Determining ownership positions in acquisitions: market and strategic influences on investments in European targets.
Francis, John D.
ABSTRACT
Ownership positions taken in international acquisitions are based
on developing efficient organizational arrangements for the purpose of
integrating and coordinating activities between the target and the
acquirer. This process is influenced by factors within market contexts
and by the strategic repertoires of the acquiring firm as they face the
complexity of foreign markets.
Regression is used to model these factors influencing the ownership
positions of U.S. firms in the acquisition of targets within European
Union nations. Results indicate that strategic similarity and to lesser
degree market uncertainty influence ownership and that these results
differ depending on the cultural proximity.
INTRODUCTION
Merger and acquisition activity has risen dramatically as an
internationalization strategy and as a means to establish an immediate
foreign presence. Of particular importance in an acquisition is the
ability to effectively combine resources and coordinate activities
through the use of power and control, where power is one member's
potential to influence the decision variables of its partner and align inter-firm resources (Griffith & Harvey, 2001). In recent years
researchers have focused on the determinants of power and the control
issues implied by various internationalization strategies (Davidson
& McFetridge, 1984, 1985; Davis, Desai & Francis, 1999;
Contractor, 1990; Erramilli, 1991; Argarwal & Ramaswami, 1992;
Anderson & Gatignon, 1986). While this attention has been helpful in
determining why various organizational arrangements have been used, its
application to merger and acquisition activity has been somewhat
simplistic. Much of the internationalization literature presents
acquisitions as if targets are always fully acquired in order to
classify this organizational arrangement as one that affords a high
degree of control to the parent (Caves & Mehra, 1986; Kogut &
Singh, 1989).
In reality, international mergers and acquisitions involve various
organizational arrangements ranging from minority owned to wholly owned
positions, each involving tradeoffs between the extent of control
afforded, the amount of risk exposure, and the level of resource
commitments required. Ownership choices in acquisitions are the first in
a sequence of strategic steps aimed at effectively combining resources
and coordinating activities in global relationships based on the power
created from the investment position taken.
Transaction costs arguments suggest that ownership positions are
predicated upon economic arrangements aimed at achieving competitive
efficiencies across national boundaries. As each transaction involves an
acquiring firm and target from different markets and firm orientations,
aspects of each are expected to influence the ownership position taken
as firms attempt to maximize efficiency and reduce transaction costs.
For international acquisitions, ownership positions must also be
examined in relationship to the specific context of crossing national
boundaries. Economic efficiency is predicated on the strategic
allocation of acquisition ownership based on effectively combining
resources and coordinating the activities of international
relationships. In international acquisitions, this process involves
overcoming potentially difficult national differences that lead to
greater transaction costs. These differences alter the strength of
industry and firm influences as acquiring firms seek to enter markets
very different from their own.
In order to understand this aspect of international acquisitions,
the paper addresses these issues and examines the degree of ownership an
acquiring firm purchases by juxtaposing elements at two levels of
analysis: those at the market and firm. The research addresses four key,
related issues:
What impact do industry characteristics have on the degree of
ownership of an international target firm?
What impact do strategic pre-dispositions have on the degree of
ownership of an international target?
Are these different sets of determinants complimentary in their
impact on the degree of ownership in international acquisitions?
Do the effects of these determinants differ between national
environments?
THEORY AND HYPOTHESES
Owning a large percentage of an international acquisition versus
holding a smaller position is important as it involves distinct
differences in the commitment of resources by the acquiring firm, as
well as the level of control desired in global operations. The choice of
ownership level is complicated further when the acquisition involves
crossing national boundaries. In order to achieve and maintain control,
multinational firms face several complexities not encountered by
domestic firms such as communication barriers, difficulties in the
evaluation of performance due to exchange rate shifts, and cultural
differences between headquarters and subsidiaries (Mascarenhas, 1992).
In the decision to acquire a target firm, a higher degree of ownership
provides greater control and power for the parent firm as it organizes
its activities. In this way, an acquiring firm increases its decision
making authority and monitoring power.
From a transactions cost perspective, the decision regarding the
degree of ownership in an international acquisition involves reducing
inefficiencies taking place between firms in two markets. At its basis,
transactions cost theory argues that the primary purpose of an
organization is economizing, to make organizations "efficient"
rather than wasteful (Williamson, 1985). Transaction costs focus on
administrative issues like "make or buy" decisions, aspects of
organization design and structure, and management of administrative and
transaction costs. Therefore, it is particularly applicable merger and
acquisition activity as it primarily focuses on the necessity of finding
an optimal solution to achieve efficiency in the investment and
administration of target firm assets within the network of a
multinational firm.
Organizing investments in foreign markets have a high degree
complexity and uncertainty for an internationalizing firm. Acquiring
firms face unclear cultural expectations regarding marketing and human
resource practices, inexperience in business negotiations, information
about local partners, and the need to integrate the target firm into its
current organizational structure and culture. Human actors make
decisions in this process with limited knowledge and bounded
rationality. They are also mindful of opportunism that can take place
within the exchange between parties when there is no structured,
organizing arrangement. Therefore, as acquisitive firms seek targets,
they make adaptive, and sequential decisions regarding the structure of
the acquisition relationship in order to shield the organization from
opportunistic behavior while creating the most efficient, economizing
arrangement. Each ownership choice is predicated on the attempt to
eliminate or reduce the perceived transactions cost that arise from the
risk and uncertainty involved in acquiring and integrating an
international target.
