首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月02日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Tacit collusion in price-setting duopoly markets: experimental evidence with complements and substitutes.
  • 作者:Anderson, Lisa R. ; Freeborn, Beth A. ; Holt, Charles A.
  • 期刊名称:Southern Economic Journal
  • 印刷版ISSN:0038-4038
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Southern Economic Association
  • 摘要:For decades, economists have studied oligopoly behavior using laboratory experiments. Much attention has been devoted to identifying factors that facilitate tacit collusion. We contribute to this literature by studying the effect of demand structure on the ability of subjects to collude within the price-setting model. Specifically, we consider Bertrand substitutes and Bertrand complements. (1) In the case of substitutes, the model generates upward-sloping reaction functions in prices. Hence, theory predicts that if one seller moves away from the Nash solution toward the collusive outcome, the other seller has a unilateral incentive to respond by raising price toward the collusive outcome. Alternatively, in the case of complements, the model generates downward-sloping reaction functions. So a unilateral deviation from the Nash solution toward the collusive outcome will provide a unilateral incentive for the other seller to adjust price in the opposite direction. Based on the slopes of the reaction functions, it is reasonable to expect that sellers of substitute goods might find it easier to collude tacitly than do sellers of complement goods (Holt 1995). This argument is not entirely compelling because the incentives are in terms of myopic best responses to past decisions of the other seller.
  • 关键词:Nash equilibrium;Price fixing;Tacit collusion

Tacit collusion in price-setting duopoly markets: experimental evidence with complements and substitutes.


Anderson, Lisa R. ; Freeborn, Beth A. ; Holt, Charles A. 等


1. Introduction

For decades, economists have studied oligopoly behavior using laboratory experiments. Much attention has been devoted to identifying factors that facilitate tacit collusion. We contribute to this literature by studying the effect of demand structure on the ability of subjects to collude within the price-setting model. Specifically, we consider Bertrand substitutes and Bertrand complements. (1) In the case of substitutes, the model generates upward-sloping reaction functions in prices. Hence, theory predicts that if one seller moves away from the Nash solution toward the collusive outcome, the other seller has a unilateral incentive to respond by raising price toward the collusive outcome. Alternatively, in the case of complements, the model generates downward-sloping reaction functions. So a unilateral deviation from the Nash solution toward the collusive outcome will provide a unilateral incentive for the other seller to adjust price in the opposite direction. Based on the slopes of the reaction functions, it is reasonable to expect that sellers of substitute goods might find it easier to collude tacitly than do sellers of complement goods (Holt 1995). This argument is not entirely compelling because the incentives are in terms of myopic best responses to past decisions of the other seller.

Moreover, the idea is somewhat at odds with economic intuition because sellers offering competing (substitute) products could reasonably be expected to engage in aggressive price-slashing behavior. In contrast, sellers of complementary goods might view the other person as more of a partner than a rival, thus fostering cooperation.

Two related articles suggest that subjects in experiments find it easier to tacitly collude when market structure generates upward-sloping reaction functions. In a recent survey, Suetens and Potters (2007) compare results from a series of Bertrand and Cournot experiments and conclude that subjects colluded more when the decision task was choosing price versus choosing quantity. One possible explanation for this finding is that reaction functions are upward sloping in Bertrand (substitutes) games and downward sloping in Cournot games. However, the different market choice variables (price versus quantity) cannot be ruled out as an explanation for the observed differences in collusion. As a follow up to this survey, Potters and Suetens (2008) conducted experiments with no market framing. They included treatments with upward-sloping and downward-sloping reaction functions. Consistent with the survey in their previous work, they conclude that there is more collusion with upward-sloping reaction functions in their experiment without market framing.

Many market experiments have focused on identifying other conditions that are favorable to seller collusion. Engel (2007) organizes the results from this vast literature in a meta-analysis that covers 107 articles. These studies span a wide range of experimental design features, including the number of firms per market, whether or not subjects have multiple interactions with the same rival, whether or not subjects face capacity constraints, whether or not firms offer more than one product, the degree of product differentiation, and the amount of information subjects receive about rivals' decisions and earnings. (2) Our design differs from all of the previous studies on collusion in the sense that we focus on the effect of market structure (substitutes versus complements) within the price-setting model. Hence, we eliminate any differences in behavior that might result from choosing quantity rather than price. Further, we include market framing in our experiments because tacit collusion is generally a market phenomenon. Our experimental design is described in detail in the next section, section 3 presents our results, and section 4 concludes.

