首页    期刊浏览 2025年03月03日 星期一
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Mathematical modelling of dispute proceedings between investors and third parties on allegedly violated third-party rights/Ginco proceso tarp investuotoju ir treciuju asmenu del galimai pazeistu treciuju asmenu teisiu matematinis modeliavimas.
  • 作者:Sostak, Olga Regina ; Vakriniene, Sigute
  • 期刊名称:Journal of Civil Engineering and Management
  • 印刷版ISSN:1392-3730
  • 出版年度:2011
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Vilnius Gediminas Technical University
  • 摘要:In most of our cities, some parts undergo intensive transformations related to commercialisation, land use and the density of buildings (Kaklauskas et al. 2007; Bardauskiene 2007; Turskis et al. 2006; Zavadskas et al. 2004; Kaganova et al. 2008). Several examples in European cities show that development can embrace internal urban areas (Mcdonald et al. 2009; Kaklauskas et al. 2009; Miller et al. 2004). Currently, Lithuanian cities also witness concentrated development (Zavadskas et al. 2009; Viteikiene and Zavadskas 2007; Burinskiene 2009; Jakaitis et al. 2009). It allows using the existing infrastructure and abandoned urban territories. Such planning also reduces the amount of used land and creates a lasting environment, the immensely dense population of which is not always able to function properly (Burinskiene and Rudzkiene 2009; Lahdenpera 2009; Petrovic et al. 2009; Greater London Authority 2003; Ribeiro 2008; Lindgren and Castell 2008). On one hand, it is a natural stage related to the renovation of neglected valuable urban areas. On the other hand, the course and outcomes at this stage reveal gaps within the renewal process. We are inclined to blame the drawbacks of laws regulating urban planning and protection of visual identity (investors cannot always be expected to abandon their self-centred ends for the sake of urban values, etc.) (Dringelis 2005; Vrubliauskas 2005; Jakaitis 2004; Mickaityte et al. 2008; Banaitis and Banaitiene 2007; Majamaa et al. 2008). This is in a large part influenced by a confusing, non-effective system for the coordination of constructions with government institutions and the public. The regulation of constructions is confusing; builders breach the introduced requirements; officials are frequently provided with the right to easily choose the requirements necessary to be applied. An inappropriate distribution of functions among government institutions and private subjects raise a number of problems (Sostak and Kutut 2009). One of the outcomes of inappropriate legal regulation is the violation of the third-party rights (i.e. the parties not directly related to the investment construction process: the owners of neighbouring plots, users, communities of residential districts, etc.). The article analyses the influence of third-party rights infringed during construction planning on the implementation of an investment project.
  • 关键词:Construction management;Decision making;Decision-making;Industrial project management;Investment management;Investments;Mathematical models;Project management;Third parties (Law)

Mathematical modelling of dispute proceedings between investors and third parties on allegedly violated third-party rights/Ginco proceso tarp investuotoju ir treciuju asmenu del galimai pazeistu treciuju asmenu teisiu matematinis modeliavimas.


Sostak, Olga Regina ; Vakriniene, Sigute


1. Introduction

In most of our cities, some parts undergo intensive transformations related to commercialisation, land use and the density of buildings (Kaklauskas et al. 2007; Bardauskiene 2007; Turskis et al. 2006; Zavadskas et al. 2004; Kaganova et al. 2008). Several examples in European cities show that development can embrace internal urban areas (Mcdonald et al. 2009; Kaklauskas et al. 2009; Miller et al. 2004). Currently, Lithuanian cities also witness concentrated development (Zavadskas et al. 2009; Viteikiene and Zavadskas 2007; Burinskiene 2009; Jakaitis et al. 2009). It allows using the existing infrastructure and abandoned urban territories. Such planning also reduces the amount of used land and creates a lasting environment, the immensely dense population of which is not always able to function properly (Burinskiene and Rudzkiene 2009; Lahdenpera 2009; Petrovic et al. 2009; Greater London Authority 2003; Ribeiro 2008; Lindgren and Castell 2008). On one hand, it is a natural stage related to the renovation of neglected valuable urban areas. On the other hand, the course and outcomes at this stage reveal gaps within the renewal process. We are inclined to blame the drawbacks of laws regulating urban planning and protection of visual identity (investors cannot always be expected to abandon their self-centred ends for the sake of urban values, etc.) (Dringelis 2005; Vrubliauskas 2005; Jakaitis 2004; Mickaityte et al. 2008; Banaitis and Banaitiene 2007; Majamaa et al. 2008). This is in a large part influenced by a confusing, non-effective system for the coordination of constructions with government institutions and the public. The regulation of constructions is confusing; builders breach the introduced requirements; officials are frequently provided with the right to easily choose the requirements necessary to be applied. An inappropriate distribution of functions among government institutions and private subjects raise a number of problems (Sostak and Kutut 2009). One of the outcomes of inappropriate legal regulation is the violation of the third-party rights (i.e. the parties not directly related to the investment construction process: the owners of neighbouring plots, users, communities of residential districts, etc.). The article analyses the influence of third-party rights infringed during construction planning on the implementation of an investment project.