Transaction costs have long been acknowledged as influenced by the
market contexts that exchanges take place in. Market based assets and
structures have been demonstrated to impact organizational arrangements
that develop global integration and maximize efficiencies (Kale, 1986;
Inkpen & Beamish, 1997), particularly the environmental
characteristics that create excess costs related to overcoming risk and
uncertainty. Dynamic market contexts are sources of ambiguity and
complexity as attributes multiply and change. This dynamism is related
to technological development, unclear customer demands, changing
infrastructure requirements and standards, and most uncertain of all the
competitive nature of the industry environment. Markets differ in terms
of their levels of instability and complexity and therefore, require
organizational arrangements that are particularly suited for them. For
cross border actions, firms seek to reduce the costs associated with
dynamic environments while integrating the resources of international
operations.
An important aspect of industry dynamism is the extent of
technological development occurring within a given market. New
technologies alter industries structures by making existing products
outdated or manufacturing processes obsolete. Technological development
within industry, due to its transitory and destructive nature, is cited
as a primary driver of a firm's strategy and structure (Chan,
Martin, & Kensinger, 1990; Child, 1972).
Acquisitions are a preferred method for firms to modify or update
their technology, as evidenced by the large amount of merger and
acquisition activity in high-tech markets. However, competing
considerations are involved in determining the initial ownership
position taken by an acquiring firm. Typically, members participating in
high-tech industries create competitive advantage through technological
competencies. These firms invest time and resources into developing
these technologies and want to fully realize their rent producing
returns. It is likely that they are reluctant to share knowledge with
rival firms (Anderson & Gatignon, 1986) or expose themselves to the
opportunism that might arise through partnerships.
However, firms in high technology industries also need to
collaborate in order to benefit from exposure to other knowledge
resources and to offset the large initial costs of new product and
technology development. As Kogut and Singh (1989) argue, foreign
expansion in high technology industries most likely requires investment
in research and development and product adaptation, creating an
incentive for firms to pool competencies and overcome risk and cost.
Therefore, firms must decide upon organizational arrangements that
reduce the opportunism that may arise through collaboration, while at
the same time lowering the expense involved in research and development.
Acquisitions with lower levels of ownership appear to be an effective
means of lowering both transactions costs that might arise through
opportunism while at the same time lowering the costs of research and
development. Supporting studies indicate that sharing ownership when it
comes to joint ventures is highly preferred in high tech environments
(Gomes-Casseres, 1989; Hennart, 1991; Kogut & Singh, 1988, 1989;
Yip, 1982). As such, we expect that acquiring firms would invest as
minority owners in high technology industries without making extensive
resource commitments that comes with purchasing high degrees of
ownership. Based on this discussion the following hypothesis is offered:
Hypothesis 1: The level of ownership of international acquisitions
will be negatively associated with the level of technological
development of an industry.
Another market attribute impacting uncertainty that can lead to
transaction costs concerns the rate of growth of the target markets.
Increased customer demand, changing industry strategies and standards,
and increased competitive rivalry are all conditions of these markets.
Rapid growth in international markets reduces entry barriers by creating
disequilibrium conditions that encourage diversification and market
entry. These types of markets are primary locations for acquisition
activity. However, they generate, at any point in time, inconsistencies
concerning competitive requirements, institutions and customers, as well
as uncertainty over future changes. For international firms, these
inconsistencies are further complicated as they apply to cross-border
activities. Businesses operating in these markets typically face high
transactions costs as they lack knowledge and information that can
reduce uncertainty, while accepting their potential accessibility and
attractiveness.
Firms taking advantage of growth opportunities in these markets
through acquisitions seek to efficiently allocate investments. They want
to add value to the firm, while improving their operations and
resources. To most efficiently optimize their investments into growing,
transitory markets, we expect acquiring firms to purchase larger degrees
of ownership. This enables an acquiring firm to not only tap into the
investment returns in these attractive markets, but also take control of
the target in regards to future strategies and opportunities and achieve
synergies with existing operations. Given rapid market growth, higher
ownership and control reduce future uncertainty for the acquiring firm.
Based on this argument the following argument is offered:
Hypothesis 2: The level of ownership of international acquisitions
will be positively associated with the degree of industry growth rates.
A third industry factor influencing ownership positions in
acquisitions concerns the level of concentration of market power by
industry rivals. Industries low in concentration are fragmented by a
large number of firms, many privately held and none with a substantial
share of total industry sales (Porter, 1985). The primary attribute of a
fragmented industry is the absence of market leaders mainly due to a
lack of economies of scale, low entry and exit barriers, changing value
chain technologies, diverse market demands, and the presence of new
products or participants. These industries are typified by changing
products, technologies, and customer demands leading to a highly
uncertain market environment.
Alternatively, highly concentrated industries contain a small
number of firms and are characterized by economies of scale and market
power while displaying conditions of oligopolistic interdependence.
Typically, due to the size and strength of industry participants, these
industries are global in nature with firms coordinating and controlling
extensive operations across multiple foreign markets. These firms have
built large hierarchies over time to eliminate or reduce transaction
costs by internalizing transactions. For participating firms in these
industries, it likely that acquisitions will be integrated as fully as
possible into the organizational hierarchy through increased ownership
positions. Small firms in fragmented industries have not developed the
global infrastructure to internalize transaction costs. They do not rely
on global coordination and scale to achieve organizational efficiency
and will therefore, not be as likely to purchase large degrees of
ownership as they expand abroad. Based on this discussion the following
hypothesis is offered:
Hypothesis 3: The level of ownership of international acquisitions
will be positively associated with the degree of industry concentration.