2. Experimental Design

We recruited 128 subjects from undergraduate classes at the College of William and Mary. Subjects participated in a repeated symmetric duopoly price-setting game in either a complements treatment or a substitutes treatment. (3) Table 1 summarizes the equilibrium values derived from the experimental parameters. The complements design is based on the following demand curve: [Q.sub.1] = 3.60 - 0.5[P.sub.1] - 0.5[P.sub.2], where [Q.sub.1] represents the quantity sold by firm 1, [P.sub.l] represents the price set by firm 1, and [P.sub.2] represents the price set by firm 2. The Nash equilibrium price is $2.40 in this treatment. The substitutes design is based on the following demand curve: [Q.sub.1] = 3.60 - 2[P.sub.1] + [P.sub.2], and the Nash price is $1.20. In both designs, there is no marginal cost of production, and there is a fixed cost of $2.18 per round. With this fixed cost, earnings from collusion are 50% higher than earnings at the Nash equilibrium. Subjects earn $0.70 per person at the Nash equilibrium, and they earn $1.06 per person at the collusive outcome. Another important feature of this set of parameters is that the difference between the collusive price and Nash price is the same ($0.60) in both designs. In addition, the collusive price is the same for both designs and is $1.80. (4) Figure 1 presents the best-response functions for the two treatments. Notice that the collusive (joint profit maximizing) price is below the Nash price in the complements case on the left side, and it is above the Nash price in the substitutes case, shown on the right.

The Appendix contains instructions for the experiment. Subjects selected prices, and pairs were able to go at their own pace. Half of the subjects in each treatment interacted for 10 rounds, and half interacted for 20 rounds. (5) To avoid end-game effects, subjects were not told the number of rounds in advance. (6) Subjects were told that they were matched with the same person for each round. In addition, subjects were told the equation for demand, and it was common knowledge that all subjects within a session faced the same demand curve and costs. Finally, at the end of each round, subjects were told the price charged by the other seller. Average earnings were $6.42 in the sessions with 10 rounds and $10.74 in the sessions with 20 rounds. Earnings also varied considerably based on the treatment, as described below.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

3. Results

Analysis of Price Levels

Figure 2 shows the average price per round for both treatments separated by 10 and 20 round sessions. In the complements treatment, the average price starts between the collusive price and the Nash price. The average price rises and falls over time but generally climbs closer to the Nash price with repetition. It oscillates around the Nash price after 13 rounds of play. In the substitutes treatment, the average price also rises and falls over time but is generally below the Nash prediction. Notice that prices in the 10 round sessions appear to be slightly closer to the collusive price than prices in the 20 round sessions for both complements and substitutes. However, because subjects did not know the number of rounds they would play, there is no theoretical reason to believe that behavior would differ across those sessions. Hence, for much of the analysis that follows, we pool data for the first 10 rounds of play. Over all rounds, the average price is $1.12 in the substitutes treatment and $2.25 in the complements treatment. This difference in pricing behavior resulted in average earnings per subject of $0.74 per round in the complements treatment compared to $0.44 per round in the substitutes treatment. (7)

Overall, Figure 2 suggests that the average price in the complements treatment is closer to the collusive price than the average price in the substitutes treatment. To further investigate the amount of collusion across the two treatments, we define the "collusive region" as the range of prices within $0.30 of the collusive price. (8) Next, we identify matched pairs of subjects who priced in this region. We focus on pairs of subjects rather than individuals who priced cooperatively because collusion in a duopoly setting is only relevant and more likely to be sustained when both players choose the cooperative outcome. Over all 20 rounds, the percentage of pairs in the collusive region is 20% for complements and 5% for substitutes. (9)

Because subjects were paired for all rounds of the experiment, we can also examine how well pairs of subjects were able to sustain cooperation. When we consider a relatively strict definition of sustained cooperation as pricing in the cooperative region for at least 70% of the rounds played, 3 of the 32 pairs in the complements treatment and none of the 32 pairs in the substitutes treatment were able to sustain cooperation. When we consider a very liberal definition of sustained cooperation as maintaining prices in the cooperative region for at least 30% of the rounds played, 7 of the 32 pairs in the complements treatment and 3 of the 32 pairs in the substitutes treatment were able to sustain cooperation. (10) For each pair of subjects, we also calculate the percentage of rounds they priced in the collusive region. On average, pairs of subjects in the complements treatment priced in the collusive region in 23% of the rounds played. Pairs of subjects in the substitutes treatment priced in the collusive region in only 5% of the rounds played. Thus, subjects in the complements treatment were significantly more likely to price in this region than subjects in the substitutes treatment. (11)

Within this collusive region, subjects in the complements treatment appear to price closer to the collusive price of $1.80 than subjects in the substitutes treatment. Figure 3 shows average prices by round for the pairs of subjects who priced in the collusive range. The average price in the collusive region is $1.78 for complements and $1.64 for substitutes. For each pair that priced in the collusive region, we calculate the difference between the average price of the pair and the collusive price. Averaging over all rounds they were in the collusive region, pairs of subjects in the substitutes treatment deviated from the collusive price by $0.15, and pairs of subjects in the complements treatment deviated by only $0.03. The average price deviations in the substitutes and complements treatments are statistically different from one another at the 5% level. (12)

