Financial markets and retail construction cycles.
Moss, Steven ; Parker, Darrell ; Laposa, Steve 等
INTRODUCTION AND LITERATURE
It is not universally accepted that specific activities such as
retail construction have a cycle of their own. It can be argued that
time series data with apparent cycles may be nothing more than chance
happenings (Markridakis, Wheelwright & Hyndman, 1998). At the
macro-economic level it is generally believed that the US economy has a
business cycle (Reilly, 1985; Ritter, 1995). A business cycle is a
wavelike or oscillating pattern about the secular trend (Mendenhall
& Sinich, 1993). Granger and Newbold (1977) argue that when a series
is plotted through time it may appear smoother than white noise. The
autocorrelation or smoothness can be the effect of sums of cosine waves
in the data that form a linear cycle model. Cycles can be two to ten
years or longer in length and are not always a function of the overall
business cycle (Bowerman & O'Connell, 1987).
Supply modeling for real estate markets has continued to progress
over the last 14 years, and there are standard products available from
information specialists. Early supply models built upon the foundation
laid by Rosen (1984), who presented a model for office stock integration
with new construction, vacancy rate, and rent. Wheaton (1987) extended
Rosen's work adapting econometric models to national office
building time series data. Born (1988), Grenadier (1995), Clapp,
Pollakowski, and Lynford (1992) have developed models for the office
market and real estate cycles. Real estate cycle estimation is important
for investors and real estate professionals. Tsolacos (1999) states that
"Quantitative studies of retail property developments are very
useful to real estate professionals because the output of this work can
be incorporated into the information set that analysts use to form
expectations about cyclical trends of new retail development".
Capital markets, interest rates and the real estate construction
cycle may be interrelated. During periods when real estate financing is
readily available at low interest rates overbuilding may occur reducing
rents, increasing vacancy rates and increasing the risk of defaults on
mortgages. The property manager should consider the relationship between
lease duration and timing within the real estate cycle. During the
bottom of the cycle when rents are at a low point it would be
inadvisable to sign long-term leases at the current rent level.
Benjamin, Jud and Winkler (1998a) propose that modeling retail
supply is important for academics and professionals. They conclude that
retail sales are related the demand for retail space but that demand and
supply are inelastic. Benjamin et. al. conclude that interest rates do
not have a significant impact on retail supply. Benjamin, Jud and
Winkler (1998b) model individual MSA's retail supply adjustment as
a function of retail sales and interest rates. Benjamin et. al conclude
that supply adjustments are inelastic in the short run in relationship
to retail sales and elastic in the long run. Scott and Judge (2000)
argue that property investment values are influenced by the development
cycle.
There is evidence that bank lending patterns change over time and
may follow cycles. The Federal Reserve Bank 1997, Nugent (2001), and the
Kulish (2001) report that banks change lending standards over time. The
changing lending standards make it easier or more difficult for
developers to obtain loans. Asea and Blomberg (1998) concluded that
banks lending standards systematically vary over a cycle. They also use
national unemployment rates as a proxy for national lending standards.
Within a regional analysis of lending, unemployment becomes a local
market measure. The empirical question remains as to the robustness of
this role of unemployment to lending at the local level.
Henneberry's 1999 study showed that there are cycles in office
building construction in England. Additionally, Henneberry argues that
the cycles are convergent due to mature capital markets and at the same
time divergent based on regional factors. Tsolacos (1999) used a single
series from 1985 to 1996 and modeled retail construction starts as a
function of consumer spending, rents, and yield levels using a VAR
model. Tsolacos (1999) concluded that there are retail construction
cycles in England, but that the cycles are not convergent in
relationship to national investment markets. Scott and Judge (2000)
analyzed a series from 1956 to 1996 and concluded that there is a retail
property value cycle in Great Britain with a cycle length of 7.8 years
Hudson-Wilson and Pappadopoulos (1999) concluded that there are real
estate cycles and they are linked to capital markets. Hudson-Wilson and
Pappadopoulos also concluded that real estate cycles are divergent
across markets and that traditional modeling techniques fail to
recognize these cycles. Hudson-Wilson and Pappadopoulos contend that
real estate cycles are a key factor missing in the estimation of default
risk for commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS). Lawson (1998)
proposes that there are retail real estate cycles and that different
cities and different types of retail have different cycles.