The development of the national economy is impossible without construction: people use construction products--various buildings--to live, work and satisfy other social needs. Construction investment contributes to national economic growth and development extensively (Urbanavieiene et al. 2009; Zavadskas and Kaklauskas 2005, 2008). The investment process in construction is long and complicated; it requires enormous financial, intellectual and other resources. If judicial disputes occur during this process, the investor may incur huge loss, and project implementation may be postponed for an indefinite term. Litigation may continue for several years (The judgement of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 19 January 2007 in the administrative case; The judgement of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 26 January 2007 in the administrative case). Thus, investors are most concerned to avoid any legal disputes and should pay considerable attention to their prevention.

Violations of third-party rights are of benefit neither to third parties, nor to the parties of the investment process, because, on one hand, such violations might wrongfully cause the deterioration of the conditions for life and other activities of third persons. On the other hand, violations of third-party rights at the stage of construction planning may affect the implementation of the investment project, because all solutions violating third-party rights also violate the provisions of legal acts and can be disputed as stipulated by the Law on Administrative Proceedings (hereinafter LAP 2000), the Law on Territorial Planning (2004) and other legal acts (Mitkus and Sostak 2009).

In a construction project, judicial disputes are an unwanted risk factor, which may disrupt the entire project. It is therefore necessary to plan and apply preventive measures for the mitigation of such risk at the initial planning stage of a construction project. To evaluate and eliminate these risk factors, state-of-the-art technologies for construction project planning and management must be integrated into each step of construction project planning and implementation. It is necessary to employ innovative methods for construction project planning and implementation when the conditions are indeterminate (Kahraman and Kaya 2010; Blaszczyk and Nowak 2009). Risk management strategies and the development of a risk management plan must be improved, risk analysis methods and technologies must be used, and the risk reporting mechanism must be implemented. For a successful construction project, it is worth to employ the functions of project management. It is necessary to analyse the risk using the knowledge of relevant experts and to properly evaluate the scope of possible negative effects and their outcomes to the construction project. The findings should influence the subsequent decision-making process. Risks must be monitored and decision-making must be analysed throughout the project lifecycle. Before launching a project, an investor must be ready for any "surprises". Forecasting is the most important part of any strategy, because the actions recommended for certain situations stem from the forecasts of possible outcomes. Thus, investors must be aware of the defence procedures taking place in administrative courts when third-party rights are violated during territorial planning--they must assess possible actions of third parties.

The process consists of the following main stages: 1) third parties learn about the violation of their rights (infringement determined); 2) a pretrial defence of infringed rights (advance instance). Before an administrative court is involved, separate legal acts or actions/ omissions of public administration entities foreseen by laws can be, and in cases established by laws must be, disputed by applying to an advance institution for out-of-court case hearing. The procedures for a pretrial defence of third-party rights are defined in Article 25 of The Law on Administrative Proceedings of the Republic of Lithuania (LAP 2000). Unless the laws foresee otherwise, administrative disputes may be heard out-of-court by public municipal commissions for administrative disputes and the Supreme Commission for Administrative Disputes (LAP 2000, Art. 26); 3) a judicial defence of violated rights. The Law on Administrative Proceedings of the Republic of Lithuania foresees that a decision of a respective commission for administrative disputes or another institution for advance out-of-court hearing of disputes made after hearing an administrative dispute out-of-court can be appealed against to an administrative court by the dispute party which is discontent with the decision of such commission for administrative disputes or another institution for advance out-of-court hearing of disputes. The appellation must be submitted to the administrative court within 20 days upon the announcement of the decision (LAP 2000, Art. 32); 4) the case proceedings at a court of first instance. Art. 68 of LAP (2000) foresees that the chairman of the court or the judge who made the decision to accepted the claim, if necessary, take care of the following important aspects of preparation for the trial: a) prepare claim guarantee measures; b) make a decision on the invitation of experts or inspection; c) perform other actions required for preparation for the trial; etc. It is not always possible to complete a trial fully and to make a judgment at the first and single court session; although the court attempts to complete a trial within one session if it does not impair proper settlement. However, it is rather difficult, and sometimes impossible, even if the proceedings are prepared properly, though it is the aim of such preparation to guarantee full completion of a trial already at the first session. Unforeseen obstacles are rather frequent; therefore, the proceedings continue for one, two, three and sometimes even ten or more sessions (Lauzikas et al. 2005); 5) the case proceedings at a court of appeal. In order to guarantee the expedition of the process, to protect the interests of the winning party in the case and to guarantee definite relations between the parties, the law specifies a period for party discontent with the court decision or for another person participating in the case to exercise their right of appeal. Judgements of county administrative courts announced after a trial in the court of first instance can be appealed against to the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania within fourteen days after the announcement of the judgement (LAP 2000, Art. 127). The proceedings of an appeal are similar to proceedings at the court of first instance. A judgement, a resolution or a rule of the court of appeal comes into force on the day of its announcement and cannot be appealed against in cassation (LAP 2000).

A peace treaty can be signed at any stage. A compromise is achieved in such case and further litigation is avoided (Mitkus and Sostak 2008a).

