A Note on the Impact of Hedonics and Computers on Real GDP.
Landefeld, J. Steven ; Grimm, Bruce T.
THERE has been recent speculation about the impact of the use of
hedonic price indexes in the measurement of real computer hardware and
software expenditures in the U.S. national income and product accounts
(NIPA's) and on the extent to which their use may be responsible
both for the pickup in real gross domestic product (GDP) and
productivity growth and for the continued low rate of measured inflation
in the United States since 1995. Strong growth in computer sales and
rapid declines in computer prices have made a significant contribution
to economic growth; because measured growth depends on prices, if the
declines in computer prices are overstated, the contribution of
computers to real GDP will be overstated. This issue is central to the
debate over the performance of the U.S. economy relative to that of
other countries and to the debate over whether the pickup in the U.S.
economy in the latter half of the 1990's represents a fundamental
change in the structure of the economy or whether it is due to changes
in measurement.
A review of the data shows that only a small share of the increase
in measured growth in the latter half of the 1990's is associated
with the use of hedonic price indexes. In addition, there is no evidence
of an overstatement in the decline in computer prices. Hedonic price
indexes for computers produce results that are quite robust and that are
virtually the same as those produced by a carefully constructed
traditional price index for computers.
The perception that the use of hedonic price indexes is largely
responsible for the pickup in measured U.S. growth appears, in part, to
be founded on misunderstandings about the nature of hedonic price
indexes, the extent to which they are used in the accounts, the possible
discontinuities in BEA's time series due to the introduction of
hedonic price indexes, the importance of using chain-type indexes in
computing real GDP and prices, the robustness of hedonic price
estimates, the differences between hedonic price and traditional price
measures, and the impact of BEA's methodology for deflating
computer software. In addition, the perceptions about the relative
impacts of these computer measurement issues on economic growth do not
consider other measurement issues that probably impart a negative bias
to measured economic growth.
What are hedonic price indexes?
Despite their unfortunate name, hedonic price indexes are simply
statistical tools for developing standardized per unit prices for goods,
such as computers, whose quality and characteristics are changing
rapidly. Just as traditional price indexes measure the change in the
price of strawberries by holding fixed the weight of the strawberries in
a box rather than by the price per box, computers need to--at a
minimum--be priced by holding fixed the computing power in the computer
box. Traditional price indexes are well adapted to measuring the price
of relatively standardized products, but they encounter problems--in
terms of data requirements and methods--when the characteristics, market
shares, and prices of a class of products are changing rapidly. Hedonic
price indexes are one means of addressing these empirical and
methodological problems.
Traditional price indexes use the "matched model" method
to measure the relative change in the price of a market basket of goods,
holding its quality and characteristics constant. The constancy of
quality and characteristics is maintained by sample design, and great
efforts are made at the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) to ensure that
exactly the same set of items is priced each month.
Hedonic price indexes developed at BLS and elsewhere use a
statistical model that employs a regression of the prices of a basket of
goods on a set of qualities or characteristics of those goods. Using the
statistical relationship between observed price changes and changes in
the characteristics and qualities of the goods, a hedonic price index is
then developed that measures relative price changes while holding
quality and characteristics constant. Thus, the hedonic price index is
doing the same thing statistically that a matched-model price index does
through sample design.(1)
How widespread and important is the use of hedonic techniques?
The use of hedonic price indexes is increasing, and the components
that are deflated by hedonic techniques account for 18 percent of GDP.
For most of these components, the impact of using hedonic techniques is
small because the matched models used earlier picked up most of the
quality changes. For example, the introduction of hedonic price indexes
by BLS slightly raised the rate of price increase for VCR's and for
rent but slightly lowered it for televisions.
The main area in which the use of hedonic price indexes has had a
large impact is in computers and peripheral equipment, whose
quality-adjusted prices have been falling at an average annual rate of
about 24 percent in recent years. In 1998, the components for which
hedonic price indexes were used contributed a negative 0.2 percentage
point to the 1.3-percentage-point increase in the GDP price index;
however, among these components, computers and peripheral equipment
contributed a negative 0.4 percentage point and thus more than accounted
for the negative contribution.
Discontinuities
In December 1985, BEA introduced quality-adjusted price indexes for
computers and peripherals that were developed using hedonic techniques.