The purpose of this study is to: 1. Show there is evidence of
convergent cycles in retail construction, and 2. Model the retail
construction cycle as a function of capital markets. Panel data will be
used to model 58 MSA's time series for a period of 27 years each. A
series length of 27 years would normally be far too short to estimate
autoregressive functions and evaluate potential cycles. A
cross-sectional/time-series regression model (panel data) using all 1566
observations preserves the integrity of the time series structure. This
will allow for time series analysis and cycle estimation in a relatively
short time series.
DATA
The dependent variable in this study is retail supply (RS). RS is
gross retail construction, in square feet, for 58 metropolitan
statistical areas (MSAs) for the periods 1970 to 1996. The data is
comprised of 58 time series of 27 periods each, for a total number of
1,566 observations. The retail supply data was obtained from FW Dodge.
There are two kinds of independent variables used to model retail
construction, local MSA level and capital market variables. The local
variables vary by both MSA and by year. The capital market variables
vary by year, but are the same for all MSAs in a given year. The capital
market variables are non-farm, non-residential loan balances outstanding
for the United States and Other Areas (CB) as reported for commercial
banks by the FDIC.
CB has been adjusted to 1996 dollars (ACB). The second capital
market variable is the prime interest rate (Prime) as reported by the
Federal Reserve Board. Both ACB and Prime are measured as first
differences
The first local independent variable is households (HH) by year, by
MSA. Households are the number of families in a MSA. Households are used
in this model instead of population. Retail expenditures such as
televisions, furniture, drapes, etc. maybe more closely related to the
household units, instead of the individuals within the households.
Household data was obtained from Woods and Poole.
The second local independent variable is retail sales (Sales) by
MSA, by year, adjusted to 1996 dollars. Retail sales were obtained from
the US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. Descriptive
statistics for all variables are shown in Table 1.
METHODOLOGY
A cross-sectional/time-series regression (panel data), shown in
equation 1, is utilized in this research (Hsiao, 1986). Ambrose and
Nourse (1993) used this methodology to analyze capitalization rates.
[y.sub.it] = [summation] [Bx.sub.it] + [E.sub.i] + [M.sub.t] +
[N.sub.it] (1)
for,
i = 1 to 58 t = 1 to 27
x is the vector of independent variables
B is the vector of regression coefficients
[E.sub.i] is the individual effect
[M.sub.t] is the time effect
[N.sub.it] is the random error term
One advantage of the cross-section/time-series regression model for
panel data is that the regression parameters are estimated with all 1566
observations, whereas a yearly index of the 58 MSAs would have only 27
observations. Indexing would also eliminate the ability to test for
differences in response by MSA. Pooling all 1566 observations without
regard to time period would remove the possibility of incorporating
lagged relationships in the model.
The fixed effects model also provides tests for response
differences relative to time (Mt) or individual MSA ([E.sub.i]). These
tests involve partitioning the residuals of the linear regression equation by year and by MSA and performing an ANOVA on the partitioned
residuals to test for main effects relative to time period or MSA
(Hsiao, 1986). A finding that time period is significant in the
residuals would indicate that the mean response across MSAs differs by
year. On average for all 58 MSAs, the model would systematically
over-predict in some years and under-predict in others. A pattern in the
residuals based on time period may be evidence of a cycle.
A finding that individual or MSA effects are significant would
indicate that some MSAs have higher or lower retail construction starts
(after regressing out the effects of the independent variables) relative
to other MSAs regardless of the time period. This could be an indication
that the model is divergent across MSAs.
Each MSA's retail supply exhibits a positive trend over time.
The time series methodology used in this paper, (see methodology),
requires that all variables be transformed to stationary series. A
stationary series is defined as a time series with a constant mean and
variance (Vandaele, 1983; Fuller, 1976). Using a stationary series
avoids problems with spurious correlations. To obtain a stationary
series, first differences of retail supply (DRS) were obtained. Since
the data set has 58 time series the individual and average observations
were analyzed for stationarity.
The mean and variance of the series now appear constant, satisfying
the conditions of a stationary series. The auto-correlation in the
series will be discussed in the results sections to follow. The first
differences of RS represent the new retail space added each year.