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

Turning our attention to competitive behavior, we define the "Nash region" to be prices within $0.30 of the Nash price. There are also large differences in the proportion of pairs who priced in this region, even in early rounds of play. Over 70% of pairs in the substitutes treatment priced in the Nash region in the first round of decision making compared to only 22% in the complements treatment. In every round, more pairs priced in the Nash region for the substitutes than the complements treatment. Looking at average pricing behavior over all rounds, 79% of the pairs of subjects in the substitutes treatment priced in the Nash region, while only 44% of the pairs in the complements treatment priced in the Nash region. Finally, we also calculate the percentage of rounds each pair of subjects priced in the Nash region. On average, pairs of subjects in the complements treatment priced in the Nash region in 38% of the rounds played, while pairs of subjects in the substitutes treatment priced in the Nash region in 77% of the rounds played. Thus, subjects in the substitutes treatment were significantly more likely to price in this region than subjects in the complements treatment. (13)

As an additional check on the way in which behavior differs across the two treatments, we calculate a standard measure of collusiveness for each duopoly pair: [rho] = ([P.sub.actual] - [P.sub.Nash])] ([P.sub.collude] - [P.sub.Nash]). Note that positive values of p indicate collusive behavior, zero indicates pricing at the Nash prediction, and negative values indicate supracompetitive pricing. Using the average collusiveness measure for each subject pair as the unit of observation, we obtain 32 observations for both the complements and substitutes treatments. We find [rho] = 0.24 in the complements treatment, and [rho] = - 0.13 in the substitutes treatment. These values are significantly different from each other at the 1% level. (14)

Although subjects do not know the number of rounds, it is possible that the degree of collusiveness decreases as subjects have the opportunity to learn. In fact, the average prices in Figure 2 appear to be approaching the Nash equilibrium toward the end of play. Table 2 presents the average degree of collusiveness over all subject pairs calculated for all rounds played and for early and late rounds of the experiment. The final column of Table 2 displays the t-test for equality of [[rho].sub.substitutes] and [[rho].sub.complements]. Note that there is significantly more collusive behavior (as indicated by the t-tests) in the complements treatment than in the substitutes treatment in four of the five comparisons presented in Table 2. The only comparison without significant differences between the two treatments is the one in which we only consider the final five rounds of the 20 round sessions. (15)

Analysis of Price Dynamics

Thus far, the analysis has focused on price levels, but pricing dynamics also reveal differences in tacit collusion across substitutes and complements. Here we examine how subjects respond to prices set by their partner in the previous round. Looking at rounds 2 through 10 (or 20), for each subject, we calculate the Nash best response to the partner's price in the previous round. Next, we compare the price actually chosen in a round to the best-response price for that round. For substitutes, if a subject prices higher than the best-response price in any given round, that price choice can be classified as "cooperation inducing." For complements, if a subject prices lower than the best-response price, that price choice can be classified as cooperation inducing. For each subject, we calculate the percentage of total prices chosen in rounds 2 through 10 (or 20) that were cooperation inducing. Figure 4 shows the distribution of cooperation-inducing prices by treatment. The pair of bars on the far left side of Figure 4 shows subjects who made cooperation-inducing price choices in less than 10% of the rounds played. Notice that only one subject in the complements treatment fell into this category, while 10 subjects in the substitutes treatment were in this category. At the other extreme, 12 subjects in the complements treatment made cooperation-inducing moves in every round, while only four subjects in the substitutes treatment did so. Overall, Figure 4 shows that subjects in the complements treatment choose cooperation-inducing prices more often than subjects in the substitutes treatment.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

We also use Nash best-response prices to identify collusive pairs. Again looking at rounds 2 through 10 (or 20), for each subject, we calculate the Nash best response to the partner's price in the previous round. Next, we calculate the deviation from the Nash price by subtracting the best response price for the actual price chosen in that round. In the substitutes treatment, a positive value for the deviation is indicative of cooperation-inducing behavior. In the complements treatment, a negative value for the deviation is indicative of cooperation-inducing behavior. For each player, we calculate the average deviation over all rounds played (not including round 1), and the resulting number gives a measure of how collusively that person priced. As a benchmark, in the complements treatment, if a pair of subjects chooses the joint profit maximizing price each round, they will each have a deviation of -$0.90 per round. In the substitutes treatment, if a pair of subjects chooses the joint profit maximizing price each round, they will each have a deviation of $0.45 per round. (16) By definition, Nash behavior in both treatments results in a deviation of $0 per round. For each pair of subjects, we plot their average deviations per round in the four-quadrant diagrams shown in Figure 5. The joint profit maximizing pairs of deviations are also plotted and labeled in the figure. Notice that more than half of the points in the complements graph fall into the lower left-hand quadrant, where both subjects had negative average deviations. This indicates that a majority of pairs chose cooperation-inducing prices in the complements treatment. However, only two pairs of subjects came close to the joint profit maximizing point of (-$0.90, -$0.90). In the substitutes treatment, very few pairs priced in the collusive (upper right-hand) region on the graph. The majority of pairs were clustered high in the supracompetitive (lower left) region.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

We next use Nash best-response prices to analyze behavior in the context of a learning direction theory (see Selten and Buchta [1998] and Capra et. al [1999] for more details about this model). Using the individual's best response to the other person's price in the previous round, we categorize each price change according to whether it was a movement toward or away from the best response. In both treatments, the number of movements toward the best response was not significantly different from the number of movements away from the best response (p = 0.19 for complements and p = 0.61 for substitutes). (17)

