Alternative measures of personal saving.
Perozek, Maria G. ; Reinsdorf, Marshall B.
THE personal saving rate, as defined in the national income and
product accounts (NIPA's), has declined sharply over the past two
decades, falling from a high of about 11 percent in the early 1980s to 1
percent in 2000. This sustained decline has generated concern that
saving is now too low to fund adequate capital accumulation or to ensure
that the baby boom generation will move through its retirement years
with reasonable financial security.
This article provides the necessary background for understanding
personal saving as defined in the NIPA's and its role in
determining aggregate capital accumulation and the financial status of
households. It also investigates several of the many possible
alternative measures of personal saving and wealth accumulation.
Changes in personal saving cannot generally be interpreted without
considering what is happening to other measures of saving and wealth
accumulation. For example, low personal saving rates may cause concern
that national saving--defined as the amount of national income left over
after all expenditures on goods and services other than capital items
are deducted--will be too low to fund adequate levels of the new capital
investments that power economic growth. However, personal saving is only
one component of national saving. Therefore, to evaluate concerns about
capital accumulation, one must examine trends in total national saving,
not just the personal sector's contribution to that total.
Likewise, a decline in personal saving does not necessarily mean
that households will have trouble financing their retirement years or
other consumption needs. Measures of household wealth provide a more
complete picture of the future consumption possibilities of households.
Moreover, wealth--along with income, interest rates, and some
others--has long been seen as a key variable in helping to explain
household spending. Changes in net wealth reflect both personal saving
and capital gains on existing assets. Capital gains are absent from
calculations of personal saving in the NIPA's because capital gains
are not a part of the NIPA concept of national income (see the box
"Definition of National Income and Saving in the
NIPA's"). However, they can be as important as personal saving
in determining the future consumption possibilities of households.
Indeed, over the last half of the 1990s, while personal saving declined
to record lows, ratios of household wealth to income rocketed to record
highs.
Definition of National Income and Saving in the NIPA's
Personal saving, business saving, and government saving
are the components of national saving. These components
are measures of deferred utilization of resources:
Current income not consumed for households; current
earnings retained within the firm for business; and revenues
not spent for government. Accordingly, national
saving is viewed as a key indicator of the extent to which
the Nation as a whole is setting aside resources today for
the purpose of increasing its future standard of living.
The definition of national saving in the national income
and product accounts (NIPA's) determines the total
amount of saving that can be attributed to persons, to
business, or to government. Net national saving measures
the portion of national income made available to fund
expansion of the capital stock. It is the amount of
national income left over after current (that is, non-investment)
expenditures are subtracted. National income
is, in turn, the amount of gross national product left over
after nonfactor income (primarily indirect business
taxes) and consumption of fixed capital (CFC) are subtracted.
Subtraction of CFC, or depreciation, is necessary
to account for the cost of replacing plant, equipment, and
software that wears out or becomes obsolete.
The definition of national income reflects the NIPA
goal of measuring production. The aggregate measure of
production, gross domestic product (GDP), is the market
value of the goods and services produced in the United
States. The NIPA concept of national income is, then, the
gross factor income arising from the production that
GDP measures, minus CFC, plus an adjustment for net
property income that U.S. residents receive from the rest
of the world.
Because national income is defined as originating from
current production of goods and services, it excludes
capital gains. Capital gains originate from revaluations of
existing assets rather than from production of new goods
and services. Besides insuring the conceptual consistency
of the NIPA's, the treatment of capital gains as separate
from national income has three noteworthy advantages.
First, with capital gains excluded from income, national
saving becomes conceptually equal to domestic investment
plus net foreign investment (though, as is shown in
NIPA table 5.1 on page D-14 in this issue, measured saving
differs from measured investment by an amount
known as "the statistical discrepancy"). Second, in making
consumption decisions, households appear to treat
capital gains differently from ordinary income, so a measure
of income that includes capital gains would not
relate as well to consumption as the NIPA concept of
income. Third, because capital gains tend to be volatile,
measures of income or saving that include them would
exhibit large fluctuations that would limit their usefulness.
