Is the dollarization of Mexico warranted?
Leavell, Hadley ; Maniam, Balasundram ; Toombs, Leslie 等
ABSTRACT
The adoption of the dollar as the primary currency by a country is
termed dollarization. This paper examines some of the general qualities
that make a country a candidate for dollarization. Some of these
qualities include being a part of an optimum currency area, having high
inflation and devaluation, and having unstable prices. This paper then
goes on to specifically evaluate Mexico as a candidate, and the related
factors associated with dollarizing
Mexico. It was found that theoretically Mexico is an excellent
candidate for dollarization. However, due to complicated political and
social factors and the lack of long-term evidence in other countries,
dollarization is not yet warranted for Mexico.
INTRODUCTION
There has been a great debate regarding the implications of
countries adopting the U.S. dollar as their currency. Under
dollarization, a country would give up its control over its money supply
and its ability to conduct an independent monetary policy. In exchange,
the country would enjoy the stability and credibility of the dollar
(Salvatore, 2001). Dollarization, like any economic and financial
change, has its benefits and costs which are country-specific. The
implications of dollarization are extremely complex. Each country that
evaluates dollarization will be faced with a vast array of challenges.
Mexico has had a very volatile past in regards to its monetary position.
Recurrent devaluation has plagued Mexico's peso for the past three
decades (Garza, 1999). This in turn has been accompanied by severe price
instability. Mexican leaders are currently seeking a solution to this
problem. Dollarization is a possible solution, but it may lead to other
social, political, and economic complications. This paper will address
the criteria for dollarization, and its general implications. Then it
will address Mexico fit for dollarization. Next, the position of the
stakeholders will be addressed. Estimated benefits and costs associated
with Mexico's dollarization will be addressed. Next, opposing
viewpoints of Mexico's dollarization will be discussed. Finally, a
conclusion will be made as to whether dollarization is recommended for
Mexico.
LITERATURE REVIEW
The term dollarization refers to using U.S. dollars instead of
domestic currency as a unit of account, store of value, or medium of
exchange (Melvin & Peiers, 1996). It can also be viewed as the most
extreme form of a fixed exchange rate (Velde & Veracierto, 2000). In
its most basic form, dollarization occurs when a country willingly
replaces its own currency with that of the U.S. dollar. In the case of
Argentina, which has proposed to implement a full dollarization regime,
it eliminates of the Argentina peso and adopts the U.S. dollar in all
day-to-day Argentine transactions (Spiegel, 1999). Not only is the
currency replaced, the adopting country must also relinquish its control
over its own monetary policy and eliminate primary functions of its
central bank. Lastly, it can no longer print its own currency and cannot
function as a lender of last resort.
The various forms of dollarization can be explained by the
following three general categories obtained from the U.S. Senate Joint
Economic Committee, 2000 (Hansen, 2000):
1. Unofficial Dollarization which generally means that at least 30%
of a country's money supply is in U.S. dollars. These countries
include most of Latin American and the Caribbean, especially
Argentina, Bolivia, Mexico, Peru and Central America; most of
the former Soviet Union; and various other countries including
Mongolia, Romania, Turkey, and Vietnam.
2. Semiofficial Dollarization, countries identified by the
International Monetary Fund (IMF) who are using U.S. dollars as
another legal tender in addition to their own domestic currency.
In these countries, the U.S. dollar is widely circulated but
plays a secondary legal role to the home currency. Countries in
this category include the Bahamas, Cambodia, Haiti, Laos, and
Liberia.
3. Official Dollarization which is full dollarization. This group
of countries includes Guam, Marshall Islands, Virgin Islands,
East Timor, Samoa, Turks, Puerto Rico, Panama, and Ecuador.
The adoption process of dollarization can either be accomplished
unilaterally, whereby a foreign country adopts the U.S. dollar with no
support and/or cooperation from the U.S., or bilaterally, which involves
forming an official monetary agreement / association with the U.S.
(Velde & Veracierto, 2000). An additional type of dollarization,
referred to as a multilateral agreement would involve creating an accord
between several countries and the U.S. In addition, the citizens of a
given country can also bring about dollarization with or without the
help of their government. This can be done through de facto dollarization, where citizens make an individual choice to swap their
home currency for the U.S. dollars, or by de jure dollarization, which
requires the citizens in a country to utilize their political process to
effect a smooth and coordinated currency substitution toward the dollar
(Taylor, 2000). De jure dollarization may be a preferred method in
adopting dollarization since this would allow the government of the
foreign country to make changes to their monetary and fiscal policies in
conjunction with the conversion process to facilitate a coordinated
transformation. However, for a country that wants some of the benefits
of dollarization without having to openly commit to it, de facto
dollarization may actually be preferred by a government. Since this form
of dollarization is subject to the will of the people and lacks
government interaction, it can actual exacerbate a troubled economy if
the populace perceives things are going to get worse before getting
better.