If a judicial dispute occurs when the construction project is already launched, the investor must also consider all possible actions of judicial institutions. The lessons learned about risk management during the implementation of construction projects should be used in future projects (Zavadskas et al. 2010; Park et al. 2009; Yang et al. 2009; Antucheviciene et al. 2010). Mathematical modelling of the problem in question and the selection of a proper method for optimisation help with determining the optimal investor's behaviour strategy that would allow expecting a certain average profit irrespective of the strategies of third parties and decisions of judicial institutions. Our research employs the mathematical model for stochastic dynamic programming.

2. Mathematical Modelling of a Dispute between Investors and Third Parties on Allegedly Violated Third-party rights with the Help of Stochastic Dynamic Programming

The analysis of the procedure related to the defence of violated third-party rights in administrative courts leads to a conclusion that a judicial dispute may either ruin a construction investment project completely or to cut the expected profits considerably. Largely, it depends on the decisions of the interested communities (third persons) that object to the construction and on the decisions of judicial institutions hearing the disputes. Naturally, investors are most interested to avoid any legal disputes. A possible preventive measure to mitigate such risk is an assessment and proper analysis of all possible future events related to the occurrence of such risk before the investment project is launched. For that purpose, the investor must come up with the scenarios of actions in possible situations and to plan strategic options. The investor, which is most interested to avoid any legal disputes, should assess all possible risk factors that may affect the implementation of a construction project. To illustrate such assessment, we shall turn to mathematical modelling of a dispute between investors and third parties on allegedly violated third-party rights. The dispute between investors and third parties on possibly infringed third-party rights was modelled by creating a tree of the behaviour variants of dispute parties (Fig. 1).

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Besides, the tree of variants helps in finding mistakes made afterwards and in correcting them (Mitkus and Sostak 2008b; Mitkus 2004; Nollke 2007; Ross Quinlan 1993). The tree of the behaviour variants of dispute parties in Fig. 1 models all possible actions of third persons, judicial institutions and the investor in a certain situation. The outcomes of their actions are assessed.

Dynamic programming will be used to find an optimal behaviour strategy for an investor. Dynamic programming is a method of calculation applied in a solution to the multi-stage problems of optimisation. It means that we need to break a complex problem of optimisation into a string of simpler problems. When these problems are solved, it is easy to find an answer to an original problem. Problems are divided following the Belman's Principle of Optimality: an optimal solution (management) has the property that whatever the initial state and initial solution are, the remaining solutions must constitute an optimal policy with regard to the state resulting from the first solutions. Note that by a dynamic problem we usually mean any process which depends on time (in our case, the court proceedings related to the defence of the infringed rights depend on time) (Ciocys and Jasilionis 1990; Taha 1997).

For further modelling, we shall look at the tree of the behaviour variants of dispute parties and make a tree of behaviour strategies for the investor (Fig. 2). If we want to solve the tree of behaviour strategies for the investor mathematically - to perform mathematical modelling--we need numerical values for our specific research case. The values are shown in Table 1. The numerical values are based on actual cases brought to Lithuanian courts (The judgement of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 20 February 2006 in the administrative case; The judgement of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 19 January 2007 in the administrative case; The judgement of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 26 January 2007 in the administrative case). We base our research on a general (abstract) model. The analysis of specific dispute cases in the future, however, could use corrected values and assess all individual aspects related to the conflict.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

3. The Model for Stochastic Dynamic Programming

Let f ([S.sub.i]) be the likely (expected) average investor's profit ensured by state [S.sub.i] and optimal strategy [x.sub.i]--selected from the set of possible strategies in this situation. The Belman's Principle of Optimality gives us recurrent equations for all situations [S.sub.i] :

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], (1)

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], is the pool of investor's original strategies in the situation (state) [S.sub.i]. Here [[m.sub.i].summation over (j=1)] [x.sub.ij] = 1 and

[x.sub.ij] [greater than or equal to] 0, j = 1, 2, ... , mi.

When the number of possible strategies is [m.sub.i], breaking the set of strategies using Index 2 satisfies equation [J.sub.is] [union] [J.sub.ib] = {1, 2, ..., [m.sub.i]}.

Generally, the intersection of index sets [J.sub.is] and [J.sub.ib] is a non-empty set, which means that the same strategy can lead to the final state or to a situation when the investor must chose a strategy again.

When j [member of] [J.sub.is], strategy [X.sub.ij] may lead the investor to situation [S.sub.ijk] (probability [p.sub.ijk]). The number of situations enabled by the investor's choice of strategy [x.sub.ij] is marked as [n.sub.ij].

When j [member of] [J.sub.ib] , strategy [x.sub.ij] leads the investor (probability [P.sub.ijk]) to the final state with profit [P.sub.jb].

f([S.sub.ijk]) is the likely (expected) average profit ensured by state [S.sub.ijk] and the optimal strategy selected from the pool of possible strategies in this state.

In our model for stochastic dynamic programming, probabilities [p.sub.ijk] and [p.sub.ijb] depend on the probability of decisions made by other institutions.

We shall proceed with the analysis of possible behaviour strategies for an investor that invests into a construction project, seeks maximum profits but faces the opposition of the community. We shall also look at the problem in which optimal strategies are determined using multi-stage optimisation--dynamic programming.