While environmental factors do affect strategic choices, a richer
perspective views acquisitions as strategic actions that allow firms to
modify their competencies and enhance their value as they keep pace with
change in the environment (Bowman & Singh, 1990, 1993; Kogut &
Zander, 1996; Oliver, 1997). International acquisitions are the result
of corporate strategies aimed at applying a successful corporate theme
(Porter, 1987). From an economic standpoint, a strategic action is more
likely to be efficient and create value when it deploys assets utilizing
similar key success factors and value-creating opportunities (Capron,
Mitchell, & Swaminathan, 2001). Employing similar or consistent
strategies throughout a network of international operations is more
efficient and leads to synergies throughout the organization.
Strategic similarity at the corporate level can be found in the
pre-existing repertoires of the acquiring firm in its pattern of
diversification and allocation of resources throughout its business
units. Firms invoking strategic similarity develop related competencies
and resources in an attempt to exploit or realize the potential
economies and synergies that large size and related diversification can
offer.
A type of strategic similarity employed by organizations involves
how resources are deployed, namely, investments in research and
development (R&D) and marketing across the firm's different
businesses. Corporate resources are distributed either evenly or
unevenly across different business units based on what yields higher
returns or to develop and enhance a common set of competencies. To
measure strategic similarity, the emphasis is not on why a certain
allocation is made or the intensity of the allocation, but on how
similar or dissimilar the allocations are across the corporation.
Similar resource allocations across multiple business units signal
involvement in industries that require competitive advantages based on
common tactics or they signal an attempt on the part of top management
to manage multiple lines of business based on a singular dominant logic
(Harrison, Hall, & Nargundkar, 1993). The similarity of resource
allocations is evidence that the corporation is emphasizing
organizational processes that require a firm to maintain similar
strategies throughout its network of business units. This consistency
signals the presence of high control processes at work throughout the
corporation and results in a tendency to replicate existing
organizational features or strategies, especially as firms invest abroad
(Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991).
R&D and advertising allocations are of particular importance as
they determine a firm's emphasis on innovation or marketing for its
competitive advantage. Outlays in these areas are expected to affect a
firm's cash flow from both its existing assets and its future
investments. If business units do not share a corporate emphasis on
innovation or marketing with their siblings, then there is no consistent
corporate strategic emphasis in these areas, indicating the use of
different strategic approaches for each business unit.
Business units with similar resource patterns indicate high levels
of internal consistency and control which in turn increase the ability
of the corporation to implement strategies and coordinate activities
(Anderson & Gatignon, 1986). Firms with a corporate strategy of
allocations of similar intensity across their business units and their
resulting benefits will want to continue this pattern in international
acquisitions. Only high ownership positions allow the control necessary
for these types of resources. Alternatively, when low levels of
ownership are purchased, target firms continue to possess the autonomy
necessary to adopt resource deployment patterns unaffected by the norms
of other organizational units within the acquiring firm. Based on these
arguments the following hypotheses are offered:
Hypothesis 4: The level of ownership of international acquisitions
will be positively associated with the similarity of R&D allocations
across acquiring firms' business units.
Hypothesis 5: The level of ownership of international acquisitions
will be positively associated with the similarity of advertising
allocations across acquiring firms' business units.
Strategic similarity also facilitates the integration of the target
to the acquirer from both a technical and organizational perspective
(Ahuja & Katila, 1998; Haspeslagh & Jemison, 1991; Singh &
Zollo, 1997). The absorptive capacity argument maintains that the
ability to use resources of acquired firms increases when the target
firm is related to the firm's existing resources (Cohen &
Levinthal, 1990). Acquisitions of firms with similar strategic
characteristics such as competition or similar products result in higher
scale efficiencies and lower transaction costs than acquisitions
involving strategically dissimilar firms (Ramaswamy, 1997).
Therefore, the relatedness of the acquiring firm to the target firm
is an extension of existing capabilities in order for the firm to
achieve the tangible and intangible benefits of product similarities. In
this case, higher degrees of ownership would be more appropriate for
firms acquiring related target firms by reducing transaction costs and
creating an optimal organizational arrangement. However, if the target
firm is not related, then less ownership will be preferred due to the
lack of synergies to be exploited and an increased level of uncertainty
due to entering a new market. Therefore, the following hypothesis is
offered:
Hypothesis 6: The level of ownership of international acquisitions
will be positively associated with the relatedness of the acquiring firm
to the target firm.
Strategic similarity creates a shared understanding that
facilitates acquisition resource deployment between the target and the
acquirer, while dissimilarity reduces the party's contextual
knowledge (Capron et al., 2001). Shared understanding arises from common
knowledge and industry experiences (Huff, 1982), common repertoires of
strategies (Spender, 1987), and common collective cognitive models and
beliefs (Porac, Thomas, Wilson, Paton, & Kanfer, 1995). To this
point, the study has argued that these variables are specifically
germane to firms crossing national boundaries due to the high level of
uncertainty in these environments and the desire for investing firms to
reduce transaction costs that arise.
However, international markets differ in the amount of uncertainty
and complexity they create for the investing firm. These differences can
be found in the distance culturally and economically from an entering
firm's home market. In acquisitions, as these differences increase,
the dissimilarities between the target and the acquiring firm become
greater. In predicting the control an organization is likely to maintain
over foreign operations, theorists associate higher distance with higher
transaction costs due to information costs and the difficulty of
transferring resources (Buckley & Casson, 1976; Vachani, 1991).