National saving as defined in the NIPA's is also important
for understanding the behavior of business cycles
and the current-account balance. In particular, this measure
of saving and its relationship to investment play key
roles in Keynesian macroeconomic models, which allow
fluctuations in aggregate demand to affect national income
via a "multiplier" that depends on the marginal
propensity to consume. In addition, swings in national
saving affect external balances unless domestic investment
changes by the same amount; for example, in 1983,
a large fall in national saving was accompanied by a jump
in the current-account deficit. Similar effects can arise
from swings in domestic investment that are unaccompanied
by changes in national saving; for example, in
1999-2000, net foreign investment turned sharply negative
as private domestic investment rose while national
saving changed very little.
Alternatives to the definition of income that is used in
the NIPA's are, of course, possible; indeed, how to define
income has long been a subject of debate among economists.
Haig (1921) and Simons (1938), in discussions of
the income tax, define income as consumption plus
change in wealth, which has the effect of including capital
gains. At the opposite pole is Fisher, who identifies
income with consumption (1906, 164) and treats it as a
flow of services rendered by capital (1906, 118). The
NIPA approach to defining income is sometimes attributed
to Hicks (1946, chapter XIV), who defines income
as the amount that could be consumed in the current
period without diminishing wealth (or, alternatively,
future consumption prospects). However, Zacharias
(2002) points out that Hicks' main focus is on the importance
of immeasurable, subjective expectations in determining
the income that households consider in making
consumption decisions. Moreover, detailed versions of
the NIPA definition of income had already been used;
see, for example, Kuznets (1934).
To highlight the uses and limitations of different measures of
personal saving, this article first describes the simple process that
governs the accumulation of wealth over time. Although the focus is on
the concept of personal saving measured in the NIPA's, an
alternative concept--the change in household net worth--that is
published in the flow of funds accounts (FFA) is also discussed. The
article then investigates several issues that arise in measuring and
interpreting personal saving: The treatment of defined benefit pension
plans, the treatment of consumer durable goods, the effect of inflation
on measured personal saving rates, and the treatment of capital gains
and capital gains taxes. For each issue, an adjusted measure of personal
saving is provided to show the effect of altering the treatment in the
NIPA's. (1)
The main conclusion is that the relevance of a personal saving
measure depends on the question being asked. For example, if the
question is how much households are contributing to national saving or
how much of their current income is left over after spending on current
consumption for purposes such as acquiring financial assets, then the
most relevant measure is personal saving as defined in the NIPA's.
However, for other questions, such as whether households in the
aggregate are making adequate financial preparation for retirement, the
net worth measures from the FFA may be more appropriate. Still other
questions may be best addressed by adjustments to the NIPA measure of
personal saving to exclude defined benefit pension plans, to include net
investment in consumer durable goods, or to remove the inflation
component of interest income from personal income. Finally, national
saving is useful for questions about the funds made available in the
United States for financing investment needs. The behavior of national
saving can also sometimes help to explain swings in the current-account
deficit, as well as business cycle developments.
A Simple Framework
As a first step in examining different concepts of personal saving,
the role of personal saving is described in the broader context of
wealth accumulation. In simplest terms, household wealth is determined
by equation 1:
(1) [W.sub.t] = [W.sub.t-1] + [DELTA][P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-1]
[W.sub.t-1] + [i.sub.t][W.sub.t-1] + [y.sub.t] - [T.sub.t] - [c.sub.t]
where [W.sub.t] is wealth at time t, [DELTA][P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-1]
is the percentage change in the price of assets from time t-1 to time t,
[i.sub.t][W.sub.t-1] is nominal interest, dividend, and rental income,
[y.sub.t] is income from sources other than wealth holdings, [T.sub.t]
is taxes paid, and [c.sub.t] is consumption expenditures on goods and
services. Therefore, wealth in a given period is equal to the stock of
wealth in the previous period ([W.sub.t-1]), plus any income
([i.sub.t][W.sub.t-1]) and capital gains (or losses) associated with
that wealth (([DELTA][P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-1])[W.sub.t-1]), plus other
household income ([y.sub.t]), less taxes ([T.sub.t]) and consumption
expenditures ([c.sub.t]). Typical life cycle models of consumption
assume that households choose consumption ([c.sub.t]) given a variety of
constraints and possibly some uncertainty about future economic
variables such as income ([y.sub.t]) and investment returns
([i.sub.t][W.sub.t-1] + ([DELTA][P.sub.t]/[P.sub.t-1])[W.sub.t-1]).