Finally, we analyze the dynamics of individual price-setting behavior using econometric methods. To identify whether players mimic the price changes of their partners, we regress the change in each seller's price in round t on the other seller's change in price in round t - 1. The lag in the other's price is necessary because people do not observe others' prices until after the round has ended. Table 3 displays the results from estimating models of [DELTA][price.sub.it] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1]

[DELTA][price.sub.jt-1] + [[epsilon].sub.it]. All models cluster standard errors at the pair level. We present models that control for individual heterogeneity using fixed effects (model 1) or random effects (model 2). We perform a Hausman test, which checks the more efficient model (random effects) against the less efficient but consistent model (individual fixed effects). For both substitutes and complements, we cannot reject the null that the coefficients estimated by the random-effects estimator are the same as the ones estimated by the fixed-effects estimator. (18) In all models, the effect of the other player's change in price is positive, suggesting that a price change by one player is generally followed by a move in the same direction by the other player, regardless of treatment. Note that the coefficient on the other's lagged price is larger in the substitutes treatment than in the complements treatment. Also, the coefficient in the substitutes treatment is significantly different from 0 at the 1% level, while the coefficient in the complements treatment is significant at the 10% level. Potters and Suetens (2008) find similar results and suggest that reciprocal behavior in the substitutes treatment may be explained by the slope of the reaction functions. Specifically, with upward-sloping reaction functions, players should adjust prices in the same direction as a change by the other player. Conversely, in the complements treatment, reciprocal behavior cannot be explained by the slope of the reaction functions. With downward-sloping reaction functions, players should adjust prices in the opposite direction of a change by the other player.

3. Discussion

We compare collusive behavior in Bertrand duopoly experiments with substitute goods versus complementary goods. We find moderate tacit collusion with complementary goods but no systematic tacit collusion with substitute goods. These results, combined with two recent related studies, suggest that market structure (that is, slope of the reaction function) is not the only determinant of collusive behavior in these experiments. Suetens and Potters (2007) compared measures of collusion in Bertrand and Cournot games from five separate experimental studies. All of the studies included Bertrand games and Cournot games and only modeled competition for substitute goods. Overall, Suetens and Potters (2007) report some evidence of tacit collusion in Bertrand markets, but no such evidence is seen in Cournot markets. This difference in results might be explained by the way that the problem was framed (price choice vs. quantity choice) or by the demand structure (the Bertrand games had upward-sloping reaction functions, and the Cournot games had downward-sloping reaction functions).

We can further explore this by comparing our results for Bertrand complements to the Cournot results that are reviewed in Suetens and Potters (2007). Mathematically, our Bertrand complements problem is identical to a Cournot substitutes game in the sense that reaction functions are downward sloping, and the Nash equilibrium level of the choice variable is greater than the collusive level. All five of the Cournot studies report subjects choosing quantities that were higher than the Cournot Nash levels. In contrast, we find a moderate degree of collusion with a similar demand structure but with a price choice, rather than a quantity choice, problem. This suggests that framing might be an important determinant of tacit collusion. (19)

To further explore the effect of framing, our results can be compared to the context-free experiments presented in Potters and Suetens (2008). They studied four experimental treatments that varied in terms of the slope of the reaction functions and the relative positions of the Nash prediction and the collusive solution in the strategy space. Two treatments had upward-sloping reaction functions, and two treatments had downward-sloping reaction functions. Each of those pairs had a treatment with the Nash prediction above the collusive solution and a treatment with the Nash below the collusive outcome.

The subjects in Potters and Suetens (2008) were Dutch college students. They played in fixed pairs and were told there would be 30 rounds. Further, at the end of each round, they were given all information about their opponent's choices and earnings. Unlike the previous work in this area, the experiment was not framed in a market context. Subjects did not choose prices or quantities; rather, they picked a number between 0 and 28. The Nash choice was 14 (the midpoint) across all treatments, and the collusive choice was either 2.5 or 25.5 depending on the treatment. Potters and Suetens (2008) report subjects' choices were generally between the Nash prediction and the collusive outcome in all four treatments, regardless of whether the Nash was above or below the collusive outcome. They calculate the degree of collusiveness for all four treatments and conclude that the slope of the reaction function was an important determinant in the degree of collusion, but behavior did not vary significantly depending on whether or not the collusive outcome was higher or lower than the Nash prediction.

The treatment used by Potters and Suetens (2008) with downward-sloping reaction functions and the collusive choice lower than the Nash choice is comparable to our complements treatment. They report [rho] = 0.24 in this case, which is identical to our finding. Potters and Suetens (2008) find the highest degree of collusion ([rho] = 0.42) in their treatment with upward-sloping reaction functions and the collusive choice greater than the Nash choice. We find very different results in our comparable (substitutes) treatment ([rho] = -0.13). It is possible that framing the choice problem as a market interaction tends to depress cooperative behavior when sellers view themselves as adversaries. Indeed, in a meta-analysis of oligopoly experiments, Engel (2007) notes that there is more collusion in experiments with a neutral frame relative to a market frame. This is also consistent with research from ultimatum game experiments. Hoffman et al. (1994) found that offers were closer to the Nash prediction when the game was framed as a market interaction as opposed to a bargaining interaction.