For a country to consider dollarization, several criteria should be
met. The country should be an optimum currency area. It should be
unstable fiscally, and have a record of financial volatility. The
country should also have the bulk of its trade with the U.S. The country
should be socially and politically willing to change. The citizens of
the country must also accept the replacement of the local currency with
the dollar. These criteria must be intensively investigated before
dollarization is implemented (Salvatore, 2001).
The theory of optimum currency areas (OCA) is a useful tool in
determining the feasibility of dollarization. "An OCA is a region
for which it is optimal to have a single monetary policy and a single
currency" (Dellas, 2001). There are two main ways in which to
assess the appropriateness of countries forming an OCA. One is on the
conditions that warrant a country's adoption of another
country's currency, and the other is by the costs and benefits of
forming an OCA (Dellas, 2001).
DO THE U.S. AND MEXICO FIT THE OCA CRITERIA?
There are a number of conditions that must be compared to evaluate
a successful OCA. There should be a high degree of fiscal integration.
High levels of fiscal integration tend to smooth out the shocks of
fiscal transfers between high unemployment regions to low unemployment
regions. Integration is very highly related when evaluating the border
of Mexico. However, when viewed as a whole, Mexico is significantly
under-employed, and therefore will not correlate with the U.S. Also
highly diversified economies are typically better candidates for OCA
than less diversified economies. The diversification acts as a buffer to
the myriad of shocks in a complex global economy. This buffer action
helps to limit the need for excessive changes in the terms of trade. The
U.S. is highly industrially diversified across the nation; Mexico is
not.
Trade integration is an important part of being deemed an OCA. With
the advent of NAFTA, Mexico and the U.S. increased their trade
integration along the border. This should translate into lower costs to
dollarize. With a very open economy, the two countries will limit their
exchange rate risks.
With two countries with parallel production structures, symmetric
trade shocks will also parallel. Exchange rates cannot then fluctuate to
help ameliorate the effects of economic shocks. Therefore, the two
countries would fit that OCA criterion. However, Mexico and the U.S. are
dissimilar in their production structures--other than along the border.
With dissimilar structures, dollarization would not provide Mexico with
any flexibility during economic shocks.
The benefits of the OCA for Mexico and the U.S. can also be linked
to the credibility hypothesis. This hypothesis focuses on the use of a
common currency as an anchor to discipline policy makers and private
enterprises. In effect, the exchange rate equals a fixed rate when using
a common currency. Dollarization would permit policy makers in Mexico
and the U.S. to focus on problems other than monetary policy in their
economies. This should lead to a more stable and productive environment
for Mexico.
For dollarization to succeed in Mexico it must facilitate fiscal
and financial stability and economic reform. This reform would then lead
to a more balanced budget and stability in the banking industry for
Mexico. Mexico would consider dollarization because of past serious
economic problems. Otherwise the costs associated with dollarization
could outweigh the benefits.
Mexico has been faced with an ill banking system making it a
candidate for dollarization. By dollarizing, Mexico's central bank
may not be as likely to lend in last resort due to additional
constraints. The financial safety net would tighten thereby
precipitating more prudent banking decisions. This would help reduce the
potential for moral hazard in the banking industry.
Dollarization should also enhance Mexico's financial stability
by promoting the growth of domestic financial markets. Mexico's
current weak financial standing forces it to have to borrow from foreign
banks. Their assets, on the other hand, are in pesos. When faced with
depreciating peso currency, the banks and firms are hurt. This
contributes to an even weaker financial position, and the cycle
continues. Dollarization would combat this problem because the
bank's and the firm's assets would both be in dollars
(Eichengreen, 2001).
According to Eichengreen (2001), dollarization is most effective
for countries whose fiscal policy is controlled centrally. Dollarization
would lead to a relative consolidation of public finances which should
lead to fiscal reform for Mexico. Dollarization would eliminate
excessive inflation and interest rates which have been so problematic
for Mexico in recent years. The interest rates would stabilize at U.S.
levels, thereby reducing costs of debt.
Salvatore (2001) delineates that a dollarizing country should have
very close ties to the U.S. He claims that trade between the two
countries should represent a significant proportion of the dollarizing
country's Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Since the U.S. is the
largest importer of Mexican products, the close ties are apparent. This
should ensure that the maximum benefits can be attained through
dollarization. Otherwise, Mexico would not want to give up its control
over its monetary policy if it was not going to receive substantial
benefits for doing so.
