college           0         1
Respondent has fee for service
  insurance                           0         1
Respondent has HMO insurance          0         1
Respondent is employed                0         1
Income: under $20,000                 0         1
Income: $20,000-$30,000               0         1
Income: $30,000-$40,000               0         1
Income: $40,000-$60,000               0         1
Income: $60,000-$80,000               0         1
Income: $80,000-$100,000              0         1
Income: unknown                       0         1
New England region                    0         1
Southeast region                      0         1
Midwest region                        0         1
Plains region                         0         1
West region                           0         1
Rate1--Rate2                         -0.421     0.313
dPF x Rate1                           0         0.348
dFP x Rate2                           0         0.496

Table 2. Individual Discount Rate Estimators-Interval Estimator

Variables                                Coefficients

Age                                    0.0018 *** [0.0004]
Gender (male = 1)                     -0.0145 ** [0.01]
Respondent in good health             -0.0401 *** [0.01]
Respondent a current smoker            0.0077 [0.01]
Respondent a former smoker             0.0028 [0.01]
High perceived cancer risk            -0.0031 [0.01]
Race (African American = 1)           -0.0087 [0.01]
Race (other race = 1)                 -0.0191 * [0.01]
Respondent married                    -0.004 [0.01]
Respondent graduated high school      -0.0245 [0.02]
Respondent has some college           -0.0301 * [0.02]
Respondent has FFS Insurance           0.011 [0.90]
Respondent has HMO                    -0.028 *** [3.99]
Respondent is employed                -0.0121845 [1.16]
Income: under $20,000                  0.0690 *** [0.02]
Income: $20,000-$30,000                0.0567 ** [0.02]
Income: $30,000-$40,000                0.0451 ** [0.02]
Income: $40,000-$60,000                0.0109 [0.02]
Income: $60,000-$80,000               -0.0034 [0.02]
Income: $80,000-$100,000              -0.0002 [0.02]
Income: unknown                       -0.0159723 [1.16]
New England region                     0.00751 [0.48]
Southeast region                      -0.0018111 [0.21]
Midwest region                        -0.0058684 [0.65]
Plains region                          0.0005773 [0.04]
West region                           -0.0129824 [1.36]
Rate1--Rate2                           0.9021 *** [32.85]
dFP x Rate1                            0.1255 *** [4.16]
dPF x Rate2                           -0.1541 *** [4.93]
Constant                               0.248 *** [7.21]
Observations                        1635

[R.sup.2] robust standard errors in brackets.

* p < 0.1.

** p < 0.05.

*** p < 0.01.

Table 3. Probability of Screening Exams within Past Two Years
Separate Probit Estimator (t-Statistics in Brackets.)

                                  Mammography      PAP Smear

Discount rate                        1.1020         -9.5797 **
                                    [0.196]        [-2.146]
Discount rate * Age                  0.0701          0.0737
                                    [0.416]         [1.024]
Discount rate * Pr[Breast CN]     -334.7819
                                   [-1.330]
Pr[Breast CN]                      153.3195 *
                                    [1.842]
Discount rate * Pr[Cervical CN]                  5,998.0997 **
                                                    [2.262]
Pr[Cervical CN]                                 -4,338.5171 ***
                                                   [-2.870]
Discount rate * Pr[Prostate CN]

Pr[Prostate CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Oral CN]

Pr[Oral CN]

Discount rate * Pr[CVD]
Pr[CVD]

Discount rate * FFS Insurance       -1.1326          0.5353
                                   [-0.761]         [0.330]
Discount rate * HMO Insurance       -0.1840          1.3373
                                   [-0.178]         [1.000]
Observations                       909             909

                                  Prostate Exam   Dental Visit

Discount rate                      21.2232 ***      -2.7790
                                   [3.250]         [-1.108]
Discount rate * Age                -0.4895 ***       0.0360
                                  [-3.442]          [0.686]
Discount rate * Pr[Breast CN]

Pr[Breast CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Cervical CN]

Pr[Cervical CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Prostate CN]   141.0315 *
                                   [1.712]
Pr[Prostate CN]                   -58.7661 **
                                  [-2.448]
Discount rate * Pr[Oral CN]                       -204.1541
                                                   [-0.326]
Pr[Oral CN]                                         -7.2772
                                                   [-0.032]
Discount rate * Pr[CVD]
Pr[CVD]

Discount rate * FFS Insurance       1.7745           0.2878
                                   [1.194]          [0.298]
Discount rate * HMO Insurance       4.3041 ***       0.5779
                                   [3.814]          [0.751]
Observations                      726             1635