Prior to the development of the hedonic-based indexes, the price index
for computers was held constant at the base period value of 100; this
treatment, which differed from that for most other NIPA price indexes
for goods, faced increasing skepticism in a period of declining prices
and increasing capabilities of computers and computer systems. Working
with IBM, BEA developed hedonic price indexes for computers and
peripherals that were designed to capture the equivalent of the price
per unit of computing power through the use of multiple regressions that
explained the differences in the prices of computers and peripherals of
different types and vintages as functions of their characteristics. The
first index covered 1969-85, and BEA later developed estimates back to
1959; before 1959, computers were of little importance and were not
separately identified in the NIPA's, thereby minimizing the
discontinuity. When the estimates of computer software prices were
introduced, they also extended back to 1959.(2)
Thus, when one looks--as several authors have--at the difference
between the real GDP growth rate in 1973-95 and that in 1995-99, the
pickup in the later period cannot be attributed to discontinuities
(table 1). For 1973-95, real GDP grew at an average annual rate of 2.8
percent, and private fixed investment in computers and software
accounted for 0.2 percentage point of that growth. In 1995-99, real GDP
grew at an average annual rate of 4.2 percent, and computers and
software accounted for 0.7 percentage point of that growth.(3) In other
words, the real GDP growth rate in 1995-99 was 1.4 percentage points
more than that in 1973-95, and computers and software contributed 0.4
percentage point to that difference, a significant share but not nearly
enough to explain the overall increase in growth.
Table 1.--Contributions of Private Fixed Investment in Computers
and Software to Percent Changes in Real GDP
[Average annual rates]
Contributions (percentage points)
Real GDP
(percent change) Computers Software Sum
1973-95 2.78 .16 .08 .24
1995-99 4.15 .37 .31 .68
Difference 1.37 .21 .23 .44
Chain-type weights versus fixed weights
Comparisons of U.S. growth rates with those of other countries are
also affected by the choice of weighting methodology. Although the
introduction of hedonic price indexes for computers raised the measured
rate of real GDP growth (relative to the previous assumption of no price
change), the concurrent adoption of chain-type price and quantity
indexes lowered it (relative to the previous fixed-weight methodology
used by the United States and currently used by most other countries).
BEA introduced chain-type weights to measure real GDP and prices in 1995
in order to eliminate the bias associated with using fixed weights.
Chain-type indexes use adjacent period weights to construct an index for
each period-annual percent changes in real GDP for 1997-98, for example,
are calculated using weights from 1997 and 1998--and the indexes for
each period are chained (multiplied) together to form a time series that
allows for changes in relative prices and the composition of output over
time.(4) In contrast, fixed-weighted measures are calculated with a
single set of weights over time.
In the index number literature, it has been long recognized that
output measures that use fixed-price weights of a single period tend to
misstate growth as one moves away from the base period. This tendency,
often called substitution bias, reflects the fact that the commodities
for which output grows rapidly tend to be those for which prices
increase less than average or decline. Using past prices to weight these
goods places too high a weight on their growth and overstates real GDP
growth. When chain-type indexes are used, the goods with rapid growth
tend to receive lower weights, and growth in real GDP is reduced. For
example, the replacement of the fixed-weight price index with the
chain-type price index in 1995 reduced the average annual rate of growth
of real GDP during the economic expansion in 1991:I-1995:II by 0.5
percentage point. (Roughly three-fifths of this reduction reflected
falling computer prices, and the rest reflected changes in the relative
prices of other goods and services.)
As the United States found, a system with fixed weights puts too
high a weight on those goods and services--such as computers--whose
prices are falling and thus overstates real GDP growth for recent
periods. Moreover, some observers may be assessing the impact of
introducing quality-adjusted prices for computers into other
countries' estimates without realizing that most other countries
use fixed-weighted systems.
Most countries periodically update their weights, but even periodic
updating of fixed weights does not adequately address substitution bias
when there are significant changes in relative prices or when the period
between updates is long. Most of these countries plan to move to
chain-type price indexes, as recommended by the international system of
guidelines on national accounting in the 1993 System of National
Accounts. If the U.S. experience is any guide, the introduction of a
chain index at the same time as the introduction of a hedonic price
index for computers will moderate the impact of the computer price index
and may even significantly offset it by eliminating the substitution
bias associated with noncomputer goods whose prices are falling. This
offset will be especially important for countries that are not large
producers of computers and computer components; indeed, if a country is
a large importer of these goods, there could be almost no net impact on
GDP. In such a case, introduction of a falling price for computers will
raise real investment, but this rise will be offset by a corresponding
increase in real imports, which is subtracted in calculating GDP.