Dess, Gupta, Hennart, & Hill (1995) suggest that high degrees of
geographic diversification create unwanted transactions cost due to the
degree of differences between cultures and nations.
A key component of transaction costs theory is that human agents
involved in decision-making are characterized by bounded rationality.
The implication of the assumption of bounded rationality is that
individuals are limited in knowledge, foresight, skill, and time,
exchanges will be characterized by adaptive, and sequential
decision-making, and trading requires the support of safeguards to
shield organizations from opportunistic behavior (Williamson, 1985).
Therefore, as the uncertainty associated with greater market distance
rises, factors influencing higher levels of control become more
important as firms look to create economically efficient organizational
arrangements. A reduced understanding of the target's home country
by the acquiring firm increases the reliance on common market
expectations and strategic repertoires as firms look to make sense of
the complexities and intricacies of foreign environments. Therefore, it
is expected that the hypothesized relationships described earlier would
intensify as market distance increases. In the context of this study,
market distance is lower for target countries closer to the United
States. Based on this discussion the following hypotheses are offered:
Hypothesis 8: The association between industry factors and higher
degrees of ownership will be stronger in markets with higher distance
proximity.
Hypothesis 9: The association between firm factors and higher
degrees of ownership will be stronger in markets with higher distance
proximity.
METHODOLOGY
The source of the sample for this study is the Mergers and
Acquisitions roster. Acquisitions included in the sample met the
following restrictions:
1. U.S. firms acquiring target firms headquartered in the European
Union.
2. Acquisitions between January 1,1993 and December 31, 1997.
3. Acquisitions involving the purchase of a target firm as opposed
to purchases of assets such as property plant and equipment.
4. Transactions reporting the degree of ownership exceeding ten
percent.
5. New transactions of acquisitions as opposed to additional share
purchases.
6. Acquisitions by publicly traded U.S. firms.
Measurement of Variables
Degree of ownership is measured using the percentage of ownership
purchased reported in Mergers and Acquisitions roster. The measurement
of an industry's technological development follows Chan et. al.
(1990) by utilizing Business Week's annual R&D scorecard for
the year prior to the acquisition. Industries are classified as high,
medium or low in technological development and treated as an interval
variable. Industry growth rate is measured within the target firm's
international industry located in its home country. The data for this
variable is obtained from the Eurostat database. The measure captures
the percentage change in industry revenues three years prior to the
acquisition.
Industry concentration is obtained using the four-firm
concentration ratio, a common method for operationalizing the variable
(Caves & Mehra, 1986; Chatterjee, 1992). Data is taken for the year
of the acquisition from the Census of Manufacturers. The arithmetic
average of the concentration ratio is used for acquiring firms active in
multiple industries following the method used by Hennart (1991).
The relatedness of the acquiring firm to the target firm is
obtained using similarities between 3 digit SIC industries of the target
firm and the acquiring firm. If the target belongs to a similar
three-digit SIC then it is treated as related; targets belonging to
different SIC industry groups are defined as unrelated. This independent
variable is tested using a dummy variable. In order to measure the
similarity or dispersions in resource allocations across businesses, the
study follows Harrison and colleagues (1993) by examining the variance
of the intensity of R&D and advertising across each business unit
segment of the corporation. Data for these variables are collected from
the COMPUSTAT database and annual reports. Acquiring firm size in terms
of revenues and prior internationalization are controlled for in the
analytical tests.
DATA ANALYSIS AND RESULTS
As the model includes a set of both market and firm strategy
variables, hierarchical set regression is used to ascertain the
increment in the proportion of variance accounted for by each set and to
support the individual hypotheses (Pedhazur, 1982). The Mergers and
Acquisition roster reveals in excess of 3,000 mergers and acquisitions
of EU targets by U.S. firms during the sample time period. Of these, 948
include some description of the degree of ownership. Upon application of
the study requirements, the final sample includes 311 acquisitions.
Comparisons on average acquisition price, target firm location, and
target firm industry membership indicate that the sample of 311
acquisitions is representative of the larger sample.
Table 1 presents the correlation matrix of the variables in the
research model and indicates the strength and significance of the
bi-variate associations between each of them. The table reveals several
expected or likely associations
The correlation matrix indicates that several variables (AFINTL,
TFREL, INTINDGR, and INDCONC) have significant bi-variate associations
with degree of ownership (OWN%).
Hierarchical set regression is used to test the research model and
the results are indicated in Table 2. Model 1 in Table 2 includes only
the control variables and indicates that the extent of prior
internationalization (AFINTL) of the acquiring firm shows a negative
significant relationship to degree of ownership.
The second model in Table 2 regresses both the control variables
and market variables on the degree of ownership. Hypotheses one, two,
and three develop the relationships concerning the influence of market
characteristics (level of technological development, international
industry growth rates and level of concentration) on the degree of
ownership in acquisitions. As this model indicates, support is found for
Hypotheses 2 and 3. Both the growth rate of the international
target's industry and industry concentration have significant
positive relationships with the dependent variable. Higher growth in the
target firm's market and higher industry concentration lead to a
higher degree of ownership being purchased. The overall adjusted R2 is
significant, explaining 8.6% of the variance of the dependent variable.
The third model is calculated with control variables and firm
strategy variables entered respectively. The model indicates that the
relatedness of the target firm to the acquiring firm is significant
(Hypothesis 6). Other firm variables are not significant, therefore
providing no support for hypotheses 4 and 5. Model 3 has a strongly
significant adjusted R2 of .26.