4. Conclusion

In summary, we find no collusion in price-setting markets with substitute goods and a moderate amount of tacit collusion in price-setting markets with complements. In both treatments, prices move closer to the Nash prediction with repetition, and in general, prices are closer to the Nash than to the collusive price. Our results are in contrast with some previous studies and suggest that framing the problem in a market context might affect behavior in important ways. Comparing our results to Potters and Suetens (2008), we provide a market framework and find less cooperation in our experiments with substitute goods. An obvious direction for future research is to extend this study to consider a quantity-choice problem with substitute and complement goods.

Appendix 1: Instructions for Complements Treatment

(Reprinted with permission from vecon.econ.virginia.edu/admin.php.) Page 1

Rounds and Matchings: The experiment sets up markets that are open for a number of rounds. Note: You will be matched with the same person in all rounds.

Interdependence: The decisions that you and the other person make will determine your earnings.

Price Decisions: Both you and the other person are sellers in the same market, and you will begin by choosing a price. You cannot see the other's price while choosing yours, and vice versa.

Sales Quantity: A lower price will tend to increase your sales quantity, and a higher price charged by the other seller will tend to lower your sales quantity. This is because consumers use your product together with the other's product, so an increase in their price will reduce your sales.

Page 2

Price and Sales Quantity: Your price decision must be between (and including) $1.50 and $3.00; use a decimal point to separate dollars from cents.

Production Cost: Your cost is $0.00 for each unit that you sell. However, you must pay a fixed cost of $2.18 for a license to operate, regardless of your sales quantity. So your total cost is $2.18, regardless of how many or few units you produce.

Consumer Demand: The quantity that consumers purchase depends on all prices. Your sales quantity will be determined by your price (P) and by the other seller's price (A): Sales Quantity = 3.60 - 0.50*P - 0.50*A. Negative quantities are not allowed, so your sales quantity will be 0 if the formula yields a negative quantity.

Sales Revenue: Your sales revenue is calculated by multiplying your production quantity and the price. Since your sales are affected by the other's price, you will not know your sales revenue until market results are available at the end of the period.

Page 3

Earnings: Your profit or earnings for a round is the difference between your sales revenue and your production cost. If Q is the quantity you sell, then total revenue is (Q*price), total cost is $0.00 + fixed cost of 2.18, so earnings = Q*(price) - $2.18.

Cumulative Earnings: The program will keep track of your total (cumulative) earnings. Positive earnings in a round will be added, and negative earnings will be subtracted. Working Capital: Each of you will be given an initial amount of money, $0.00, so that gains will be added to this amount, and losses will be subtracted from it. This initial working capital will show up in your cumulative earnings at the start of round 1, and it will be the same for everyone. There will he no subsequent augmentation of this amount.

Page 4

In the following examples, please use the mouse button to select the best answer. Remember, your sales quantity = 3.60 - 0.50*Price - 0.50*(Other Price).

Question 1: Suppose that both sellers choose equal prices and that the total sales for both sellers combined is Q units, then each seller has a sales quantity of:

(a) 2Q

(b) Q/2.

Question 2: A higher price will increase both the price-cost margin and the chance of having a positive sales quantity.(True/False)

(a) True.

(b) False.

Page 5

Question 1: Suppose that both sellers choose equal prices and that the total sales for both sellers combined is Q units, then each seller has a sales quantity of:

(a) 2Q

(b) Q/2

Your answer, Ca), is Correct. The sales quantity formula divides sales equally when prices are equal.

Question 2: A higher price will increase both the price-cost margin and the chance of having a positive sales quantity.(True/False)

(a) True.

(b) False.

Your answer, (b), is Correct. The chances of making sales go down as price is increased.

Page 6

Matchings: Please remember that you will be matched with the same person in all rounds.

Earnings: All people will begin a round by choosing a number or "price" between and including $1.50 and $3.00. Remember, your sales quantity = 3.60 - 0.50*Price + - 0.50*(Other Price). Your total cost is $0.00 times your sales quantity, plus your fixed cost $2.18, and your total sales revenue is the price times your sales quantity. Your earnings are your total revenue minus your total cost. Positive earnings are added to your cumulative earnings, and losses are subtracted.

Rounds: There will be a number of rounds, and you are matched with the same person in all rounds.

Appendix 2: Instructions for Substitutes Treatment

(copied from veconlab.econ.virginia.edu/admin.htm)

Page 1

Rounds and Matchings: The experiment sets up markets that are open for a number of rounds. Note: You will be matched with the same person in all rounds.

Interdependence: The decisions that you and the other person make will determine your earnings.

Price Decisions: Both you and the other person are sellers in the same market, and you will begin by choosing a price. You cannot see the other's price while choosing yours, and vice versa.

Sales Quantity: A lower price will tend to increase your sales quantity, and a higher price charged by the other seller will tend to raise your sales quantity. This is because consumers view the products as similar, so an increase in their price will increase your sales.