Robustness
As is the case with any statistical method, the results from
hedonic regressions are subject to error, but the hedonic indexes for
computers appear to produce consistent results. A recent survey of the
literature by Ernst Berndt and Neal Rappaport (2000) suggests a fairly
robust central tendency among hedonic estimates of computer prices over
time. Table 2 compares the rates of decline of computer prices reported
by a number of authors for a wide variety of time periods and types of
computers. The estimated rates of decline in quality-adjusted prices
range from 14 percent per annum to 40 percent per annum, depending on
the time period and on the type of computer examined. The range narrows
when similar time periods are examined; for example, the results for
personal computers (PC's) for the latter half of the 1990's
cluster around an average annual rate of decline of between 30 percent
and 40 percent.
Table 2.--Hedonic Studies of Computer Prices
Author(1) Prices:
Computer Time Annual
type period rates of
change
Chow mainframe 1960-65 -21
Triplett mainframe 1953-72 -27
Cole et al. mainframe 1972-84 -19
Cartwright mainframe 1972-84 -14
Gordon mainframe 1951-84 -22
Cohen personal computer 1982-87 -25 to -27
Berndt and personal computer 1982-89 -23 to -25
Griliches
Berndt, mobile personal
Griliches, computer 1989-92 -23 to -24
and Rappaport desktop personal
computer 1989-92 -31 to -32
Nelson, Tanguy, desktop personal
and Patterson computer 1984-91 -18 to -25
laptop personal
computer 1990-98 -40
Chwelos desktop personal
computer 1992-98 -32 to -35
personal computer 1976-83 -18
Berndt and personal computer 1983-89 -18
Rappaport(2) personal computer 1989-94 -32
personal computer 1994-99 -39
Aizcorbe, desktop personal
Corrado, computer 1994:IV-1998:IV -31
and Doms notebook personal
computer 1994:IV-1998:IV -26
personal computer,
weighted
average.(3) 1994: IV-1998:IV -30
BEA price index personal computer 1994:IV-1998:IV -32
(1) See "Bibliography" for more complete citations.
(2) Results reported for "all pooled" regression, (Berndt
and Rappaport 2000).
(3) Weights are 0.75 for desktops, 0.25 for notebooks.
Berndt and Rappaport also evaluated the impact of using varying
parameters over time to address a long-standing concern about
hedonics--that the estimated coefficients of performance characteristics
are unstable over time. They attempted to overcome this problem by
estimating individual-year regressions and using methods analogous to
the construction of Paasche and Laspeyres chain-type indexes to
construct price-index time series; this was done separately for mobile
and desktop PC's.(5) Their approach produced four price indexes;
the mean of the four alternative (time varying) indexes was a
39.8-percent rate of decline in the prices of PC's in 1995-99, 6.5
percentage points more than the 33.3-percent average rate of decline in
the BEA hedonic price index for PC's over the same period (table
3).
Table 3.--Price Indexes for Computers: Average Annual Rates of
Decline, 1995-99
Percent
NIPA private fixed investment:
Computers and peripheral equipment -24.2
Personal computers -33.3
Berndt and Rappaport(1):
Desktop personal computers, unit prices -8.7
Mobile personal computers, unit prices -4.6
Personal computers, mean of alternative hedonic indexes -39.8
(1) Source: Berndt and Rappaport 2000.
Relation to traditional price measures
One of the principal obstacles to estimating the impact of hedonic
price indexes for computers is the lack of traditionally measured price
indexes for computers. Fortunately, two recent, but very different,
studies--the aforementioned study by Berndt and Rappaport and one by Ana
Aizcorbe, Carol Corrado, and Mark Doms (2000)--provide some new price
information. Berndt and Rappaport estimated the average unit prices for
computers and found an 8.7-percent annual rate of decline for desktop
PC's and a 4.6-percent annual rate of decline for mobile PC's
in 1995-99 (table 3). Although such an index makes no allowance for the
increased computing power, storage capacity, speed, or graphics
capability over this period, it allows the calculation of a crude
measure of the contribution of quality change to the growth in real GDP.
