Interest rates and aggregate inventory investment.
Larkins, Daniel ; Gill, Gurmukh S.
THIS article suggests a new view of how interest rates may effect
inventory demand, Specifically, it suggests that when real short-term
interest rates surpass previous peak levels, firms revise their
inventory management techniques; when interest rates recede from a peak,
the revamped management techniques remain in place, affecting inventory
holdings until a new peak in interest rates is recorded.
Using this new "ratchet" approach to incorporating the
effect of interest rates leads to the following main findings:
* The interest rate variable is a statistically significant
determinant of aggregate inventory investment. Many earlier studies
failed to find a significant interest rate effect.
* The interest rate variable, along with expected sales and
beginning stocks of inventories, explains aggregate inventory investment
rather well.
* Discrepancies between desired and actual levels of inventories
are removed slowly; it takes about three quarters to eliminate one-half
of a given discrepancy.
* The relationship between inventory investment, on the one hand,
and expected sales and the interest rate variable, on the other, appears
to have been relatively stable over the 1952-84 period.
Interest rate ratchet
Many earlier investigtions failed to establish a significant effect
of the rate of interest on inventory demand. This failure, in the face
of the widespread theoretical conviction that cost considerations are an
important determinant of inventory investment, suggests that the effect
of interest rates may be more subtle than commonly supposed. Research
on the demand for money suggests a plausible mechanism for incorporating
interest rates in inventory investment equations.
Some analysts at the Federal Reserve have found that money demand
equations perform better if an interest rate ratchet variable is
included in the equation. A ratchet variable is a variable that moves
in only one direction, usually upwards. Formally, a ratchet variable R
that represents the real interest rate r may be defined as:
The rationale for including a ratchet variable in a demand for
money equation is straightforward. When interest rates reach a new
peak, the opportunity cost of holding money becomes high enough to
trigger investment in new cash management techniques. When interest
rates recede from the peak, the new management techniques are not
jettisoned, but remain in place until a new interest rate peak is
recorded.
The same rationale may be put forward to explain the effect of
interest rates on inventories, by changing the "cost of holding
money" to the "cost of holding inventories" and "new
cash management techniques" to "new inventory management
techniques." These new inventory management techniques may take a
number of forms. They may entail consolidation of storage facilities,
personnel training, the acquisition of new equipment (which may range
from conveyor belts and for lift trucks to computers), etc. Effecting
these changes may involve significant outlays over extended periods of
time. These and other innovations in inventory management techniques
would all have the same goal, namely to reduce the size of inventories
relative to sales, thereby reducing the cost of holding inventories.
Model and data
The ratchet interest rate variable (R.sub.t) and the level of
expected sales (XS.sub.t) are assumed to determine the optimal inventory
stock (INV.sup.*.sub.t) according to the following specification:
By allowing expected sales to scale the ratchet variable, this
specification implies, reasonably, that the effect of the interest rate
ratchet increases as expected sales increase.
Equation (1) is used in conjunction with another equation, known as
the stock-adjustment (or partial adjustment) model, which states that
discrepancies between optimal and actual inventories are eliminated
gradually:
The speed at which discrepancies are eliminated is given by
[lambda]. If [lambda] = 0, the discrepancy is never reduced; if
[lambda] = 1, the entire discrepancy is eliminated in the current
period. The final term in equation (2), u.sub.t, incorporates all other
factors that impinge on the change in inventories, the most obvious of
which is unexpected sales, or "sales surprises" (SS.sub.t).
Sales surprises should be allowed to enter the estimating equation
explicitly. Their effect on inventory change is a matter of interest in
its own right for what it reveals about the bufferstock model of
inventory investment. Moveover, failure to take explicit account of
SS.sub.t could bias the estimated coefficients of the other variables in
the equation.
Substituting equation (1) into equation (2), letting sales
surprises enter explicitly, and defining the remaining "other
factors= as u'.sub.t, yields: or
Clearly, equations (3) and (3a) are equivalent. The former
explains the change in inventories (i.e., inventory investment) between
the end of quarter t-1 and the end of quarter t; the latter explains the
level of inventory at the end of quarter t.
This article concentrates on the specification given by equation 3,
because analysts usually are more interested in inventory investment
than they are in the absolute level of inventories. Whichever variant is
used for regression purposes, however, it should be noted that the
estimated coefficient for the sales variable will be an estimate of the
product of [lambda] and b.sub.1, and the estimated coefficient for the
interest rate variable will be an estimate of the product of [lambda]
and b.sub.2. As a result, the estimated coefficients will measure the
immediate, or short-run, impact of a change in sales or interest rates.
To obtain the eventual, or long-run, impact, the estimated coefficients
must be divided by the estimate of the adjustment coefficient, [lambda].
In estimating equation (3), inventories and sales were taken from
the national income and product accounts (NIPA's). NIPA table 5.11
presents aggregate end-of-quarter inventories (seasonally adjusted), in
billions of 1972 dollars. The quarter-to-quarter change in these
inventory stocks is used as the dependent variable in the regression.