The household series exhibit varying degrees of positive trend over
time. First differences (DHH) were obtained to transform HH to a
stationary series. The DHH represents the net change in households each
year within an MSA. Retail sales also show trends within each MSA. First
differences of sales, (Dsales) are used to transform sales to a
stationary series
RESULTS
Total retail construction, shows upward trends with no distinct
cyclical pattern. DRS, shows autocorrelation but no distinct repeating
cycle. To determine if DRS is cyclical the effects household formations
(DHH), retail sales (Dsales) and short-term autocorrelation will be
regressed out of DRS. Then the residuals of the DRS model will be
analyzed to determine if there is a cycle present (Bails & Peppers,
1993; Markridakis et.al, 1998).
The first step in developing the regression model is to observe the
autocorrelation and partial auto-correlation function to determine the
autoregressive structure for DRS.
The autocorrelation function and partial autocorrelation function
show that lags of DRS up to 6 periods may need to be included in the
model. The Ljung-Box Q-statistic, significant at the 1% level, confirms
the DRS series is not white noise.
After the autoregressive structure of the dependent variable is
determined, the independent variables, DHH and Dsales, are added to the
model. During this process the objective is to achieve white noise in
the residuals. The regression model shown in equation 2 is the result.
DRSt =216.24+.082D[Sale.sub.t-1]+12.09[DHH.sub.t]+13.16
[DHH.sub.t-1]+.57[DRS.sub.t-1]+.07[DRS.sub.t-2]+.16[DRS.sub.t-6] (2)
(4.3) * (5.7) * (2.6) ** (12.4) * (1.7) *** (6.3) *
[R.sup.2] = .677
where,
t statistics are shown in parenthesis
* significant at the 1% level.
** significant at the 5% level
*** significant at the 10% level
The Ljung-Box Q test, significant at the 10% level, indicates that
the residuals may not be white noise. The autocorrelation function and
partial autocorrelation function for equation 2 indicate that the
residuals for equation 2 are white noise.
Equation 2 confirms Benjamin, Judd and Winkler (1998) findings that
there is a relationship between retail sales changes and retail
construction. Benjamin, Judd and Winkler findings suggested that this
relationship lagged on average 8.1 years, varying from 2 to 20 years by
MSA. Our results using the cross-sectional/time-series regression model
with first differenced variables show intermediate lags of retail sales
are not significant. Longer lags, six to 9 years, are statistically
significant, but have a negative coefficient and almost no observable
impact on the [R.sup.2]. The model also indicates that household
formations play a significant role for predicting retail construction
starts.
Dokko, Edlestein, Lacayo and Lee (1999) found that when developing
a model for income and value cycles that each MSA had its own cycle and
required its own estimation (the cycle was divergent across MSAs). The
significance of the regression coefficients in equation 2 using all 58
MSAs simultaneously indicates that the relationships are to some degree
stable across MSAs for retail construction. If the relationship between
DRS and the independents changed by MSA the coefficients would not be
statistically significant in the cross-sectional/time-series regression.
To determine if there is a long-term cycle in retail construction,
the residuals from equation 2 were averaged by year. The yearly average
is based on a yearly sample size of 58, one data point for each MSA in
the study.
This analysis also indicates that a cycle does exist for the
residuals and is stable (convergent) across MSAs. If each MSA were on an
independent cycle (divergent) the residuals by year would have been
random and cancelled each other out resulting in a mean residual of zero
for each year. This finding is confirmed by the ANOVA model for the
residuals of the cross-sectional/time-series regression (equation 2)
shown in Table 2.
The ANOVA indicates the residuals are not significantly different
by MSA but are significantly different by year. The convergent cycle
confirms the findings of Henneberry (1999) and Hudson-Wilson and
Pappadopoulis (1999). The cycle length is approximately 8-10 years the
same as found by Scott and Judge (2000). Low points of the construction
cycle are in the early 1980's and 1990's. High points of the
cycle are in the late 1970's, mid 1980's and mid 1990's.