Page 2

Price and Sales Quantity: Your price decision must be between (and including) $0.60 and $2.10; use a decimal point to separate dollars from cents. An increase in the other seller's price will tend to raise the number of units you sell.

Production Cost: Your cost is $0.00 for each unit that you sell. However, you must pay a fixed cost of $2.18 for a license to operate, regardless of your sales quantity. So your total cost is $2.18, regardless of how many or few units you produce.

Consumer Demand: The quantity that consumers purchase depends on all prices, with more of the sales going to the seller with the lowest (best available) price in the market. Your sales quantity will be determined by your price (P) and by the other seller's price (A): Sales Quantity = 3.60 - 2.00*P + 1.00*A.

Negative quantities are not allowed, so your sales quantity will be 0 if the formula yields a negative quantity.

Sales Revenue: Your sales revenue is calculated by multiplying your production quantity and the price. Since your sales are affected by the other's price, you will not know your sales revenue until market results are available at the end of the period.

Page 3

Earnings: Your profit or earnings for a round is the difference between your sales revenue and your production cost. If Q is the quantity you sell, then total revenue is (Q*price), total cost is $0.00 + fixed cost of 2.18, so earnings = Q*(price) - $2.18.

Cumulative Earnings: The program will keep track of your total (cumulative) earnings. Positive earnings in a round will be added, and negative earnings will be subtracted.

Working Capital: Each of you will be given an initial amount of money of $0.00, so that gains will be added to this amount, and losses will be subtracted from it. This initial working capital will show up in your cumulative earnings at the start of round 1, and it will be the same for everyone. There will be no subsequent augmentation of this amount.

Page 4

In the following examples, please use the mouse button to select the best answer. Remember, your sales quantity = 3.60 - 2.00*Price + 1.00*(Other Price).

Question 1: Suppose that both sellers choose equal prices and that the total sales for both sellers combined is Q units, then each seller has a sales quantity of:

(a) 2Q

(b) Q/2.

Question 2: A higher price will increase both the price-cost margin and the chance of having a positive sales quantity.(True/False)

(a) True.

(b) False.

Page 5

Question 1: Suppose that both sellers choose equal prices and that the total sales for both sellers combined is Q units, then each seller has a sales quantity of:

(a) 2Q

(b) Q/2

Your answer, (b), is Correct. The sales quantity formula divides sales equally when prices are equal.

Question 2: A higher price will increase both the price-cost margin and the chance of having a positive sales quantity.(True/False)

(a) True.

(b) False.

Your answer, (b), is Correct. The chances of making sales go down as price is increased.

Page 6

Matchings: Please remember that you will be matched with the same person in all rounds.

Price Choice: All people will begin a round by choosing a number or "price" between and including $0.60 and $2.10.

Demand: Remember, your sales quantity = 3.60 - 2.00*Price + 1.00*(Other Price).

Cost: Your total cost is $0.00 times your sales quantity, plus your fixed cost $2.18.

Earnings: Your earnings are your total revenue (price multiplied by sales quantity) minus your total cost. Positive earnings are added to your cumulative earnings, and losses are subtracted.

References

Altavilla, Carlo, Luigi Luini, and Patrizia Sbriglia. 2006. Social learning in market games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 61:632-52.

Capra, C. Monica, Jacob K. Goeree, Rosario Gomez, and Charles A. Holt. 1999. Anomalous behavior in a traveler's dilemma. American Economic Review 89(3):678-90.

Davis, Douglas. 2008. Do strategic substitutes make better markets? A comparison of Bertrand and Cournot markets. Unpublished Paper, Virginia Commonwealth University.

Dolbear, F. Trenery, Lester B. Lave, G. Bowman, A. Lieberman, Edward C. Prescott, R. Rueter, and Roger Sherman. 1968. Collusion in oligopoly: An experiment on the effect of numbers and information. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 82(2):240-59.

Dufwenberg, Martin, and Uri Gneezy. 2000. Price competition and market concentration: An experimental study. International Journal of Industrial Organization 18:7-22.

Engel, Christoph. 2007. How much collusion: A meta-analysis of oligopoly experiments. Journal of Competition Law and Economics 3(4):491-549.

Feinberg, Robert M., and Roger Sherman. 1988. Mutual forbearance under experimental conditions. Southern Economic Journal 54(4):985-93.

Garcia-Gallego, Aurora. 1998. Oligopoly experimentation of learning with simulated markets. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 25:333-55.

Garcia-Gallego, Aurora, and Nikolaos Georgantzls. 2001. Multiproduct activity in an experimental differentiated oligopoly. International Journal of Industrial Organization 19:493-518.

Hoffman, Elizabeth, Kevin McCabe, Keith Shachat, and Vernon Smith. 1994. Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior 7(3):346-80.

Holt, Charles A. 1995. Industrial organization: A survey of laboratory research. In Handbook of experimental economies, edited by John Kagel and A1 Roth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 349-443.