In addition, both countries must be politically and socially
accepting to the idea of dollarization. In effect, de facto
dollarization may occur if Mexico continues to use the dollar
domestically. It literally may only take one side, the government or
society, to make dollarization occur. (Pruitt, 1998). For example, if
firms in a country demand dollars for their goods and services they are
essentially dollarizing the country, albeit, through a very slow
process. Similarly, small businesses may also demand dollars from the
citizens. It may not be long before the national pride of having the
peso as a sovereign currency will be eroded away by necessity of the
dollar.
PROPONENTS OF DOLLARIZATION
Mexico, with two main exceptions, fits the mold of what many
economists consider as an appropriate candidate for dollarization. The
exceptions to this fit are the size of Mexico and its deeply rooted
economic past. Mexico and U.S. would be considered by many to be an OCA
by definition. The two countries share a high degree of economic
diversification. This diversification would help to buffer the
transitional shocks of implementation. Mexico and the U.S. are also
highly trade-integrated. The more integrated two countries are, the
smaller the transition costs when a single currency is adopted.
Mexico and the U.S. have a very open trade agreement. This openness
spawns frequent exchange rate adjustments. These exchange rate
adjustments result in price instability which then calls for a common
currency
Mexico experienced four maxi-devaluation periods from 1976 to 1998,
which have been followed by massive price instability. In 1995, Mexico
experienced a 637% increase in the price level. This was joined by a
year-to-year inflation of 7% to 52% (Prepared..., 2000). Mexico has been
historically unstable financially, fiscally, and politically, thereby
making Mexico a textbook example of a candidate for dollarization.
Mexico is deemed ready for dollarization by many economists,
business leaders, and financial experts. Leading Mexican business
associations, like Business Coordinating Council, the National Chamber
of the Manufacturing Industry, and the Mexican Employers Confederation
are in support of a dollar-based economy (Crane, 1999). Many of these
groups have lost their confidence in the central banks' ability to
keep Mexico out of crisis. The American Chamber/Mexico conducted a
survey in 1999 and a small majority 58 percent out of 48 U.S. and
Mexican companies operation in Mexico) were in favor of dollarizing the
Mexican economy (Crane, 1999).
Mexico's high inflation rate fueled a significant level of
price instability. Inflation is the result of both a monetary and an
exchange rate problem in Mexico. Dollarization would help end inflation
and devaluation. It would also allow the price level to fall to the U.S.
level. This could persuade more investors to look to Mexico for
investment opportunities. The CCE states with regards to Mexico that
"to adopt a strong foreign currency as legal tender stops the
problem of recurrent instability, diminishes country risk, and lessens
the cost of capital, and eliminates many of the transaction costs."
(Crane, 1999).
The importance of the dollar to Mexican business interests has
never been stronger. There are many companies that already adopted the
dollar for payment of their invoices. The dollar is extensively used,
especially in the border-states, for the sale of luxury items,
computers, office equipment, trucks and furniture. Capital investments
have also been demanded to be in dollars (Garza, 1999). Therefore, de
facto dollarization is already occurring.
OPPONENTS OF DOLLARIZATION FOR MEXICO
The outcome for officially dollarizing Mexico would seem to have
many positives, but those are primarily speculations. Mexico has a
relatively large economy when compared to Panama or Ecuador, two of the
other nations that have dollarized. Dollarization has not been a
clear-cut success for them and it is still too early to conclude the end
results.
Opponents to dollarization have made some strong points. One
opponent claims that dollarization is a false solution that only
addresses the symptoms and not the root cause of the problems (Puertas,
2000). It is also postulated that many Mexicans fear that converting to
dollars will surrender Mexico's control over its monetary policy,
thus, putting itself at the mercy of the U.S. and the Federal Reserve
(Garza, 1999). Historically, Mexico's monetary policy has been very
volatile; however, there is no evidence that the Mexican government
would be willing to surrender monetary decision making policy to the
U.S. A Mexico more optimistic about a more stable future could find its
leaders preferring to rely on supply and demand to determine the
currency exchange rate.
Floating exchange rates have two advantages over dollarization: (1)
Exchange rates can depreciate (appreciate) and act as the classical
"shock absorber" for an economy and (2) What is considered
appropriate policy for the U.S. might not be good for other countries.
When a country undertakes a pegged exchange rate, it is only promising a
conditional action and not an unconditional guarantee of staying with
the peg. Thus, governments are not prevented from backing out of the
pegged rate nor does the pegged rate prevent the exchange rate from
collapsing (Sachs, 1999). A unilateral monetary policy by Mexico would
have no formal treaty relationship between the two countries and be
predicated on the convenience of Mexico (von Furstberg, 2000). Except
along the border, Mexico's economy is relatively inflexible and
still commodity dependent. Any policy to preserve the pegged exchange
rate by contracting the economy would probably result in costly high
unemployment and falling domestic output. Any real devaluation would be
achieved via a fall in nominal wages and prices, aggrevating any
economic recession.