Prior studies such as Tsolacos (1999), Benjamin, Jud and Winkler
(1998), Henneberry (1999), and Hudson-Wilson and Pappadopoulis (1999)
have suggested that retail construction cycles may be influenced by
capital market variables. The second objective of this research is to
determine if the retail construction cycle, observed in the residuals of
equation 2, is influenced by capital market variables. To model the
retail construction cycle the average residual from equation 2 serves as
the dependent variable. The independent variables are U.S. commercial
banks non-farm, non-residential loan balances adjusted to 1996 dollars
(DACB) and the prime rate (DPrime), both in first difference form. Both
variables are the same by year for each MSAs. The resulting regression
is shown in equation 3.
Avg[Res.sub.t] = -23.27 + 9.44[DACB.sub.t] - 7.57[DACB.sub.t-2] -
37.05D[Prime.sub.t-2] (3)
(2.32) * (2.14) * (1.79) **
* significant at the 5% level
** significant at the 10% level
[R.sup.2] = .498
Where,
DACB = First differences of commercial bank portfolios
DPrime = First difference of the prime interest rate
The [R.sup.2] for equation 3 indicates that 50% of the retail
construction cycle can be explained by two capital market variables. The
convergent retail construction cycle is inversely related to changes
interest rates on a lagged basis. The model also indicates that when
banks increase their outstanding loan balances there is an increase in
retail construction followed by smaller lagged reduction in retail
construction two years later. The conclusion can be drawn that to the
degree there are national lending and interest rate cycles they are
influencing the retail construction cycle.
Having established that there is a convergent retail construction
cycles influenced by capital markets, the next step is determine the
relative importance of the retail construction cycle driven by capital
market variables versus the local MSA level variables in equation 2.
This is accomplished by adding the U.S. commercial bank portfolio and
prime rate variables to the cross-sectional/time-series regression. The
results are shown in equation 4 and reported fully in Table 3.
[DRS.sub.t] =146.87+.03D[Sale.sub.t-1]+11.55[DHH.sub.t]+14.62
[DHH.sub.t-1]+.54[DRS.sub.t-1]+.09[DRS.sub.t-2]+.14[DRS.sub.t-6] (2.0)
** (2.5) ** (3.1) * (12.0) * (2.4) ** (5.7) *
12.03[DACB.sub.t] - 7.89[DACB.sub.t-2] - 56.85D[Prime.sub.t-2] (4)
(4.9) * (4.0) * (4.3) *
[R.sup.2] = .694
where,
t statistics are shown in parenthesis
* significant at the 1% level.
** significant at the 5% level
The results show that the relationship with the national financial
variables remains the same when the model is simultaneously estimated
across all 58 MSAs. The results also indicate that the impact of the
capital market variables is incremental. All the local MSA level
variables from equation 2 remain statistically significant with only
small changes in the coefficients.
The Ljung-Box Q test, autocorrelations and partial autocorrelations
for the residuals of equation 4 now indicate that the residuals are
white noise. In other words, the cycle in the residuals has been removed
by adding the capital market variables to the model.
The additional predictive power of the retail construction cycle
can be determined by comparing the [R.sup.2] of equation 2 and 4. This
provides a measure of the importance of the capital market variables and
thus the retail construction cycle. By adding the capital market
variables driving the retail construction cycle to the model the
[R.sup.2] only increases from .677 to .694. This would indicate that
although there is retail construction cycle influenced by national bank
lending and interest the additional explanatory power of the capital
markets is minimal compared to local variables such as local retail
sales, house hold formations, and short term construction trends. The
cross-sectional/time-series model was also estimated with only the
capital market variables. The variables were all significant in the
resulting equation. The R2 for the equation was only .059 confirming the
minimal impact of the capital markets on MSA level retail construction
starts.
Another check for robustness can be found by examining the impact
of recessionary periods upon the estimation. Asea and Bloomberg (1998)
use monthly data and find that changes in lending standards have a more
profound effect on the economy during an expansion than a contraction.
For annual data at the MSA level the use of recessionary dummy variables
while significant do not change the nature of the results and add little
to improve the explanatory power of the model.
To further verify that the results are robust each of the capital
market variables was regressed against the local variables including all
possible time lags of the local variables implied by equation 4. Each of
the local variables was then regressed against the capital market
variables and all possible time lags of the capital market variables
implied by equation 4. Using the resulting [R.sup.2] from the equations
a variance inflation factor was then calculated for each independent
variable. The results are shown in Table 4.