Holt, Charles A., and Susan K. Laury. 2008. Theoretical explanations of treatment effects in voluntary contributions experiments. In Handbook of experimental economics results, Volume 1, edited by Charles Plott and Vernon Smith. New York: Elsevier Press, pp. 846-55.

Huck, Steffen, Hans-Theo Normann, and Joerg Oechssler. 2000. Does information about competitors' actions increase or decrease competition in experimental oligopoly markets? International Journal of Industrial Organization 18:39-57.

Potters, Jan, and Sigrid Suetens. 2008. Cooperation in experimental games of strategic complements and substitutes. Review of Economic Studies 76(3):1125-47.

Selten, Reinhard, and Joachim Buchta. 1998. Experimental sealed bid first price auctions with directly observed bid functions. In Games and human behavior, edited by D. Budescu, I. Erev, and R. Zwick. Philadelphia, PA: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, pp. 79-104.

Sherman, Roger. 1971. An experiment on the persistence of price collusion. Southern Economic Journal 37(4):489-95.

Suetens, Sigrid, and Jan Potters. 2007. Bertrand colludes more than Cournot. Experimental Economics 10:71-7.

Lisa R. Anderson, * Beth A. Freeborn, ([dagger]) and Charles A. Holt ([double dagger])

* Department of Economics, College of William and Mary, Williamsburg, VA 23187, USA; E-mail [email protected]; corresponding author.

([dagger]) Department of Economics, College of William and Mary, Williamsburg, VA 23187, USA; E-mail [email protected].

([double dagger]) Department of Economics, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, VA 22904, USA; E-mail [email protected].

Financial support from the National Science Foundation (SBR 0094800) is gratefully acknowledged. We thank Sara St. Hillaire for research assistance and three anonymous reviewers for comments.

Received July 2008; accepted January 2009.

(1) Note that we refer to goods from a consumption perspective rather than a production perspective. Specifically, we use the term "substitute goods" to refer to goods with a positive cross price elasticity of demand. Some studies in this area define the relationship between goods based on producers' reaction functions, which can be affected by cost considerations as well as demand effects. For example, the term "strategic substitutes" refers to downward-sloping reaction functions, and the term "strategic complements" refers to upward-sloping reaction functions.

(2) See, for example, Dufwenberg and Gneezy (2000) on the effect of number of firms, Feinberg and Sherman (1988) on the effect of repeated matchings, Sherman (1971) on the effect of capacity costs, Garcia-Gallego and Georgantzis (2001) on multiproduct firms, Garcia-Gallego (1998) on product differentiation, and Huck, Normann, and Oechssler (2000) and Altavilla, Luini, and Sbriglia (2006) on the effect of information about other's choices and earnings. A recent article by Davis (2008) studies the effect of product differentiation on pricing behavior and reports that Bertrand markets converge to the Nash prediction faster than Cournot markets. Note that this finding is somewhat inconsistent with the results reported in Potters and Suetens (2008). Further, a high degree of product substitutability speeds the convergence to Nash prices in Bertrand markets.

(3) Experiments were conducted using the Veconlab website developed by Charles Holt at the University of Virginia.

(4) Suetens and Potters (2007) report a "Friedman Index" to measure the sustainability of collusion. It is calculated as the collusive profit minus the Nash profit (the potential gain from colluding) divided by the maximum profit from a unilateral defection minus the collusive profit (the potential gain from defecting on a collusive agreement). The five studies they review have indexes ranging from 0.32 to 1.00. The parameters in our experiment generate a Friedman Index of 0.88 in both treatments, which is higher than three of the five studies reviewed in Suetens and Potters (2007).

(5) This design feature was motivated by results we observed in early sessions of the experiment. We had subjects play only 10 rounds of the experiment, and we noticed a general upward trend in prices over all 10 rounds in the substitutes treatment and the complements treatment. We added the 20 round sessions to determine whether or not that trend would persist past 10 rounds.

(6) In an early experimental study of collusion in Bertrand markets, Dolbear et al. (1968) report that subjects altered behavior in late rounds of their pilot experiments. More recently, end-game effects have been observed in public goods experiments. Holt and Laury (2008) survey articles using the voluntary contributions mechanism and report that when the number of rounds is known, cooperation declines in late rounds of the experiment.

(7) Average per round earnings are higher in the complements treatment than in the substitutes treatment at the 1% level (t-stat = 4.80, p = 0.0000). To test for significant differences in earnings across the treatments, we calculated the average earnings per round for each subject, which resulted in a total of 128 observations.

(8) We chose $0.30 as the boundary of the collusive region because it is the midpoint between the collusive price and the Nash price.

(9) In the substitutes treatment, there are six rounds with no pairs pricing in the collusive region (rounds 1 and 2 and 16-19). There is at least one pair that prices in the collusive region for all rounds of the complements treatment.

(10) There is no evidence that the number of rounds played affects the ability of subjects to maintain collusion. The pairs of collusive subjects were distributed roughly equally across the 10 and 20 round sessions.

(11) The unit of observation for this t-test is the percentage of rounds a pair of subjects priced in the collusive region (n = 64, t-star = 3.56, p = 0.0000).