Lastly, Model 4 is estimated. This regression model includes the
control, industry, and firm strategy variables entered simultaneously.
In this last model, only the relatedness of the target firm to the
acquiring firm indicates a significant t-ratio. However, the model does
not have a significant adjusted R2, indicating that this model does not
explain any additional variance beyond Models 1, 2 or 3.
Cultural distance
The initial sample included acquisition targets from a large
homogenous political/legal environment in order to control for
extraneous national or legal effects on the degree of ownership. Large
numbers of acquisitions within the sample are clustered in the United
Kingdom, France, and Germany. The sample included 101 acquisitions of
U.K. targets, with 74 and 46 in Germany and France respectively. Even
though these countries have common tariffs and international trading
standards, they are of course very different socially and culturally. Of
the three, the U.K. is most culturally similar to the U.S. and is its
leading international trading partner. As such, this nation is
considered having the least market distance between U.S. markets and
business practices.
To investigate the hypothesized relationships in the context of
cultural differences between U.S. firms and the individual nations
within the European Union, the research model was again tested using
these subsets of the overall acquisition sample per nation. The results
of the tests run on the three nations are indicated below in Table 3.
This test illuminates the strength of the proposed hypotheses (H7 &
H8) per each of these three countries.
As the results indicate, all three models had significant adjusted
R2's, however they differed somewhat on the predictor variables.
For the French and German sample of firms, the common significant
predictor was similarity of advertising allocations across business
units. This variable indicated a strong negative relationship with
degree of ownership. Therefore, when advertising intensity is similar
across businesses within the acquisitive firm the degree of ownership
purchased would be less. Another finding for the French sample is the
importance of industry growth in the French market. The model shows a
significant influence on the dependent variable suggesting that higher
industry growth in the target market meant higher degrees of ownership
by the acquiring American firms.
As for the U. K. sample, different predictor variables indicated
significant explanatory power. The regression equation included the
relatedness variable as significant to explaining the degree of
ownership. Acquiring firms that were related to their targets acquired a
greater degree of ownership than unrelated firms is similar to previous
results.
DISCUSSION
The results of the data analyses reveal that, indeed, explaining
the degree of target firm ownership is a combination of market and firm
influences. The study suggests that acquisition ownership is driven in
part by environmental influences and strategic similarity between the
firms. The findings neither completely support the industry influences
model nor the firm effects. Rather, they reveal that acquisitions and
ownership are part of a process of capturing market opportunities and
combining knowledge of existing market environments and internal
capabilities.
The results concerning hypothesis 1, the level of technological
development, suggest that this characteristic is not an important
influence on firms concerning the degree of ownership they acquire.
Overall, this finding is in contrast with much of the literature
maintaining that an industry's technological development is one of
the primary drivers of a firm's strategy and structure (Chan,
Martin & Kensigner, 1990; Child, 1972). Perhaps the primary issue of
acquiring firms investing in these markets is not the degree of the
investment, but the fact that a purchase of any degree provides access
to new technologies in international markets. Therefore, no ownership
pattern emerges for these acquisitions.
In other aspects of the tests of market effects, it appears that
industry growth rates are important for an acquiring firm's
ownership preferences as indicated in hypothesis 2. U.S. firms purchase
high levels of ownership in high growth markets regardless of any risk
associated with volatility and change, in order to more capitalize on rapid market growth and reduce transaction costs. Acquisitions are one
of the primary choices for corporate growth strategies that allow firms
to move rapidly into new markets or areas and receive immediate
benefits. With increased uncertainty and inconstancies inherent in these
rapidly changing markets, firms utilize high degrees of ownership to
structure their acquisitions.
Lastly, in the tests of market effects, the findings support
hypothesis 3. The results suggest that U.S. firms belonging to highly
concentrated industries purchase more of their targets than firms
competing in fragmented industries. Typically, these concentrated
industries are characterized by market maturity and stability.
Alternatively, fragmented industries provide an environment for firms to
undertake a diverse set of strategies. Investing abroad involves
inherent uncertainty in determining how to compete in new industries or
markets. In developing organizational responses for dealing with the
uncertainties associated with international expansion, firms
historically relying on market power in concentrated industries are
likely to extend similar competencies into new subsidiaries. This meets
their need for control required by large, powerful firms for resource
allocation and for any post-acquisition realignment in the overall
structure of the firm. Therefore, a conformance to pre-existing firm
norms brought about by membership in highly concentrated environments
may be particularly relevant for firms investing abroad through
acquisitions. The overall result of this pattern is an effort by U.S.
firms in concentrated markets to retain control through ownership over
operations as they expand into newly acquired EU subsidiaries.
The tests of the firm effects model examine the importance of the
acquiring firm's strategic similarity in terms of pre-existing
relatedness patterns and resource allocations and the relatedness of the
acquiring firm and target. The results for these effects are mixed with
the variables relating pre-existing strategic patterns as having little
importance for explaining the degree of ownership in acquisitions. The
lack of support for these hypotheses has many plausible explanations.
Perhaps when a highly related acquiring firm purchases targets in new
areas or markets it does not have the existing competencies to warrant
high degrees of ownership and control. As such, lower degrees of
ownership would be warranted.