Rearranging equation 1 yields an expression for one concept of
personal saving, the change in household wealth:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
According to equation 1', the total change in wealth can be
parsed into two categories: (a) Increments to wealth from net capital
gains on existing assets and (b) NIPA-concept personal saving.
NIPA-concept personal saving is calculated by subtracting consumption
expenditures ([c.sub.t]) from NIPA-concept disposable personal income
(DPI) (rent, interest, and dividend income on assets
([i.sub.t][W.sub.t-1]) plus nonasset income ([y.sub.t]), such as labor
income or government benefits, less taxes paid ([T.sub.t])). (2) If
households accumulate wealth to balance current consumption needs
against future needs, then unexpected increases in the first
component--capital gains on existing wealth--can affect the personal
saving decisions as measured in the NIPA's. For example, a
household whose stock market portfolio returns are more than expected
this year may decide to boost spending immediately rather than to
reserve all the gain to fund spending in the future. If noncapital
income is unchanged, then the household's NIPA-concept saving rate
must fall even though its wealth has increased.
The NIPA's distinguish between capital gains (shown in part
(a) of equation 1') and saving (shown in part (b)) because NIPA
saving is designed to measure the funds that are taken out of current
income and made available for new capital investment. Because capital
gains reflect revaluations of existing assets, they do not derive from
current production and are therefore excluded from NIPA measures of
production, income, and personal saving. The FFA, however, presents a
measure of total change in wealth. (3) Estimates from the FFA show that
the stock market boom of the 1990s propelled the change in household
wealth as a percentage of DPI to record highs even as the published
measures of personal saving from the NIPA's fell to record lows. In
a complete set of national accounts that combines the FFA with the
NIPA's, the change in wealth arising from capital gains and losses
would appear in the accumulation accounts. (For further details on an
accumulation account, see table 2 at the end of the article.)
The NIPA concept of personal saving can be calculated with data
from the FFA. The FFA records households' current investment in
tangible and financial assets and net increases in household
liabilities. As an accounting matter, household saving must be used to
invest in assets, such as corporate equities and real estate, or it must
be used to pay down liabilities, such as mortgages and credit card debt.
Because the flows recorded in the FFA exclude capital gains associated
with existing assets, the calculation of a NIPA-concept personal saving
measure is straightforward: Personal saving equals the net acquisition
of financial and tangible assets, less the net increase in liabilities
of the personal sector and the net capital transfers received by the
personal sector. (4)
Issues in Measuring Personal Saving
Sector definitions
The definition of sectors in the NIPA's can affect the amount
of national saving that is attributed to the personal sector. National
saving includes the funds that the three sectors of the domestic
economy--the personal sector, the business sector, and the government
sector--make available for investment. The boundary lines between
sectors, particularly those between the business and personal sectors,
are somewhat difficult to draw because of the complicated set of
interactions among participants both within and across sector lines.
Though sector definitions do not alter national saving, they can affect
the allocation of saving across sectors; in particular, sector
definitions have important implications for the measurement of personal
consumption expenditures and personal income.
In the NIPA's, the personal sector consists of households and
nonprofit institutions that primarily serve households. Pension funds,
some insurance reserves, and private trust funds are treated as the
property of persons. (5) As a result, payments of benefits from pension
funds to retirees are treated as transfers within the personal sector
rather than as personal income. In contrast, employer contributions to
pension plans are considered to be compensation from the business or
government sector to the personal sector; therefore, they are counted in
personal income. The treatment of pension income is one way that the
definitions of sector boundaries significantly affect the measure of
personal saving in the NIPA's.