The VIF's are all close to one indicating that the model does
not have a significant amount of multi-colinearity between the local and
capital market variables.
CONCLUSION
This paper has presented evidence that there is a convergent cycle
in retail construction. The retail construction cycle may be obscured by
the effects of differing levels of growth in factors such as retail
sales and household formations within each MSA. After the effects of
varying growth rates and short term autocorrelation in the individual
MSA have been regressed out a distinct convergent cycle appears. The
cycle length estimated by this research is 8 years confirming the cycle
length observed by Scott and Judge (2000).
If the cyclical fluctuations observed are random it is unlikely
that the cycle would have remained consistent across 58 time series. If
the cycle observed were simply random behavior in the time series it is
more likely that with a sample size of 58 the cycle should average out
to a mean residual of zero by year. It has been shown that the residuals
are significantly different from zero by year.
Having determined that there is an underlying convergent cycle in
retail construction the cycle timing can be analyzed. The bottom of the
cycle is in the early 1980's and 1990's. This coincides with
the last two recessions in the US economy. The retail construction cycle
can be explained by capital markets, bank lending and interest rates.
The impact of the capital markets is incremental but has little
additional explanatory power for predicting retail construction at the
MSA level.
When predicting MSA level retail construction the local market
conditions are key to understanding retail construction. MSA level
retail sales changes, MSA level household formations, and MSA level
short-term trends in retail construction provide 98% of the explanatory
power in this analysis.
DATA APPENDIX
RS - Retail Supply - Gross Retail Construction. DRS - First
differences of retail supply. [DRS.sub.t] = [RS.sub.t] - [RS.sub.t-1]
CB - Commercial Balances - non-residential loan balances
outstanding for the United States and Other Areas as reported for
commercial banks by the FDIC.
ACB - Commercial Balances adjusted to 1996 dollars. [DACB.sub.t] =
[ACB.sub.t] - [DACB.sub.t-1]
PRIME - the prime interest rate as reported by the Federal Reserve
Board. [DPrime.sub.t] = [Prime.sub.t] - [Prime.sub.t-1]
HH - Households are the number of families in a MSA. DHH - Net
change in households each year within an MSA. [DHH.sub.t] = [HH.sub.t] -
[HH.sub.t-1]
Sales - Retail sales by MSA, by year, adjusted to 1996 dollars.
Dsales - First differences of sales. [Dsales.sub.t] = [Sales.sub.t] -
[Sales.sub.t-1]
REFERENCES
Ambrose, B. W. & Nourse, H. O. (1993). Factors influencing
capitalization rates, Journal of Real Estate Research, 8(2), 221-238.
Asea, P. K.& Blomberg, B. (1998). Lending cycles, Journal of
Econometrics, 83, 89-128
Bails, D. & Peppers, L. (1993). Business Fluctuations
Forecasting Techniques and Applications, (2nd Ed.). Englewood Cliffs,
NJ: Prentice Hall.
Benjamin, J. D., Jud G. D. & Winkler, D. T. (1998a). A
simultaneous model and empirical test of the demand and supply of retail
space, The Journal of Real Estate Research, 16(1), 1-13.
Benjamin, J. D., Jud G. D. & Winkler, D. T. (1998b). The supply
adjustment process in retail space markets, The Journal of Real Estate
Research, 15(3), 297-307.
Born, W. L., (1988). A real estate market research method to screen
areas for new construction potential, The Journal of Real Estate
Research, 3(3), 51-62.
Bowerman, B. & O'Connel,l R. (1987). Time Series
Forecasting Unified Concepts and Computer Implementation, Boston:
Duxbury Press.
Clapp, J. M., Pollakowski, H. O. & Lynford, L. (1992).
Intrametropolitan location and office market dynamics, Journal of the
American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 20(2), 229-258.
Dokko, Y., Edelstein, R. H., Lacayo, A.J. & Lee, D. C. (1999).
Real estate income and value cycles: A model of market dynamics, Journal
of Real Estate Research, 18(1), 69-95. Federal Reserve Board, (1997),
Bank Lending in the U.S., Economic Trends, Dec., 16.