In interpreting the results focusing on corporate resource
allocation patterns, the evidence suggests little influence of these
strategic considerations on the degree of ownership. The findings do not
allow us to extend Harrison et al. (1990), who argue that consistency of
allocations provide clues as to the dominant logic of the firm and
signal high control processes at work throughout the firm. It appears
that for firms allocating resources similarly throughout their
subsidiaries, the need for consistently applying this strategy does not
carryover to its purchase of new subsidiaries by acquiring a high degree
of ownership. Perhaps pre-existing patterns of allocating might be more
important as influences later in the implementation process and could be
an important factor in an acquiring firm increasing its ownership stake.
Overall, hypothesis four and five are not supported.
The variable with the strongest significant explanatory power of
any in the overall research model is the relatedness of the target firm
to the acquiring firm. These results reveal that when acquiring firms
are interested in expanding into related areas, then high degrees of
ownership are warranted. Based on the theoretical framework, this is a
continuation of capabilities developed in the acquiring firm and
extended to the target. It is also an opportunity for the acquirer to
adapt and change as new ideas and resources are brought into the firm.
High degrees of ownership enable these processes within merging firms
and provide an economically efficient means for growth. Lastly,
purchasing related businesses offset the risk associated with an
international acquisition.
Lastly, the sample was split into subgroups consisting of
acquisitions located in France, Germany and the U.K. The regression
models were rerun to test what, if any differences, market distance had
on the hypothesized relationships. Many international researchers have
long argued that differences between nations necessitate the need for
firms to be locally responsive to individual markets (Dunning, 1980;
Kimura, 1989; Rosenzweig & Singh, 1991) even when legal or political
considerations are similar. Theoretically, it was argued that as
differences in national environments increased, the industry and firm
factors driving ownership would have even stronger influences on degree
of ownership.
The results are weak concerning hypotheses 7 and 8 as the factors
do not appear stronger for the French and German subsets than they do
for the U.K. The only factors that do differentiate themselves from the
overall model concern advertising allocations and the extent of internal
diversification of the acquiring firm. Consistent advertising
allocations were not supported in the overall model. In the French and
German samples they are not supported either, but are significant in the
opposite direction of the hypothesized relationships. This evidence
suggests that firms purchasing targets in nations with high market
distance from the U.S. are expecting to adapt to their local
environments in terms of marketing expenditures. The likelihood that the
target will be integrated into the parent organization in this area
appears to be, at least initially, offset for the need to be locally
responsive in these strategic areas. In this situation, acquiring firms
are not acting on extending similar strategic patterns, but are focusing
on gaining market knowledge from other partners until time that shares
of ownership will be increased or divested.
As for the U. K. sample, different predictor variables indicate
significant explanatory power. The regression equation includes the
relatedness variable as significant on the degree of ownership.
Acquiring firms that were related to their targets acquired a greater
degree of ownership than unrelated firms did. Interestingly, the
strategic similarity theory as it applies to diversification relatedness
appears stronger for targets located in the U.K. than for the French and
German samples. Perhaps U.S. firms are more confident of extending their
capabilities in U.K. firms with similar cultural proximity and
therefore, purchase large degrees of ownership.
For an indication of the relative strength of the market and firm
strategy effects, the results indicate that strategic considerations
provide more explanatory power than industry influences. This difference
is expressed in the percent of explained variance indicated in the
adjusted R2 between the two main research models (2 and 3) in Table 2.
Interestingly, more variables are significant in the industry effects
model, but the model's overall predictive power is weaker. This
result appears to be due to the importance of the relatedness of the
target firm to the acquiring firm.
The two sets of market and strategy influences appear to lack any
complementary or additive effects on the degree of ownership as expected
in the research model. Instead, they appear to offset each other's
explanatory power. For example, the explained variance of degree of
ownership is not significant when the two sets are input simultaneously
in regression Model 4. The significant industry variables, concentration
and international growth, become inconsequential and even negative in
their relationship with ownership, while the overall model is not
significant in explaining any variance. Also, only the relatedness of
the target firm to the acquiring firm is significant to the degree of
ownership in Model 4.
Conclusions from these results indicate that the most predictable
effects stem from the relatedness of the target firm to the acquirer,
the growth rate of the target's international market and industry
concentration level. Overall, the set of strategic choice variables is
strongest in its explanatory power of degree of ownership. The
complementary nature of these sets of predictors is not supported. The
results do suggest that strategic similarity and environmental
considerations are important for ownership choices.
As with any research, there are limitations to the study. While,
efforts were made to minimize these limitations, some remain and must be
stated. One issue concerns the inherent nature of cross-sectional
designs. While this type of research design has the ability to describe
features of large numbers of organizations, it is difficult to eliminate
all factors that could possibly cause the observed correlation. The
study attempted to control for these, but obviously many other factors
could be suggested as important influences on the degree of ownership
purchased of international acquisitions.
Another limitation of this research is the focus on acquisitions
made in European Union nations. The findings of the study may not be
generalizable to acquisitions made in other countries. Also, the study
includes only acquisitions during the time frame of 1992-1997. The
decade of the 1990's was an era of great change and discontinuity in the EU as new laws passed, Eastern European nations integrated into
the West, and monetary and regulatory unification between the member
nations continued. Obviously, with such change, one has to acknowledge
that existing patterns and actions of firms during this period may not
be the replicable in other time periods.
The results suggest that acquisitive U.S. firms investing in the
E.U. tend to purchase higher levels of ownership if the firm is
strategically similar to its current line of business, regardless of
previous international experience, size of the firm, or industry
characteristics. With high control via ownership, it may still be
necessary to be locally responsive with corporate resource allocations.