The Fed (U.S.) could not be expected to open its discount window to
Mexico's banks to assist in difficult times. Additionally, U.S.
politicians would be expected to be most concerned with domestic issues
over international issues as these would be the issues at election time
(Falcoff, 1999). Mexico also needs to consider that it is at a different
economic and fiscal development point than the U.S. This difference in
the productivity growth rate can be best accommodated by changes in
relative prices (Mann, 1999).
Berg and Borenzstein (2000) postulate the debate is no longer
centered on inflation stabilization as this problem has abated over the
1990's. Today the problems are the degree of capital mobility and
scale of capital flows as well as the apparent frequency and severity of
currency crises.
Dollarization supporters rarely address the needed policies that
must accompany dollarization to make it feasible and effective. Often,
potential costs to both the dollarizing country, in this case Mexico,
and to the U.S. are overlooked.
CONCLUSION
Most people would agree that Mexico needs economic reform. Mexico
has had a history of inflation, unstable prices, and devaluation. One
possible solution to these problems is dollarization. Mexico has many of
the characteristics necessary for dollarization. Mexico and the U.S. can
already be considered an OCA, a precursor to dollarization. Certainly
Mexico's historically unstable financial status would theoretically
benefit from the conversion to the stable dollar.
Dollarization would hypothetically benefit Mexico's current
state. It should help halt inflation, devaluation, and help set stable
prices. This should in turn, result in economic growth and prosperity.
However, there is no substantive proof that these outcomes will
occur. Evidence from past dollarizers, such as Panama and Ecuador, do
not support the claims made by proponents of dollarization. At this
time, dollarization would not benefit either the U.S. or Mexico. The
added knowledge from evaluating the results of other nations will allow
both Mexican and U.S. stakeholders to re-visit this issue in the near
future.
REFERENCES
Berg, A. & E. Birensztein. (2000). The dollarization debate.
Finance & Development. 37(1), March.
Crane, A. T. (1999). Top dollar. American Chamber of Commerce of
Mexico Business Mexico. May 1, 1999.
Dellas, H. & Tavlas, G. (2001). Lessons of the euro for
dollarization. Journal of Policy Modeling. 23(3), April, 333-335.
Edwards, S. (2001). Dollarization-Myth and realities. Journal of
Policy Modeling. 23(3). April, 249-265.
Eichengreen, B. (2001). What problems can dollarization solve?
Journal of Policy Modeling. 23(3), April, 267-277.
Falcoff, M. (1999). Dollarization for Argentina? For Latin America?
Latin American Outlook. April.
Garza, A. (1999). Mexican business men, President at odds over
dollarization. The Associated Press. March 13.
Hansen, F. (2000, November/December). The rise of regional
currencies. Business Credit, 102(10), 36-40. Retrieved from EBSCO database.
Mann, C. L. Dollarization as diet. Statement Before the Joint
Hearing of the Subcommittee on Economic Development and the Subcommittee
on International Trade and Finance Committee on Banking, Housing, and
Urban Affairs, United States Senate. April 22, 1999.
Melvin, M. & Peiers, B. (1996, July). Dollarization in
developing countries: Rational remedy or domestic dilemma? Contemporary
Economic Policy, 14(3), 30-41. Retrieved from EBSCO Database.
Prepared Testimony of Dr. Roberto Salianas-Leon Executive Director
of Policy Analysis TV Aztec. Federal News Services, Inc. June 22, 2000
Pruitt, S. (1998). Dollarization debate: Sovereignty vs. stability.
Novedades Editores, S.S. De C.V. 1998 InfoLatinoa S.A. de C.V.
Puertas, J. A. (2000). Latin American policy makers consider
benefits of making dollar their own. Agency France Press. March 7, 2000.
Sachs, J. (1999). Why dollarization is more straight jacket than
salvation. Foreign Policy. Fall.
Salvatore, D. (2001). Dollarization for the Americas? Journal of
Policy Modeling. 23(3). April, 237-239.
Spiegel, M. (1999, September 24). Dollarization in Argentina.
Federal Reserve Board of San Francisco Economic Letter, 99(29), 1-3.
Retrieved from EBSCO database.
Taylor, A. (2000, May 19). Dollarization as a technology import.
Federal Reserve Board of San Francisco Economic Letter, 2000(16), 1-3.
Retrieved from EBSCO database.
Velde, F. & Veracierto, M. (2000). Dollarization in Argentina.
Economic Perspectives, 1st Quarter, 24-38. Retrieved from EBSCO
database.
Von Furstenberg, G. (2000). A case against U.S. dollarization.
Challenge. July.
Hadley Leavell, Sam Houston State University
Balasundram Maniam, Sam Houston State University
Leslie Toombs, Rockhurst University
Louis Kuhn, Sam Houston State University