Treatment of defined benefit pension plans
Treating pension funds as part of the personal sector in the
NIPA's causes the net saving by pension plans to be included in
personal saving. (6) This treatment seems appropriate for defined
contribution (DC) pension plans, such as 401 (k) accounts, which are in
many ways similar to individual retirement accounts (IRAs). Although
employers usually contribute to these pension plans and may exercise
some control over investment decisions, the employee bears the
investment risk and is generally entitled to all the funds accrued in
the account at retirement. Because all funds in DC plans belong to
employees, or persons, including them in the personal sector seems
reasonable.
Inclusion of defined benefit (DB) pension plans in the personal
sector has, however, generated some controversy. (7) In contrast to DC
plans, employees are not entitled to all the funds that accrue in DB
pension plans; rather, retirement benefits are based on a formula that
typically includes salary and years of service. Conceptually, the
personal-sector saving that is attributed to pension funds should be
equal to the increase in the value of the benefits promised to employees
in a given period. However, the firm's contribution to its pension
plan does not have to equal the increase in the actuarial value of the
firm's expected pension liability. (8) Indeed, just as a
household's saving may decline if it has capital gains on its
assets, a firm that has large gains on its investments may not need to
make pension contributions to meet its pension obligations. As a result,
in periods of large capital gains, such as the 1990s, the pension
component of personal saving may fall even if the actuarial value of
promised pension benefits rises. (9)
Because businesses and governments are liable for payment of
accrued retirement benefits according to the plan formula, a reasonable
alternative treatment of DB plans would be to assign them to the
business and government sectors. (10) If DB plans were part of the
business and government sectors, then personal income and, therefore,
saving would be recorded when benefits are paid to retirees rather than
when employers contribute to the plans. This change in sector definition
would shift saving from the benefits accrual stage to the payout stage
and would significantly alter the contour of personal saving rates over
the past two decades.
Chart 1 shows an alternative measure of personal saving that
excludes the net saving of DB plans, which is equal to employer
contributions plus employee contributions and interest and dividends on
assets less benefit payments and administrative expenses. (11) Excluding
DB plans from the personal sector reduces personal saving for most of
the 1980-2000 period by nearly 2 percent of DPI in 1980 and by less
through much of the 1980s and 1990s. However, starting in the mid-1990s,
employers' pension contributions are so low that net pension saving
in DB plans is actually negative. (12) Indeed, as the chart shows,
altering the treatment of DB plans boosts the adjusted saving measure as
much as 1/2 percent of DPI in 2000. Therefore, the personal saving
measure adjusted to exclude DB plans did not decline as steeply as the
published measure; the drop in saving by DB pension plans accounted for
nearly 2 1/2 percentage points, or about one-fourth of the 9
1/4-percentage-point decline in published personal saving rates over the
past two decades. (See also table 1.)
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Treatment of consumer durable goods
Saving is roughly equal to after-tax income less consumption, so
the measurement of saving depends critically on whether certain
expenditures are classified as consumption or investment. A defining
feature of net investment--or increments to wealth net of capital gains
and depreciation--is that it increases the future consumption
possibilities of households whereas current consumption expenditures do
not.
Classifying some types of transactions as either consumption or
investment is simple. For example, a meal purchased at a restaurant is
consumed immediately and is therefore part of current consumption
expenditures. Alternatively, money placed in a bank account is clearly
part of saving and is likely loaned out to support investment by the
personal sector, the business sector, or the government sector.
Expenditures on other types of goods, such as those that may last
for several years, may not be so easy to classify as consumption or
investment. Indeed, expenditures for housing and consumer durable goods
include elements of both categories. For example, investments in housing
raise future consumption possibilities because they yield a stream of
housing services over time; therefore, housing is treated as an
investment good in the NIPA's. (13) The measures of wealth held as
produced assets in NIPA table 5.16 include the value of the housing
stock.
However, the NIPA's treat net purchases of consumer durable
goods, which also provide a stream of services over a period of years,
as consumption rather than as investment. Consumer durable goods consist
of items, such as television sets and automobiles, that are expected to
provide a stream of services--like the transportation services provided
by automobiles--for 3 years or more. Therefore, the acquisition of a
durable good increases future consumption possibilities in much the same
way that the acquisition of a financial asset or housing does, and for
this reason many have argued that spending on durable goods should be
treated as investment rather than consumption. If durable goods share
the same characteristics as housing, then like housing, the stock of
consumer durable goods should be included as a component of household
wealth. (14) Indeed, durable goods are treated as assets in the FFA.