(12) The unit of observation for this t-test is the average deviation from the collusive price made by a pair of subjects during the rounds they priced in the collusive region (n = 64, t-stat = 2.20, p = 0.0186).

(13) The unit of observation for this t-test is the percentage of rounds a pair of subjects priced in the Nash region (n = 64, t-stat = 5.91, p = 0.0000).

(14) The unit of observation for this t-test is the average p for a pair of subjects (n = 64, t-star = 4.51, p = 0.0000).

(15) Table 2 also reveals that prices were more competitive in the 20 round sessions than in the 10 round sessions (as indicated by the lower values of [rho]). For example, averaging over all rounds played in the substitutes treatment, [rho] = - 0.100 for pairs who played 10 rounds, and [rho] = -0.161 for subjects who played 20 rounds. Since subjects did not know how many rounds they would play, there is no theoretical explanation for why subjects would behave differently in these sessions.

(16) These joint profit maximizing deviations are derived from the best-response functions as follows. In the substitutes treatment, the best response to the joint profit maximizing price is [P.sub.A] = 0.90 + 0.25[P.sub.B] = 0.90 + 0.25 (1.80) = $1.35. The deviation between the joint profit maximizing price and the best response is $1.80 - $1.35 = $0.45. Similarly, in the complements treatment, the best response to the joint profit maximizing price is [P.sub.A] = 3.60 - 0.50[P.sub.B] = 3.60 -- 0.50 (1.80) = $2.70. The deviation between the joint profit maximizing price and the best response is $1.80 - $2.70 = -$0.90.

(17) A more complete version of these results is available from the authors upon request.

(18) The [chi square] values for the Hausman test are 0.16 for substitutes and 0.00 for complements.

(19) Alternatively, it might appear that there is more collusion in the complements treatment because it is harder for subjects to determine the Nash best response with downward-sloping reaction functions. The results reported in Potters and Suetens (2008) contradict this explanation; they report significantly less collusion with downward-sloping reaction function than with upward-sloping function. The results of the learning direction analysis described in the results section also contradict this explanation. If it is more difficult for subjects to figure out the Nash best response with downward-sloping reaction functions, in early rounds of play, subjects in the complements treatment should be less likely to make price changes in the direction of the Nash best response than subjects in the substitutes treatment. The learning-direction analysis shows that in round 2, more subjects responded to their partner's round 1 price by moving in the direction of the Nash price in the complements treatment (42%) than in the substitutes treatment (39%). If we take an average over rounds 2 through 5, we find that the number of subjects moving in the direction of the Nash price is identical across treatments at 52%. Thus, there is no evidence in early rounds of play that subjects in the substitutes treatment were more aware of the Nash best response than subjects in the complements treatment. Over all rounds, subjects in the complements treatment moved toward the Nash best response 57% of the time compared to 50% for subjects in the substitutes treatment.
Table 1. Equilibrium Values

                               Complements Treatment

                    Price             Quantity       Profit Per Round

Nash                $2.40               1.2               $0.70
Joint profit
  maximizing        $1.80               1.8               $1.06

                               Substitutes Treatment

                    Price             Quantity       Profit Per Round

Nash                $1.20               2.4               $0.70
Joint profit
  maximizing        $1.80               1.8               $1.06

Table 2. Pair-Level Average Degree of Collusiveness
by Rounds of Play

                           Substitutes            Complements

                       Mean      Standard      Mean      Standard
Rounds of Play        [rho]     Deviation     [rho]     Deviation

Panel A: 10 Round Sessions
  All 10 rounds       -0.100      0.066       0.370       0.081
  Last 5 rounds       -0.005      0.068       0.311       0.094

Panel B: 20 Round Sessions
  All 20 rounds       -0.161      0.081       0.116       0.094
  First 10 rounds     -0.183      0.085       0.212       0.115
  Last 5 rounds       -0.121      0.086       0.011       0.125

                     t-test for
Rounds of Play       Equality

Panel A: 10 Round Sessions
  All 10 rounds      -4.532 ***
  Last 5 rounds      -2.730 ***

Panel B: 20 Round Sessions
  All 20 rounds      -2.238 **
  First 10 rounds    -2.765 ***
  Last 5 rounds      -0.868

There are 16 pairs of subjects within each of the four groups
represented in the table (10 round complements, 10 round
substitutes, 20 round complements, and 20 round substitutes).

* p < 0.10.

** p < 0.05.

*** p < 0.01.

Table 3. Regression of Change in Individual's Price

                                  Model 1              Model 2

Panel A: Complement goods
  Lagged change in other     0.0866 * (0.048)     0.0870 * (0.048)
    seller's price
  Control for individual     Fixed effects        Random effects
Panel B: Substitute goods
  Lagged change in other     0.1447 *** (0.040)   0.1484 *** (0.039)
    seller's price
  Control for individual     Fixed effects        Random effects

Standard errors are in parentheses. Because the independent
variable is lagged change in other seller's price, we cannot
use the first two rounds of prices. This results in 832
observations for each regression.

* p < 0.10.

** p < 0.05.

*** p < 0.01.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有