Here, probabilities [p.sub.ijk] and [p.sub.ijb] depend on the probability of certain decisions made by the community opposing the construction and judicial institutions hearing the disputes.

Let us define possible judicial situations.

Let [T.sub.k] be possible judicial states, k = [bar.1.7] (in our research, there are seven of these states).

In each state [T.sub.k], courts may make one of two decisions: [A.sub.k] or [B.sub.k].

Let the probabilities of events [A.sub.k] and [B.sub.k] be [q.sub.kl] = P([A.sub.k]) and [q.sub.k2] = P([B.sub.k]), [q.sub.kl] + [q.sub.k2] = 1 [q.sub.kl] [greater than or equal to] [q.sub.k2] [greater than or equal to] 0.

The first judicial state [T.sub.1] is possible if breaches are determined in planning and implementing construction investment projects and if the interested community applies with a claim to an advance institution for out-of-court case hearing. There are two possible events in such situation:

1) [A.sub.1]: the advance hearing institution rejects the claim (determines that the solutions of the construction investment project do not violate rights of the interested community).

2) [B.sub.1]: the advance hearing institution satisfies the claim.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[q.sub.11] = P([A.sub.1]) = 0.40 , [q.sub.12] = P([B.sub.1]) = 0.60.

The second judicial state [T.sub.2] is possible if the advance hearing institution rejects the claim of the interested community and the interested community applies to a court of first instance. There are two possible events in such situation:

1) [A.sub.2] : the claim of the interested community is rejected.

2) [B.sub.2] : the claim of the interested community is satisfied.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[q.sub.21] = P([A.sub.2]) = 0.50, [q.sub.22] = P([B.sub.2]) = 0.70.

The third judicial state [T.sub.3] is possible if the court of first instance rejects the claim of the interested community and the interested community applies to a court of appeal. There are two possible events in such situation:

1) [A.sub.3]: the claim of the interested community is rejected and the investor makes profit [P.sub.7].

2) [B.sub.3] : the claim of the interested community is satisfied and the cancellation of the solutions related to the construction investment project is initiated--the investor suffers loss N.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[q.sub.31] = P([A.sub.3]) = 0.50, [q.sub.32] = P([B.sub.3]) = 0.50.

The judicial state [T.sub.4] is possible if the court of first instance satisfies the claim of the interested community and the investor applies to a court of appeal. There are two possible events in such situation:

1) [A.sub.4] : the investor's claim is rejected and the cancellation of the solutions is initiated--the investor suffers loss N.

2) [B.sub.4]: the investor's claim is satisfied and the investor makes profit [P.sub.8].

Let us assess the probabilities of the events: [q.sub.41] = P([A.sub.4]) = 0.50, [q.sub.42] = P([B.sub.4]) = 0.50.

The fifth judicial state [T.sub.5] is possible if the advance institution for out-of-court case hearing satisfies the claim of the interested community and the investor applies to a court of first instance. There are two possible events in such situation:

1) [A.sub.5]: the investor's claim is satisfied;

2) [B.sub.5]: the investor's claim is rejected.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events: [q.sub.51] = P([A.sub.5]) = 0.50 , [q.sub.52] = P(B5) = 0.50 .

The sixth judicial state [T.sub.6] is possible if the court of first instance rejects the investor's claim and the investor applies to a court of appeal. There are two possible events in such situation:

1) [A.sub.6] : the investor's claim is rejected and the cancellation of the solutions is initiated--the investor suffers loss N.

2) [B.sub.6] : the investor's claim is satisfied and the investor makes profit [P.sub.10].

Let us assess the probabilities of the events: [q.sub.61] = P([A.sub.6]) = 0.50, [q.sub.62] = P([B.sub.6]) = 0.50.

The seventh judicial state T7 is possible if the court of first instance satisfies the investor's claim and the interested community applies to a court of appeal. There are two possible events in such situation:

1) [A.sub.7] : the claim of the interested community is satisfied and the cancellation of the solutions is initiated--the investor suffers loss N.

2) [B.sub.7] : the claim of the interested community is rejected and the investor makes profit [P.sub.12].

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[q.sub.71] = P([A.sub.7]) = 0.50, [q.sub.72] = P([B.sub.7]) = 0.50.

Let [V.sub.j] be the possible states of the interested community (situations when the community decides), j = [bar.1,5] (in our research, there are five of these states).

The interested community may act in two different ways in each state: either to refrain from applying to a judicial institution (event [C.sub.j]) or to apply (event [D.sub.j]).

There are respective probabilities [p.sub.j1] and [p.sub.j2], where [p.sub.j1] + [p.sub.j2] = 1, p.sub.j1] [greater than or equal to] [p.sub.j2] [greater than or equal to] 0.

The first state of interested community [V.sub.1] is possible if the investment solution violates rights. There are two possible events in such case:

1) [C.sub.1] : the interested community fails to see the violations in the investment solution or fails to submit its suggestions or objections before the deadline, thus the investor makes profit P.

2) [D.sub.1] : the interested community determines the violations in the investment solution and submits its suggestions and/or objections before the deadline.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[p.sub.11] = P([C.sub.1]) = 0.80, [p.sub.12] = P([D.sub.1]) = 0.20.