(15)
However, conceptual and practical problems arise in counting
consumer durable goods as capital assets in the NIPA's. On the
conceptual side, treating durable goods as assets would imply that
services furnished by these assets should count in gross domestic
product (GDP). Yet these services, together with labor from household
members, are inputs into household production activities that are out of
scope for GDP. Because household production is out of scope for GDP, the
System of National Accounts (1993), which provides international
guidelines for national accounts, recommends that spending on consumer
durables be treated as consumption. On the practical side, the lack of
vibrant rental markets for a broad variety of durable goods would make
many rental values hard to impute. (16) In addition, the imputations for
the expenditures and income from the services of the durables treated as
assets would make the NIPA's more complex and make the market-based
transactions that interest many users of the NIPA's harder to
follow.
Nevertheless, a measure of personal saving that includes net
investment in durable goods remains a reasonable alternative to the
published NIPA measure. (17) Chart 2 compares the path of the published
NIPA personal saving rate with a personal saving measure that has been
augmented by net investment in durable goods. (18) The pattern of the
saving rate adjusted to include consumer durable goods reflects the
cyclical nature of spending on these goods: Net investment in consumer
durables increased substantially in the 1990s, rising from about 1/2
percent of DPI at the end of 1991 to 3 1/2 percent in 2000. As a result,
the adjustment for consumer durables raises personal saving between 1/2
percent and 3 1/2 percent of DPI compared with the published NIPA
measure but does not significantly alter the decline in the saving rate
in the late 1990s.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Effect of inflation on measured personal saving rates
Another issue that arises in implementing equation 1 is whether the
equation should be stated in real terms or in nominal terms. The
personal saving rate in the NIPA's is calculated from nominal
values of income and consumption. To the extent that inflation simply
scales up the value of income and consumption, it will have little
effect on the saving rate. Inflation tends, however, to raise interest
income and outlays by more than the change in the general price level.
As a result, saving rates vary with the rate of inflation.
The mechanism that raises interest income and outlays in the
presence of expected inflation is straightforward. If there were no
adjustment to nominal interest rates, then households with
interest-bearing wealth would clearly be worse off in inflationary
periods because inflation erodes the purchasing power of their wealth.
As a result, when those with money to lend anticipate inflation, they
demand higher nominal rates of interest to compensate for the loss in
purchasing power of both the principal and the interest income
associated with that asset. Roughly, the required increase in nominal
interest income is equal to the product of the inflation rate and the
real value of the previous period's net interest-bearing assets.
(19) If the value of interest-bearing assets exceeds the value of
interest-bearing liabilities in the personal sector, the increase in
nominal interest rates will raise measured personal saving even though
it leaves the purchasing power of household net worth unchanged. (20)
The effect of inflation on net interest income may cause difficulty
in interpreting changes in personal saving rates over time, In
particular, because the personal sector tends to be a net lender to
other sectors, a decline in personal saving will be observed as
inflationary pressures wane, even if the real values of interest income
and outlays and of noninterest income and consumption are unchanged.
A measure of personal saving that removes the inflation premium--or
the amount of interest income required to cover the loss of purchasing
power induced by inflation--from nominal interest earned on assets and
nominal interest paid on liabilities shows how real saving behavior has
changed over time. The inflation premium is estimated by multiplying the
realized inflation rate, as measured by the average change in the
chain-type price index for PCE, by the average holdings of
interest-bearing assets less liabilities for the personal sector
recorded in the FFA. Assets held indirectly through pension plans,
insurance contracts, personal trusts, and mutual funds are included.
Since personal income includes the profits of noncorporate businesses,
such as sole proprietorships and partnerships, the interest-bearing
assets and liabilities of noncorporate businesses are also included in
the adjustment. These businesses tend to be net borrowers, so the effect
of adjusting their net interest-bearing assets for inflation partly
offsets the effect of adjusting the net interest-bearing assets of
households, which tend to be net lenders.