Fuller, W. (1976). Introduction to Statistical Time Series, New
York: John Wiley & Sons.
Granger, C.W.J. & Newbold, P. (1977). Forecasting Economic Time
Series, New York: Academic Press Inc.
Grenadier, S. R. (1995). The persistence of real estate cycles,
Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 10(1), 95-119.
Henneberry, J. (1999). Convergence and difference in regional
office development cycles, Urban Studies, 36(9), 1439-1466.
Hudson-Wilson, S. & Pappadopoulos, G. (1999). CMBS and the real
estate cycle, Journal of Portfolio Management, 25(2), 105-112.
Hsiao, C. (1986). Analysis of Panel Data, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge
University Press.
Kulish, N. (2001). Economy: Banks are toughening lending rules,
Wall Street Journal, May 18, Sec A., 2.
Lawson, R. (1998). Area office, retail markets nearing top of
cycle, Nashville Business Journal, 14(15), 39-42.
Makridakis, S., Wheelwright, S. & Hyndman, R. (1998).
Forecasting Methods and Applications, (3rd Ed.), New York: John Wiley
& Sons.
Mendenhall, W. & Sincich, T. (1993). A Second Course in
Business Statistics: Regression Analysis, (4th Ed.), New York:
Macmillan.
Nugent, J. (2001). No surprise: Banks are tightening syndicated
loan standards, Bank Loan Report, Federal Reserve Board, March 5, 16(9),
4.
Reilly, F. (1985). Investment Analysis and Portfolio Management,
(2nd Ed.), Chicago: The Dryden Press, 336-337.
Ritter, J. (1995). An outsiders guide to real business cycle
modeling, Review (Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis), 77(2), 49-61.
Rosen, K. T. (1984). Toward a model of the office building sector,
Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association,
12(3), 261-270.
Scott, P. & Judge, G. (2000). Cycles and steps in British
commercial property values, Applied Economics, 32(10), 1287-1298.
Tsolacos, S. (1999). Retail building cycles: Evidence from Great
Britain, Journal of Real Estate Research, 18(1), 197-218.
Vandaele, W. (1983). Applied Time Series and Box-Jenkins Models,
New York: Academic Press Inc.
Wheaton, W. C. (1987). The cyclic behavior of the national office
market, The Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics
Association, 15(4), 281-299.
Steven Moss, Georgia Southern University
Darrell Parker, Georgia Southern University
Steve Laposa, PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP
Table 1: Descriptive Statistics
Variable Mean S.D. Min Max
RS 1,864.82 1,506.23 98.90 11,105.50
ACB 186.93 78.98 93.97 315.99
PRIME 9.42 3.16 5.25 18.87
HH 724.23 626.74 99.13 3,331.78
SALES 29,803.93 28,348.95 6,377.87 212,629.70
Table 2: Analysis of variance for the residuals from equation 2.
Source SOS DOF
INDIV 48658409.29 57
TIME 71027746.38 20
JOINT 119686155.68 77
ERROR 780955504.23 1140
TOTAL 900641659.92 1217
Source Mean Square F Sign. Level
INDIV 853656.3035 1.246 0.107
TIME 3551387.3194 5.184 0.000
JOINT 1554365.6583 2.269 0.000
ERROR 685048.6879
TOTAL
Table 3: Regression Results
Variable Coeff Std Error T-Stat Signif
Constant 146.867 53.068 2.767 0.005
DASALES{1} 0.032 0.016 2.021 0.043
DHHOLDS 11.549 4.585 2.519 0.012
DHHOLDS{1} 14.623 4.696 3.114 0.002
SUPPLY{1} 0.544 0.046 11.961 0.000
SUPPLY{2} 0.091 0.038 2.376 0.017
SUPPLY{6} 0.138 0.024 5.688 0.000
DACB 12.033 2.459 4.893 0.000
DACB{2} -7.889 1.980 -3.982 0.000
DPRIME{2} -56.847 13.175 -4.315 0.000
[R.sup.2] = 0.694
Table 4
Variable [R.sup.2] VIF
DACB .17 1.21
DPRIME .03 1.03
DHHOLDS .01 1.01
DASALES .24 1.31