The second state of interested community [V.sub.2] is possible if the investor rejects the suggestions submitted by the interested community regarding the violations in the investment solution. There are two possible events in such case:

1) [C.sub.2] : the interested community does not apply to an advance institution for out-of-court dispute hearing and the investor makes profit [P.sub.3].

2) [D.sub.2] : the interested community applies to an advance institution for out-of-court dispute hearing.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[p.sub.21] = P([C.sub.2]) = 0.30, [p.sub.22] = P([D.sub.2]) = 0.70.

The third state of interested community [V.sub.3] is possible if the advance institution for out-of-court dispute hearing rejects the claim of the interested community. There are two possible events in such case:

1) [C.sub.3] : the interested community does not apply to a court of first instance and the investor makes profit [P.sub.4].

2) [D.sub.3] : the interested community applies to a court of first instance.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[p.sub.31] = P([C.sub.3]) = 0.25 , [p.sub.32] = P([D.sub.3]) = 0.75.

The fourth state of interested community [V.sub.4] is possible if the court of first instance rejects the claim of the interested community. There are two possible events in such case:

1) [C.sub.4] : the interested community does not apply to a court of appeal and the investor makes profit [P.sub.6].

2) [D.sub.4] : the interested community applies to the court of appeal.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[p.sub.4l] = P([C.sub.4]) = 0.15, [p.sub.42] = P([D.sub.4]) = 0.85.

The fifth state of interested community [V.sub.5] is possible if the court of first instance satisfies the investor's claim. There are two possible events in such case:

1) [C.sub.5] : the interested community does not apply to a court of appeal and the investor makes profit [P.sub.11].

2) [D.sub.5] : the interested community applies to a court of appeal.

Let us assess the probabilities of the events:

[P.sub.51] = P([C.sub.5]) = 0.45, [p.sub.52] = P([D.sub.5]) = 0.55.

Let [S.sub.i] be the possible states of the investor--the situations when the investor decides, i = [bar.0.5] (in our research, there are six of these states).

In each state, the investor can choose from either two or three behaviour strategies. Mixed behaviour strategies are also possible, when each original strategy has a probability assigned:

[x.sub.i1] is the probability the first strategy [s.sub.i1] will be selected; is the probability the second strategy [s.sub.i2] will be selected; [x.sub.i3] is the probability the third strategy [s.sub.i3] will be selected. [x.sub.i1] + [x.sub.i2] + [x.sub.i3] = 1, [x.sub.il] [greater than or equal to] 0, l = 1,2,3.

[S.sub.0] is the zero state of the investor. In this state, the investor contemplates whether the investment project is worth launching.

[S.sub.1] is the first state of the investor. If violations are de termined, the investor has three strategies to choose from:

[x.sub.11] : to accept the suggestions of the interested community and to make profit [P.sub.1].

[x.sub.12] : to sign a peace treaty and to make profit [P.sub.2].

[x.sub.13] : to reject the suggestions of the interested community.

[S.sub.2] is the second state of the investor. If the interested

community applies to a court of first instance, the investor has two strategies to choose from:

[x.sub.21] : to sign a peace treaty with the interested community and to make profit P5.

[x.sub.22] : to reject the peace treaty.

[S.sub.3] is the third state of the investor. If the court of first instance satisfies the claim of the interested community, the investor has two strategies to choose from:

[x.sub.31] : to refrain from an application to a court of appeal and to suffer loss N.

[x.sub.32] : to apply to a court of appeal.

[S.sub.4] is the fourth state of the investor. If the advance institution for out-of-court dispute hearing satisfies the claim of the interested community after the hearing, the investor has three strategies to choose from:

[x.sub.41] : to refrain from applying to a court of first instance and to suffer loss N.

[x.sub.42] : to sign a peace treaty with the interested community and to make profit [P.sub.9].

[x.sub.43] : to apply to a court of first instance.

[S.sub.5] is the fifth state of the investor. If the court of first instance rejects the investor's claim, the investor has two strategies to choose from:

[x.sub.51] : to refrain from applying to a court of appeal and to suffer loss N.

[x.sub.52] : to apply to a court of appeal.

We shall proceed with further mathematical modelling and, using the data from our graph (Fig. 2), shall come up with the recurrent equations (2):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (2)

In each state, we need to solve the problem of linear optimisation:

max([c.sub.1][x.sub.i1] + [c.sub.2][x.sub.i2] + ... + [c.sub.mi] [x.sub.imi]), [[m.sub.i].summation over (j=1)] [x.sub.ij] = 1, [x.sub.ij] [greater than or equal to] 0,

j = 1, 2, ..., [m.sub.i], in which one of the optimal plans is [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].

Thus, we can replace the recurrent equations with simplified versions (3):

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]. (3)

In order to determine optimal behaviour strategies for the investor, a programme code for a solution to the recurrent equations (3) has been developed in the EXEL environment (see Table 2). Let us analyse calculations in question.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

We solve the recurrent equations to find the specific values of profit in the final state and to determine specific probabilities that the community and judicial institutions will take one or another action. These values are the expected average profit for each state (situation) f ([S.sub.i]) and the optimal situation management marked as [x.sup.*.sub.t]. Obviously, original strategies are optimal for each state; their probability is equal to one.