The evidence also suggests that U.S. firms in highly concentrated
domestic industries purchase a higher degree of ownership of
international acquisitions than firms participating in more fragmented
industries. Overall, when making decisions about acquisitions, it
appears that fitting the target to the acquiring firm may be of more
importance to decision-makers than industry considerations.
From an investigation of this topic, questions emerge that generate
areas for further research. One primary issue lies in determining the
relationship of the degree of ownership with the performance of
acquisitions. The performance--ownership linkage could be examined using
market measures at the time of the purchase or the subsidiaries
performance following the purchase. Lastly, an investigation of the
different levels of ownership and control and their impact on the
implementation of the acquisitions would be appropriate. Linking
performance to the issue of degree of ownership would provide meaningful
information in the areas of structure and implementation, providing data
for firms on the most beneficial method for structuring acquisitions at
their inception.
REFERENCES
Anderson, E. & Gatignon, H. (1986). Modes of foreign entry: A
transaction cost analysis and propositions. Journal of International
Business Studies, 17, 1-26.
Bowman, E.H. & Singh, H. (1990). Overview of corporate
restructuring, trends and consequences. In Corporate Restructuring, Rock
L. & Rock R.H. (Eds), New York: McGraw Hill, 1-16.
Bowman, E.H. & Singh, H. (1993). Corporate restructuring:
reconfiguring the firm. Strategic Management Journal, Summer Special
Issue, 14, 5-14.
Buckley, P.J. & Casson, M. (1976). The Future of the
Multinational Enterprise. London: MacMillan.
Capron, L., Mitchell, W. & Swaminathan, A. (2001). Asset
divestiture following horizontal acquisitions: A dynamic view. Strategic
Management Journal, 22(9), 817-844.
Caves, R. E. & Mehra, S.K. (1986). Entry of foreign
multinationals into U.S. manufacturing industries. In M.E. Porter (Ed.),
Competition in Global Industries. Boston: Harvard Press.
Chan, S.H., Martin, J.D. & Kensinger, J.W. (1990). Corporate
research and development expenditures and share value. Journal of
Financial Economics, 26, 255-276.
Chatterjee, S. (1992). Sources of value in takeovers: Synergy or
restructuring-Implications for target and bidder firms. Strategic
Management Journal, 13, 267-286.
Child, J. (1972). Organizational structure, environment, and
performance--The role of strategic choice. Sociology, 6, 1-22.
Davidson, W.H. (1982). Global Strategic Management. New York: John
Wiley & Sons.
Dunning, J. (1980). Toward an eclectic theory of international
production: Some empirical tests. Journal of International Business
Studies, 11(2), 9-31.
Galbraith, J.R. & Kazanjian, R.K. (1986). Strategy
Implementation: Structure, Systems, and Process. St. Paul: West.
Gomes-Casseres, B. (1989). Ownership structures of foreign
subsidiaries: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, January: 1-25.
Griffith, D.A. & Harvey, M.G. (2001). A resource perspective of
global dynamic capabilities. Journal of International Business, 32(3),
597-606.
Harrison, J.S., Hall, E.H. & Nargundkar, R. (1993). Resource
allocation as an outcropping of strategic consistency: Performance
implications. Academy of Management Journal, 36, 1026-1051.
Haspeslagh, P.C. & Jemison, D.B. (1991). Managing Acquisitions,
New York: Free Press.
Hedlund, G. (1986). A hypermodern MNC--A heterarchy? Human Resource
Management, Spring: 9-35.
Hennart, J-F. (1991). Control in multinational firms: The role of
price and hierarchy. Management International Review, Special Issue:
71-96.
Hill, C.W., Hwang, P. & Kim, W.C. (1990). An eclectic theory of
the choice of international entry mode. Strategic Management Journal,
11, 117-128.
Hout, T., Porter, M. & Rudden, E. (1982). How global companies
win out. Harvard Business Review, 60, 98-108.
Huff, A.S. (1982). Industry influences on strategy reformulation.
Strategic Management Journal, 3(2), 119-131.
Inkpen, A. & Beamish, P. (1997). Knowledge, bargaining power,
and the instability of joint ventures. Academy of Management Review,
20(1), 177-202.
Kale, S.H. (1986). Dealer perceptions of manufacturer power and
influence strategies in a developing country. Journal of Marketing
Research, 23(4), 387-393.
Kim, W.C. & Hwang, P. (1992). Global strategy and
multinational's entry mode choice. Journal of International
Business Studies, 23(1), 29-53.
Kimura, Y. (1989). Firm-specific strategic advantages and foreign
direct investment behavior of firms: The case of Japanese semiconductor
firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 20, 296-314.
Kogut, B. & Singh, H. (1988). The effect of national culture on
the choice of entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies,
19(3), 411-432.
Kogut, B. & Singh, H. (1989). Industry and competitive effects
on the choice of entry mode. Academy of Management Proceedings, 116-120.
Kogut, B. & Zander, U. (1996). What firms do? Coordination,
identity and learning. Organization Science, 7, 502-518.
Mascarenhas, B. (1992). Order of entry of performance in
international markets. Strategic Management Journal, 13(7), 499-510.
Oliver, C. (1997). Sustainable competitive advantage: combining
institutional and resource-based views. Strategic Management Journal,
18(2), 697-713.
Palepu, K. (1985). Diversification strategy, profit performance,
and the entropy measure. Strategic Management Journal, 6, 239-255.
Pedhazur, E.J. (1982). Multiple Regression in Behavioral Research.