NIPA table 5.11 also shows two measures of sales: business final
sales and business final sales of goods and structures, both in billions
of 1972 dollars. The use of either sales measure in an inventory demand
equation can be justified. On the one hand, because it is goods that
are held in inventory, it is natural to assume that the production (and
sale) of goods (and, possibly, structures) far outweights the production
of services as a determination of inventory demand. On the other hand,
because inventories are held to support the activities of the entire
economy, it is just as natural to assume that the inventory demand of
the total (business) sales. There is no a priori reason for preferring
one sales measure over the other, and regression results are much the
same regardless of which is chosen. The regressions reported below use
the total business final sales series. (Table 5.11 presents final sales
as quarterly totals, but at monthly rates. For ease of interpreting the
regression results, the final sales series has been converted to
quarterly rates--i.e., has been multiplied by 3.)
Equation (3) uses expected sales and sales surprises. Many
techniques are available for generating expected sales from actual
sales. One of the simplest is to assume that expected sales in quarter
t equal actual sales in quarter t-1. This technique has been used in
many studies of inventory investment. Sales surprises, of course, are
calculated as the difference between actual and expected sales.
The real short-term rate of interest is crudely approximated by
subtracting an inflation rate from a nominal interest rate. The rate on
commercial paper (4-6 months) serves as the nominal short-term interest
rate. A price index for inventory stock is the obvious choice for the
price variable; such a price index is not readily available, however.
An implicit price deflator for inventory stocks is available, but it
reflects both price changes and changes in the composition of
inventories. In instances where compositional changes can safely be
ignored, deflators may be adequate indicators of price movements; in the
case of inventories--which have rapid turnover--it is not clear that
compositional changes can be safely ignored. In the regressions
reported below, the deflator for final sales (in which compositional
changes are presumed to be less important) is used as the price
variable. Quarter-to-quarter changes (at annual rates) in the deflator
are subtracted from the nominal interest rate to obtain the real rate,
which is expressed as a decimal (e.g., 4 percent = 0.04).
Construction of the interest rate ratchet variable is
straightforward. When the real rate is below its previous peak level,
the ratchet variable is equal to the previous peak level; when the real
rate rises above its previous peak level, the ratchet variable is equal
to the current real rate.
The real rate and the ratchet variable derived from it are shown in
chart 1. The rachet varable shows very little variation--it changes
only nine times--over the sample period, and it is certainly far
different from the real rate itself.
Results
Ordinary least-squares estimation of equation 3 yields:
Figures in parentheses are absolute values of t-statistics; rho is
the first order autocorrelation coefficient from A Cochrane-Orcutt
correction.
The ratchet variable has the correct (negative) sign and is
significant at the 5-percent level. The coefficients of expected sales
and lagged inventory stock carry the correct signs and are highly
significant. Sales surprises enter the equation with a negative (albeit
very small and statistically insignificant) coefficient, as implied by
the buffer-stock model of inventory investment.
The coefficient of the lagged inventory stock is of particular
interest, because it is a measure of the speed with which discrepancies
between optimal and actual inventories are removed. The estimated speed
of 21 percent per quarter implies that it takes about three quarters to
eliminate one-half of a given discrepancy. This speed is slower than
might seem reasonable on a priori grounds, but it is quite consistent
with the adjustment speeds found in many earlier studies.
The overall goodness of fit, as measured by R.sup.-2, is
satisfactory. As chart 2 shows, the equation tracks actual inventory
change quite well during the sample period--perhaps better than one
might expect from an equation with an R.sup.-2 of 0.59.
As was mentioned earlier, the estimated coefficients of the
expected sales and interest rate ratchest variables represent the
short-run impacts of these variables on inventory investment; the
long-run coefficents are found by dividing the estimated coefficients by
the estimated speed of adjustment (table 1).
Table 1 also shows the implied elasticity of inventory stocks with
respect to expected sales and the interest rate ratchet. The long-run
elasticity of stocks with respect to expected sales is 1.1; a 1-percent
increase in expected sales induces, eventually, an approximately
1-percent increase in inventory stocks. The elasticity with respect to
the interest rate ratchet variable is very small: below -0.1 in the long
run. Nevertheless, such a value implies that a 1-percentage-point
increase in the level of the ratchet from 4-1/2 percent to 5-1/2 percent
would have led, eventually, to a reduction in inventory stocks of more
than $5 billion (1972 dollars).
The deflator for final sales was used in constructing the ratchet
variable shown in chart 1 and used in the regression. Ratchet variables
were also constructed using several alternative price measures. Table 2
defines these alternatives ratchets and, in column 1, shows the
t-statistic of each when it is scaled by expected sales and used in the
regression. In an effort to determine whether scaling materially
affects the results, column 2 of the table shows the t-statistics for
each of the ratchets when it is not scaled by expected sales.
Regardless of the precise specification, the ratchet does quite well; in
all cases, it is significant at the 10-percent level or better.
Although there are difficulties in applying the F test for
structural stability to regressions estimated with autocorrelation
corrections, and although there are no obvious points at which to check
for structural shifts, the test was conducted, with arbitrary breaks
(alternatively) in the first midpoint of the sample period) and of 1981
(before the ratchet makes its F-statistic statistically significant. At
the 5-percent level of significance, the critical value of the
F-ratio--with 4 and 124 degrees of freedom--is approximately 2.45; the
calculated F-ratios were 1.47 (for the break in the first quarter of
1968) and 1.74 (for the break in the first quarter of 1981). The null
hypothesis of structural stability cannot be rejected, but because of
the difficulties mentioned above, this finding can only be interpreted
as suggestive, not conclusive.