Optimal investor's strategies determined using our calculations are shown in Fig. 3. A broad analysis of determining the dependency of the solutions on the parameters is possible. If, for instance, the size of loss N in the final situation varies between 1 and 1000, the optimal investor's behaviour remains the same, only values f ([S.sub.5]) and f ([S.sub.3]) change (1,000 monetary units were used as a measuring unit throughout research).

Further research should focus on the analysis of the investor's possibilities of choosing only the projects that would trigger the most positive reactions of third persons with increasing f([S.sub.1]) values.

Therefore, future research should consider the inclusion of several trees of the behaviour variants of dispute parties with the same starting point So and equivalent to the tree used in this research. An investor, when in state So, could select an optimal project based on the same Belman's Principle (see Fig. 3).

4. Conclusions

1. Violations of third-party rights are of benefit neither to third persons, nor to the parties of the construction investment process, because, on one hand, such violations might wrongfully cause the deterioration of conditions for life and other activities of third persons. On the other hand, violations of third-party rights at the stage of construction planning may affect the implementation of the investment project, because all solutions violating third-party rights also violate the provisions of legal acts and can be disputed as stipulated by the Law on Administrative Proceedings (LAP), the Law on Territorial Planning and other legal acts.

2. Investors may incur, and do incur, huge losses when solving disputes on the infringement of third-party rights.

3. In order to make the relations between investors and third parties more rational, a mathematical model of a dispute on allegedly infringed third-party rights has been developed. It helps with determining optimal investor's strategies for each situation of decision-making and thus ensures a certain average profit to the investor irrespective of the strategies chosen by third persons if the probabilities of selecting these strategies are known.

4. The mathematical model for stochastic dynamic programming (EXEL programme code for recurrent equations (3) is used) enables a broad analysis of the dependencies between the optimal investor's strategy and the probabilities that third parties will select a certain strategy. It also helps in analyzing the possible numerical values of profit (or loss).

doi: 10.3846/13923730.2011.560628

References

Antucheviciene, J.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Zakarevieius, A. 2010. Multiple criteria construction management decisions considering relations between criteria, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 16(1): 109-125. doi:10.3846/tede.2010.07

Banaitis, A.; Banaitiene, N. 2007. Development of a rational housing model: The Lithuanian case, International Journal of Environment and Pollution 30(3-1): 430-142. doi:10.1504/IJEP.2007.014820

Bardauskiene, D. 2007. Ekspertiniu vertinimu taikymas rengiant miesto bendraji plan? [The expert's estimates application in the preparation of city general plan], Technological and Economic Development of Economy 13(3): 223-236.

Blaszczyk, T.; Nowak, M. 2009. The time-cost trade-off analysis in construction project using computer simulation and interactive procedure, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(4): 523-539. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.523-539

Burinskiene, M. 2009. New methodology for sustainable development towards sustainable transportation system, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(1): 5-9. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.5-9

Burinskiene, M.; Rudzkiene, V. 2009. Future insights, scenarious and expert method application in sustainable territorial planning, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(1): 10-25. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.10-25

Ciocys, V.; Jasilionis, R 1990. Matematinis programavimas [Mathematical programming]. Vilnius: Mokslas.

Dringelis, L. 2005. Miesto viesosios erdves: pokyciu tendencijos ir savitumo issaugojimas [Public Urban Areas: trends of changes and preservation of peculiar features], Urbanistika ir architektura [Town Planning and Architecture] 29(1): 50-53.

Greater London Authority. 2003. Housing for a Compact City. Greater London Authority Architecture and Urbanism Unit.

Jakaitis, J. 2004. Neformalaus veikimo veiksniu itaka urbanistinei raidai [Influence of factors of informal activities on urban development], Urbanistika ir architektera [Town Planning and Architecture] 18(3): 132-143.

Jakaitis, J.; Paliulis, N.; Jakaitis, K. 2009. Aspects of the national urban policy management under conditions of integrated planning, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(1): 26-38. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.26-38

Kaganova, O.; Akmatov, A.; Undeland, C. 2008. Introducing more transparent and efficient land management in post-socialist cities: lessons from Kyrgyzstan, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 12(3): 161-181. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2008.12.161-181

Kaklauskas, A.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Saparauskas, J. 2009. Conceptual modelling of sustainable Vilnius development, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(1): 154-177. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.154-177

Kaklauskas, A.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Vainienas, P.; Jonaitis, V.; Stragys, V. 2007. Lietuvos statybu 2007-2030 vizija ir strategija. Gyvenimo kokybe [A vision and strategy for Lithuanian construction 2007-2030. Quality of life], in Lietuvos nacionaline statybu technologiju platforma [Lithuanian National Construction Technology Platform], 30-38.

Kahraman, C.; Kaya, I. 2010. Investment analyses using fuzzy probability concept, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 16(2): 43-57. doi:10.3846/tede.2010.03

Lahdenpera, P. 2009. Phased multi-target areal development competitions: algorithms for competitor allocation, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 13(1): 1-22. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2009.13.1-22

Lauzikas, E.; Mikelenas, V.; Nekrosius, V. 2005. Civilinio proceso teise [Law of Civil Process]. Vol. 2. Vilnius: JUSTITA.