If we assume that desktop PC's account for three-fourths of the
market and that mobile PC's account for one-fourth, the average
rate of decline in unit prices for PC's was 7.7 percent, compared
with a 33.3-percent rate of decline in BEA's hedonic price index, a
difference of 25.6 percentage points. If we weight this difference using
the weight for computers and peripherals from the NIPA's, the
quality change in PC's adds, at most, one-quarter of a percentage
point to the estimate of average annual real GDP growth over the
period.(6)
This "what-if" exercise using unit prices may provide a
rough estimate of the impact of quality change for computers, but a more
instructive exercise is to compare the hedonic price index to a
traditional matched-model price index, such as the one recently
constructed by Aizcorbe et al. They collected quarterly data on PC
prices and sales to construct a chain-weighted price index for PC's
in which the weights were current-dollar shares for each period; no
explicit adjustments were made to reflect quality differences across
models. They found that the decline in the prices of PC's with
Pentium I processors when Pentium II processors were being introduced,
the decline in the prices of PC's with Pentium II processors when
Celeron processors were introduced, and so on, represented the price
reductions that were necessary to make the older units competitive with
the newer higher quality units. The price indexes that they constructed
are remarkably close to the corresponding hedonic price indexes (table
4). Their estimates of the average annual rates of price decline in
1994:IV-1998:IV were 30.6 percent for desktop computers and 24.6 percent
for notebook computers. Their estimates of hedonic price indexes for the
same period showed a 31.0-percent average annual rate of decline for
desktop computers and a 26.3-percent average annual rate of decline for
notebook computers. BEA's price index for personal computers
declined at an average annual rate of 32.5 percent over the same period.
Table 4.--Price Indexes for Computers: Average Annual Rates of
Decline, 1994:1V to 1998:1V
Percent
NIPA Private fixed investment: Traditional Hedonic
Computers and peripheral equipment ... -23.7
Personal computers ... -32.5
Aizcorbe et al. (1):
Desktop personal computers -30.6 -31.0
Notebook computers -24.6 -26.3
Weighted average(2) -29.1 -29.8
(1) Source: Aizcorbe et al. 2000.
(2) Weights are 0.75 for desktops, 0.25 for notebooks.
Software prices
BEA uses a hedonic price index (as well as a matched-model index)
in the estimation of real prepackaged software investment for 1985-93,
but this index declines more slowly than BEA's computer price
index, and its impact is largely offset by BEA's use of cost-based
estimates in constructing the price indexes for the other two components
of software-custom software and own-account software (charts 1 and 2).
BEA's price index for custom software is a weighted average of the
prepackaged-software index and a cost-based price index; the price index
for own-account software is a pure cost-based index. (A paper describing
BEA's methodology for software is on BEA's Web site at
<www.bea.doc.gov>.) By construction, BEA's cost-based indexes
assume roughly zero growth in multifactor productivity A number of
observers have questioned this conservative methodology, but until BEA
is able to obtain better indexes, the contribution of software
investment to real GDP growth is likely to be little different than its
contribution to current-dollar GDP growth, so the net impact of hedonics on software prices is minimal.
[Charts 1-2 OMITTED]
Other factors
Although much attention has recently been focused on whether real
GDP growth in the latter half of the 1990's has been overstated as
a result of the use of hedonic-based price estimates for computers and
peripherals and for computer software, there are other reasons to
suspect that growth--especially that related to high-tech
innovations--has been understated. First, a number of the industries
that are heavy users of the new information technology, such as
education and certain financial services, are deflated using cost-based
indexes or by input and partial output extrapolators. As noted above, if
nominal output is deflated by total cost indexes, there is roughly zero
multifactor productivity growth, or if real output is extrapolated by
labor inputs, there is no labor productivity growth (and if capital
inputs grow faster than labor inputs, there is negative multifactor
productivity growth). Recently, BEA replaced its input extrapolation for
banking services with a new BLS banking services index; this replacement
raised real GDP growth rates in recent years by an average of 0.05
percentage point. If similar indexes were introduced into the remaining
20 percent of GDP that is still estimated using cost and input-based
indexes, real GDP growth might be revised up substantially.