Fort Worth, TX: Harcourt Brace.
Porac, J.F., Thomas, H., Wilson, F., Paton, D. & Kanfer, A.
(1995). Rivalry and the industry model of Scottish knitwear producers.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 40, 203-227.
Porter, M. (1986). Competition in global industries: A conceptual
framework. In M.E. Porter (Ed.) Competition in Global Industries.
Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Ramaswamy, K. (1997). The performance impact of strategic
similarity in horizontal mergers: Evidence from the U.S. banking
industry. Academy of Management Journal, 40(3), 697-716.
Root, F.R. (1987). Entry Strategies for International Markets.
Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath.
Rosenweig, P.M. & Singh, J.V. (1991). Organizational
environments and the multinational enterprise. Academy of Management
Review, 16(2), 340-361.
Singh, H. & Zollo, M. (1997). Knowledge accumulation and the
evolution of post-acquisition management practices. Presented at the
Academy of Management Conference, Boston, MA.
Spender, J-C. (1987). Industry Recipes: An Inquiry in the Nature
and Sources of Managerial Judgement, Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Vachani, S. (1991). Distinguishing between related and unrelated
international diversification: A comprehensive measure of global
diversification. Journal of International Business Studies, 22(2),
307-322.
Williamson, O. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New
York: The Free Press.
Yip, G. (1982). Diversification entry: Internal development versus
acquisition. Strategic Management Journal, 3, 331-345.
John D. Francis, Iona College
Table 1 Correlation Matrix
1 2 3 4 5
1. Acquiring 1.00
Firm Revenues
2. Acquiring Firms .12 * 1.00
Internationalization
3. Relatedness of .03 .05 1.00
Acquisition
4. Similarity of -.05 .05 .05 1.00
Acq Firm's R&D
5. Similarity of -.14 .21 .06 .02 1.00
Acq Firm's
Advertising
6. Industry Tech -.01 .16 ** -.04 .02 -.16
Development
7. Industry Growth -.05 .14 * .21 ** .04 .04
8. Industry .05 .07 -.08 -.16 * -.07
Concentration
9. Degree of -.05 .15 ** .31 ** .08 -.13
Ownership Purchased
6 7 8 9
1. Acquiring
Firm Revenues
2. Acquiring Firms
Internationalization
3. Relatedness of
Acquisition
4. Similarity of
Acq Firm's R&D
5. Similarity of
Acq Firm's
Advertising
6. Industry Tech 1.00
Development
7. Industry Growth -.07 1.00
8. Industry .14 * -.13 1.00
Concentration
9. Degree of .01 .17 * .18 ** 1.00
Ownership Purchased
N = 311.
** Correlation is significant at the .01 level (1-tailed).
* .Correlation is significant at the .05 level(1-tailed).
Table 2: Regression Estimates For Degree of Ownership Total sample
Model 1 Model 2
Variables [beta] t-ratio [beta] t-ratio
Constant 89.266 50.51 68.846 8.95
Control Variables
AF SALES -1.349E-5 -1.01 5.646E-5 -.38
AF INTL -15.307 * -2.76 -13.946 -1.90
Industry Variables
INDTCDV -- -- -.485 -.237
INTINDGR -- -- .173 * 2.41
INDCONC -- -- 26.079 *** 3.51
Firm Variables
TFREL -- -- -- --
AFR&DINT -- -- -- --
AFADVINT -- -- -- --
Adjusted [R.sup.2] * .022 ** .086
N 311 311
Model 3 Model 4
Variables [beta] t-ratio [beta] t-ratio
Constant 111.954 18.42 116.821 5.06
Control Variables
AF SALES -6.770E-4 * -2.59 -3.674E-4 -.83
AF INTL -14.298 -1.44 -27.006 -1.78
Industry Variables
INDTCDV -- -- -3.434 -.80
INTINDGR -- -- -983 1E-3 -.05
INDCONC -- -- 13.161 .78
Firm Variables
TFREL 11.328 ** 2.81 14.824 * 2.42
AFR&DINT 17.540 .76 -24.279 .74
AFADVINT -54.190 -1.75 -36.098 -.89
Adjusted [R.sup.2] ** .260 .132
N 311 311
* p<.05, ** p<.01, *** p<.001
Table 3 Regression Estimates For Degree of Ownership France,
Germany, And U. K. Subsets
France Germany
Variables B t-ratio B t-ratio
Constant 97.985 12.25 101.997 14.85
-Control Variables
AF SALES .251 .85 .025 .09
AF INTL .491 1.29 -.433 -1.66
-Industry Variables
INDTCDV .152 .48 -.187 -.70
INTINDGR .502 * 2.99 -.035 -.13
INDCONC -.031 -.06 .430 1.92
-Firm Variables
TFREL .103 .31 -.008 -.02
AFR&DINT .099 .32 -.295 -1.21
AFADVINT -265.
631 * -3.18 -683.45 * -2.82
Adjusted [R.sup.2] *.646 *.411
N 47 74
U. K.
Variables B t-ratio
Constant 66.700 8.57
-Control Variables
AF SALES .177 1.06
AF INTL -.105 -.43
-Industry Variables
INDTCDV -.203 -1.20
INTINDGR .194 .94
INDCONC .020 .09
-Firm Variables
TFREL 34.691 ** 5.54
AFR&DINT .013 .064
AFADVINT
-.043 -.23
Adjusted [R.sup.2] *.792
N 101
* p<.05, ** p<.01, *** p<.001