Chart 3 shows the path of the inflation-adjusted personal saving
rate over the past 20 years. When inflation is relatively high, as it
was in the early 1980s, the inflation-adjusted saving rate is 1 1/2 to 2
1/2 percentage points below the published rate. As inflation rates come
down, as they did in the 1990s, the gap between the inflation-adjusted
saving rate and the published measure narrows; by 1998, the gap is just
1/2 percentage point. Although the inflation-adjusted measure falls less
than the published measure, it still declines significantly from its
peak of 9 1/2 percent of DPI in 1982 to about zero in 2000.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Treatment of capital gains and capital gains taxes
In the NIPA's, personal income excludes capital gains (and
losses) because they do not derive from current production. As a result,
the large capital gains realized during the stock market boom of the
1990s failed to boost personal saving. Indeed, they effectively reduced
measured personal saving over that period because taxes paid on those
gains are included in personal tax payments, which are deducted from
personal income in calculating DPI.
Some have argued that the NIPA treatment of capital gains is
inconsistent with its treatment of capital gains taxes: If capital gains
are not part of income, then taxes on those gains should not be counted
against income as personal tax payments. Despite these arguments, the
NIPA treatment is appropriate given the purpose of the NIPA accounting
framework. Changes in asset values due to price changes provide no new
funds for investment--they merely represent changes in the asset and
liability positions of some investors relative to others. Capital gains
taxes, however, do represent payments from the personal sector to the
government sector. The reason why a tax is due is generally not a
consideration in deciding whether to account for it in the NIPA's.
(21) Furthermore, if the NIPA's did not count capital gains taxes
as personal tax payments, then the government could not be credited with
the capital gains tax revenue. This treatment would have unsatisfactory
consequences for the measure of the government surplus or deficit.
Nevertheless, if one steps outside the NIPA framework, a plausible
implementation of equation 1 might be to expand the concept of income by
including capital gains or to narrow the concept of tax payments by
excluding capital gains taxes from personal tax payments. To show the
effect of the treatment of capital gains taxes on personal saving over
the past two decades, chart 4 presents a measure of saving that excludes
those taxes from personal tax payments. Only Federal taxes on capital
gains are considered; State capital gains taxes have been estimated to
range between one-tenth and one-fifth the size of Federal capital gains
taxes.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
The chart shows that Federal capital gains taxes typically
accounted for between 1/2 percent and 1 percent of DPI in the past two
decades, but they are estimated to have increased to 1 1/2 percent from
1998 forward. Therefore, excluding capital gains tax payments from
personal tax payments raises the adjusted saving measure by relatively
more in recent years and eliminates at most 1 percentage point of the
decline in the personal saving rate. The treatment of capital gains
appears to be responsible for very little of the sharp decline in
personal saving over the past 20 years.
Measures of Wealth Accumulation
Although saving measures that exclude capital gains are appropriate
for the purposes of the NIPA's, broader concepts of saving that
include capital gains along with NIPA-concept saving can be useful for
understanding changes in the future consumption possibilities of
households. Indeed, accounting for the capital-gains component of
changes in wealth is important for understanding changes in the
NIPA-concept saving rate. For example, households that are saving to
accumulate enough funds for retirement may find that they can save less
if they experience larger-than-expected gains in the value of their net
worth. (22)
Published quarterly, the FFA provide estimates of household net
worth, which is defined as the value of financial and tangible assets
minus liabilities. They also provide a decomposition of sources of
change in net worth. Any increase in the level of net worth from one
period to the next must, in the absence of discontinuities, be due
either to capital gains on existing assets or to money taken out of
current income to purchase assets or pay down debt. (23) These sources
of change in net wealth are tabulated in the accumulation account in
table 2.