(1.) In practice, statistical agencies employ a mix of hedonic and
matched-model techniques to produce hedonic estimates. For example, BLS
uses the results from hedonic regressions to adjust for quality
differences between the prices of models going out of production and the
prices of new models replacing them in the sample. The results from the
monthly price surveys are then used to produce the relevant producer
price and consumer price indexes.
(2.) BEA now uses detailed BLS price indexes for computers,
peripherals, parts and for some types of software; these indexes are
aggregated using BEA chain weights to produce chain-type price indexes.
(3.) The contribution of final sales of computers and
software--which also includes personal consumption expenditures,
exports, imports, and government--was also 0.7 percent, as imports
largely offset the other components.
(4.) The chain-type indexes that BEA uses are described in the
price index literature as Fisher Ideal indexes. These indexes, which are
the geometric means of Paasche and Laspeyres chain-type indexes, have
the characteristic of minimizing substitution bias, which the Paasche
and Laspeyres indexes do not. For a more complete discussion, see Parker
and Triplett (1996).
(5.) Laspeyres indexes are price indexes that use past-period
weights to measure changes in relative prices, whereas Paasche indexes
are price indexes that use current-period weights. For a description of
these indexes and other indexes, see Jack T. Triplett (1992).
Bibliography
Aizcorbe, Ana, Carol Corrado, and Mark Doms. 2000.
"Constructing Price and Quantity Indexes for High Technology
Goods." Paper presented at the National Bureau of Economic Research
Summer Institute 2000 session on Price, Output, and Productivity
Measurement. Cambridge, MA, July 31, 2000.
Berndt, Ernst R., and Zvi Griliches. 1993. "Price Indexes for
Microcomputers: An Exploratory Study." In Price Measurements and
Their Uses. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 57, edited by Murray F.
Foss, Marilyn Manser, and Allan H. Young, 63-93. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press, for the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Berndt, Ernst R., and Neal Rappaport. 2000. "Price and Quality
of Desktop and Mobile Personal Computers: A Quarter Century of
History." Paper presented at the National Bureau of Economic
Research Summer Institute 2000 session on Price, Output, and
Productivity Measurement. Cambridge, MA, July 31, 2000. Revised,
November 8, 2000.
Berndt, Ernst R., Zvi Griliches, and Neal Rappaport. 1995.
"Econometric Estimates of Price Indexes for Personal Computers in
the 1990's." Journal of Econometrics 68 (July 1995): 243-68.
Cartwright, David W. 1986. "Improved Deflation of Purchases of
Computers." SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS 66 (March 1986): 7-9.
Chow, Gregory. 1967. "Technological Change and the Demand for
Computers." American Economic Review 57 (December 1967): 1117-30.
Chwelos, Paul. 1999. "Hedonic Approaches to Measuring Price
and Quality Change in Personal Computer Systems." Ph.D.
dissertation, Faculty of Commerce and Business Administration,
University of British Columbia, December 1999.
Cohen, Jeremy M. 1988. "Rapid Change in the Personal Computer
Market: A Quality-Adjusted Hedonic Price Index, 1976-1987."
Master's thesis, Alfred P. Sloan School of Management,
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, May 1988.
Cole, Roseanne, Y.C. Chen, Joan A. Barquin-Stolleman, Ellen R.
Dulberger, Nathan Helvacian, and James H. Hodge. 1986.
"Quality-Adjusted Price Indexes for Computer Processors and
Selected Peripheral Equipment." SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS 66
(January 1986): 41-50.
Gordon, Robert J. 1971. "The Postwar Evolution of Computer
Prices." In Technology and Capital Formation, edited by Dale W.
Jorgenson and Ralph Landau, 77-125. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Nelson, Randy A., Tim L. Tanguay, and Christopher D. Patterson.
1994. "A Quality-Adjusted Price Index for Personal Computers."
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 12 (January 1994): 12-31.
Parker, Robert. P. and Jack E. Triplett. 1996. "Chain-Type
Measures of Real Output and Prices in the U.S. National Income and
Product Accounts: An Update" Business Economics 31 (October 1996):
37-43.
Triplett, Jack E. 1989. "Price and Technological Change in a
Capital Good: A Survey of Research on Computers" In Technology and
Capital Formation, edited by Dale W. Jorgenson and Ralph Landau,
127-213. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.
Triplett, Jack E. 1992. "Economic Theory and BEA's
Alternative Quantity and Price Indexes." SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS
72 (April 1992): 49-52.