Lietuvos Respublikos administraciniu bylu teisenos istatymas. 2000 [The Law on Administrative Proceedings of the Republic of Lithuania], Valstybes zinios, 11 10 2000, No. 85-2566.

Lietuvos Respublikos teritorije planavimo estatymas. 2004 [The Law on Territorial Planning of the Republic of Lithuania], Valstybes zinios, 07 02 2004, No. 21-617.

Lindgren, T.; Castell, P. 2008. Open space management in residential areas--how it is organised and why, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 12(3): 141-160. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2008.12.141-160

Majamaa, W.; Junnila, S.; Doloi, H.; Niemisto, E. 2008. Enduser oriented public-private partnerships in real estate industry, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 12(1): 1-17. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2008.12.1-17

McDonald, S.; Malys, N.; Maliene, V. 2009. Urban regeneration for sustainable communities: A case study, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(1): 49-59. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.49-59

Mickaityte, A.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Kaklauskas, A.; Tupenaite, L. 2008. The concept model of sustainable buildings refurbishment, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 12(1): 53-68. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2008.12.53-68

Miller, Ch. J. M.; Packham, G. A.; Pickernell, D. G.; Mcgovern, M. 2004. Building for the future: The potential importance of the construction industry in Welsh economic development policy, Construction Management and Economics 22(5): 533-540. doi:10.1080/01446190310001649128

Mitkus, S. 2004. Statybos dalyviu rizika ir atsakomybe uz statybos produktu defektus [Risk and liability of parties in the construction process for defects of construction products], Technological and Economic Development of Economy 10(3): 109-115.

Mitkus, S.; Sostak, O. R. 2008a. Peculiarities of defence of public and private interests, Socialiniai tyrimai [Social Researches] 2(12): 75-93.

Mitkus, S.; Sostak, O. R. 2008b. Modelling the process for defence of third party rights infringed while implementing construction investment projects, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 14(2): 208-223. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2008.14.208-223

Mitkus, S.; Sostak, O. R. 2009. Preservation of healthy and harmonious residential and work environment during urban developent, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 13(4): 339-357. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2009.13.339-357

Nollke, M. 2007. Kaip iveikti neapibreztuma: optimaliu sprendime priemimo budai [How to overcome uncertainty: methods for optimal decisions]. [cited 2 April 2008]. Available from Internet: <http://www.elitarium. ru/2007/01/09/tekhniki_vyrabotki_optimalnykh_reshenijj. html>.

Park, M.; Chu, Y.; Lee, H.-S.; Kim, W. 2009. Evaluation methods for construction projects, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 15(4): 349-359. doi:10.3846/1392-3730.2009.15.349-359

Petrovic, J.; Ivkovic, I.; Vujacic, I.; Zezelj, S. 2009. Possibilities of buses on alternative fuel in public urban transport in elgrade, Technological and Economic Development of Economy 15(1): 78-89. doi:10.3846/1392-8619.2009.15.78-89

Ribeiro, L. F. 2008. Urban regeneration economics: The case of Lisbon's old downtown, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 12(3): 203-213. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2008.12.203-213

Ross Quinlan, J. 1993. C 4.5: Programs for Machine learning. Morgan Kaufmann Publishers, Inc.

Sostak, O. R.; Kutut, V. 2009. Neteisetos statybi pletros tyrimas Kursiu nerijos nacionaliniame parke [Investigation of expansion of illegal construction in the national park of Curonian spit), Verslas: teorija ir praktika [Business: Theory and Practice] 10(3): 223-232. doi:10.3846/1648-0627.2009.10.223-232

Taha, H. A. 1997. Operations research: An introduction. 6th Edition. Prentice Hall.

The Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania. 2006. Lietuvos vyriausiojo administracinio teismo 2006 m. vasario 20 d. sprendimas administracineje byloje pareiskejai A. S., B. S. ir T. Z. pries Vilniaus m. savivaldybes administracija, Nr. [A.sup.11]-792/2006 [The resolution of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 20 February 2006 in the administrative case the Applicants A. S., B. S. and T. Z. vs. the Administration of Vilnius City Municipality, No. [A.sup.11]-792/2006]. [cited 25 September 2007]. Available from Internet: <http://www.lvat.lt/ Default.aspx?item=nutart&lang=1>.

The Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania. 2007a. Lietuvos vyriausiojo administracinio teismo 2007 m. sausio 19 d. nutartis administracineje byloje pareiskejai T. Z. pries Vilniaus m. savivaldybes administracija, Nr. [A.sup.3]-64-07 [The judgement of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 19 January 2007 in the administrative case The Applicant T. Z. vs. the Administration of Vilnius City Municipality, No. [A.sup.3]-64-07]. [cited 25 September 2007]. Available from Internet: <http://www.lvat.lt/Default. aspx?item=nutart&lang=1>.

The Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania. 2007b. Lietuvos vyriausiojo administracinio teismo 2007 m. sausio 26 d. nutartis administracineje byloje pareiskejai O. S., L. K. pries Vilniaus m. savivaldybes administracija, Nr. A14-110-07 [The judgement of the Supreme Administrative Court of Lithuania of 26 January 2007 in the administrative case The Applicant O.S., L. K vs. the Administration of Vilnius City Municipality, No. A14-11007]. [cited 25 September 2007]. Available from Internet: <http://www.lvat.lt/Default.aspx?item=nutart&lang=1>.

Turskis, Z.; Zavadskas, E. K.; Zagorskas, J. 2006. Sustainable city compactness evaluation on the basis of GIS and ayes rule, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 10(3): 185-207.

Urbanavieiene, V.; Kaklauskas, A.; Zavadskas, E. K. 2009. The conceptual model of constructional and real estate negotiation, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 13(1): 53-70. doi:10.3846/1648-715X.2009.13.53-70

Viteikiene, M.; Zavadskas, E. K. 2007. Evaluating the sustainability of Vilnius city residential areas, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 13(2): 149-155.

Vrubliauskas, D. 2005. Miesto bendruomeniu vaidmuo tausojant istorines aplinkos savituma [The role of urban communities in preservation of distinctive features of historical environment], Urbanistika ir architektura [Town Planning and Architecture] 29(1): 33-36.

Yang, J.; Shen, G. Q.; Ho, M.; Drew, D. S.; Chan, A. P. C. 2009. Exploring critical success factors for stakeholder management in construction Projects, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 15(4): 337-348. doi:10.3846/1392-3730.2009.15.337-348

Zavadskas, E. K.; Kaklauskas, A.; Vainiunas, P.; Saparauskas, J. 2004. A model of sustainable urban development formation, International Journal of Strategic Property Management 8(4): 219-229.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Kaklauskas, A.; Turskis, Z.; Kalibatas, D. 2009. An approach to multi-attribute assessment of indoor environment before and after refurbishment of dwellings, Journal of Environmental Engineering and Landscape Management 17(1): 5-11. doi:10.3846/1648-6897.2009.17.5-11

Zavadskas, E. K.; Kaklauskas, A. 2005. Working out a rational model of Lithuanian construction industry development, Journal of Business Economics and Management 6(2): 71-80.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Kaklauskas, A. 2008. Model for Lithuanian construction industry development, Transformations in Business & Economics 7(1): 152-168.

Zavadskas, E. K.; Turskis, Z.; Tamosaitiene, J. 2010. Risk assessment of construction projects, Journal of Civil Engineering and Management 16(1): 33-46. doi:10.3846/jcem.2010.03

Olga Regina Sostak (1), Sigute Vakriniene (2)

Department of Law, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223 Vilnius, Lithuania

E-mails: (1) [email protected] (corresponding author); (2) [email protected]

Received 14 Jun. 2010; accepted 31 Jan. 2011

Olga Regina SOSTAK. A PhD student at the Department of Law, Vilnius Gedminas Technical University (VGTU). Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223 Vilnius, Lithuania. MA in Civil Engineering (2006, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University). Research interests: land planning, construction investment, decision making, stochastic programming.

Sigute VAKRINIENE. A graduate in mathematics from Vilnius University (1963). Doctor (1972). Associate Professor at the Faculty of Fundamental Science, the Department of Mathematical Statistic, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, Sauletekio al. 11, LT-10223 Vilnius, Lithuania. Research interests: operation research-game theory, stochastic programming.
Table 1. A numerical expression of behaviour strategies for the
investor shown in the tree

No.   PROFIT               LTL                %

1     P = P3 = P4 =      LTL 1m *            100%
2     P1 =               LTL 500,000 **      50%
3     P2 = P5 = P9 =     LTL 950,000 ***     95%
4     P6 = P11 = P7 =    LTL 980,000 ****    98%
5     P8 = P10 = P12 =   LTL 950,000 *****   95%
6     N =                LTL 1 mi ******     -100%

* successful completion of the construction investment project;

** changed project solutions cut the profits by LTL 500,000;

*** a peace treaty is signed with the interested community,
profit decreases by LTL 50,000;

**** the annual litigation expenditures make up LTL 10,000
(2 years), thus profit decreases by LTL 20,000;

***** the annual litigation expenditures make up LTL 10,000
(3 years), plus LTL 20,000 for forensic examinations; thus
profit decreases by LTL 50,000;

****** the construction investment project is cancelled.

Table 2. Optimal investor's strategies calculated using the
programme code developed in the EXEL environment

Situation     f ([S.sub.5])    [x.sup.*.sub.5]

[S.sub.5]          -25         [x.sub.52] = 1

Situation     f ([S.sub.3])    [x.sup.*.sub.3]

[S.sub.3]          -25         [x.sub.32] = 1

Situation     f ([S.sub.4])    [x.sup.*.sub.4]

[S.sub.4]          950         [x.sub.42] = 1

Situation     f ([S.sub.2])    [x.sup.*.sub.2]

[S.sub.2]          950         [x.sub.21] = 1

Situation     f ([S.sub.1])    [x.sup.*.sub.1]

[S.sub.1]         968.5        [x.sub.13] = 1
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有