                                    Blood
                                   Pressure    Cholesterol
                                    Check         Check

Discount rate                       -5.3134      -4.8187 **
                                   [-1.025]     [-2.187]
Discount rate * Age                  0.0909       0.0776 *
                                    [0.820]      [1.743]
Discount rate * Pr[Breast CN]

Pr[Breast CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Cervical CN]

Pr[Cervical CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Prostate CN]

Pr[Prostate CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Oral CN]

Pr[Oral CN]

Discount rate * Pr[CVD]            -51.7020     -12.2294
Pr[CVD]                           [
22.6030    [-10.4775
                                    [1.273]      [0.239]
Discount rate * FFS Insurance        1.9021      -1.1328
                                    [0.970]     [-1.145]
Discount rate * HMO Insurance        0.2720       1.2482 *
                                    [0.151]      [1.758]
Observations                      1635         1635

Value of t-statistics in brackets.

* Significant at 10%.

** Significant at 5%.

*** Significant at 1%.

Also included, but not shown: indicator variables for male, age,
good health, current smoker, former smoker, cancer risk,
African-American, other race, high school, some college, FFS
insurance, HMO insurance, employed, income status (6 categories),
unreported income, and census region.

Table 4. Probability of Screening Exams within Past Two Years
2SLS Estimator

                                  Mammography     PAP Smear

Discount rate                        1.983          -9.0121
                                    [0.25]          [1.83] *
Discount rate * Age                  0.0436          0.0747
                                    [0.18]          [0.96]
Discount rate * Pr[Breast CN]     -289.8772
                                    [0.82]
Pr[Breast CN]                      147.6453
                                    [1.30]
Discount rate * Pr[Cervical CN]                  5,428.51
                                                    [1.96] **
Pr[Cervical CN]                                 -4,163.33
                                                    [2.80]
Discount rate * Pr[Prostate CN]

Pr[Prostate CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Oral CN]

Pr[Oral CN]

Discount rate * Pr[CVD]
Pr[CVD]

Discount rate * FFS Insurance       -1.5579         -0.2036
                                    [0.88]          [0.11]
Discount rate * HMO                 -0.0052          1.6452
Insurance                           [0.01]          [1.01]
Predicted term from 1st Stage      -48.6137        -85.3871
                                    [1.12]          [1.64] *
Observations                       909             909

                                  Prostate Exam   Dental Visit

Discount rate                      20.6764          -2.7258
                                   [2.76] ***       [1.16]
Discount rate * Age                -0.4839           0.0435
                                   [2.97] ***       [0.85]
Discount rate * Pr[Breast CN]

Pr[Breast CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Cervical CN]

Pr[Cervical CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Prostate CN]   135.9581
                                   [1.57]
Pr[Prostate CN]                   -58.8215
                                   [2.24]
Discount rate * Pr[Oral CN]                       -325.3897
                                                    [0.49]
Pr[Oral CN]                                         45.7768
                                                    [0.18]
Discount rate * Pr[CVD]
Pr[CVD]

Discount rate * FFS Insurance       2.6646          -0.5766
                                   [1.26]           [0.43]
Discount rate * HMO                 4.1324           0.8469
Insurance                          [3.56] ***       [1.18]
Predicted term from 1st Stage      77.0192         -97.3898
                                   [1.95] *         [3.37] ***
Observations                      726             1635

                                     Blood
                                   Pressure     Cholesterol
                                     Check         Check

Discount rate                       -5.6227       -4.8626
                                    [1.59]        [2.10] **
Discount rate * Age                  0.1085        0.0769
                                    [1.45]        [1.61]
Discount rate * Pr[Breast CN]

Pr[Breast CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Cervical CN]

Pr[Cervical CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Prostate CN]

Pr[Prostate CN]

Discount rate * Pr[Oral CN]

Pr[Oral CN]

Discount rate * Pr[CVD]            -63.5172      -11.8873
Pr[CVD]                             27.229        [2.1429
                                    [1.95] **     [0.35]
Discount rate * FFS Insurance        0.9957       -0.9718
                                    [0.56]        [0.89]
Discount rate * HMO                  0.3976        1.2408
Insurance                           [0.25]        [1.78] *
Predicted term from 1st Stage      -90.8521       14.859
                                    [1.76] *      [0.59]
Observations                      1635          1635

z statistics in brackets.

* Significant at 10%.

** Significant at 5%.

*** Significant at 1%.

Also included, but not shown: indicator variables for male, age,
good health, current smoker, former smoker, cancer risk,
African-American, other race, high school, some college, FFS
insurance, HMO insurance, employed, income status (6 categories),
unreported income, and census region.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有