As chart 5 shows, the total change in household wealth averaged 36
percent of DPI over the past two decades, with capital gains accounting
for about two-thirds of the total change in wealth, on average. However,
the wealth accumulation measure exhibits considerable volatility; the
change in wealth rises from 10 percent in 1990, balloons close to 75
percent of DPI in 1999, and then falls to a record low of nearly -10
percent in 2000. Besides revealing the large magnitude and volatility of
capital gains, chart 5 suggests that the low rates of personal saving
since the mid-1990s might be partly explained by the surge in household
net worth caused by the stock market boom of the 1990s.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
The large gains of the 1990s are especially unusual because they
occurred when inflation was low. During periods of significant
inflation, some gains in asset prices simply reflect changes in the
general price level and therefore do not represent increases in the real
consumption possibilities of the asset holders. In 1980, for example,
the personal sector's nominal capital gains are around 50 percent
of nominal DPI, but the chain-type price index for PCE indicates an
inflation rate of around 10 percent per year. Deducting the price
changes that merely maintain assets' real value in terms of
consumption goods and services shows that in real terms the personal
sector's capital gains are only around 5 percent of real DPI in
1980. In contrast, from 1995 to 1999, real capital gains range from 25
to 55 percent of real DPI, compared with a range of 36 to 68 percent for
the ratio of nominal capital gains to DPI. (For data on real capital
gains and real net worth, see table 3.)
National Saving
An important reason for concern about personal saving is its role
in funding the capital accumulation that is vital for economic growth.
The domestic source of funds for capital investments is net national
saving, which includes personal saving, saving by businesses
(undistributed profits), and saving by governments (surpluses). Personal
saving generally accounts for most of this total, and it is almost
always larger than either of the other two components of net national
saving.
However, low levels of personal saving need not imply inadequate
national saving. National saving is more stable than the saving by
individual sectors of the domestic economy because swings in personal
saving and government saving tend to offset each other. For example, as
shown in chart 6, net national saving rebounds from a trough of below 4
percent of net national product (NNP) in 1993 to over 7 percent of NNP
in 1998, despite the decline in personal saving between those years.
This rebound reflects an increase in government saving that exceeds the
fall in personal saving. Nevertheless, net national saving averaged 9
percent of NNP in 1980-81, and viewed from a long-term perspective, net
national saving is down substantially.
[GRAPHIC OMITTED]
Conclusion
Personal saving provides funds for new capital investment, which in
turn powers economic growth and raises the future consumption
possibilities of households. Though the definition of personal saving is
fairly simple--DPI less consumption--the definitions of personal income
and consumption can be controversial.
The definitions of income and consumption explored in this article
differ from those used in the NIPA's. These definitions (1) alter
the boundaries of the personal sector by excluding defined benefit
pension plans, (2) treat consumer durable goods expenditures as
investment rather than consumption, (3) remove the effects of inflation
from nominal interest income and outlays, and (4) narrow the definition
of personal tax payments by excluding taxes paid on capital gains. These
adjustments flatten the contour of personal saving, but not enough to
alter the conclusion that personal saving rates have fallen to very low
levels in recent years.
Since the personal sector is usually the main source of national
saving, one concern raised by the decline in the NIPA personal saving
rate over the past two decades is whether national saving is still
adequate to fund needed capital accumulation. The record low of net
foreign investment in 2000 shows the effects of low national saving.
Nevertheless, the decline in personal saving in the late 1990s was
offset by a large increase in government saving. As a result, net
national saving actually increased through much of the 1990s, albeit not
to the levels that prevailed before 1982. Furthermore, net domestic
investment in new capital assets (which includes private domestic
investment and government investment less consumption of fixed capital)
increased even more as a percent of NNP, regaining the level it had at
the beginning of the 1980s.
Two more concerns raised by the &dine in personal saving are
the retirement preparedness of households and the ability of households
to weather unexpected shocks to their income or expenses. However, the
recent decline in personal saving rates does not in itself indicate that
households are ill-prepared to finance their retirement or to handle
unexpected expenses. To get a sense of the strength of household balance
sheets, a broader measure of wealth accumulation is useful. Perhaps the
broadest concept of personal saving is the change in household net
worth, which can be measured using data from the FFA. Change in net
worth in the FFA includes increments to wealth that are unrelated to
current production, in particular, capital gains on existing tangible
and financial assets as well as net investment in consumer durable
goods.
Capital gains in the last half of the 1990s were responsible for
large gains in household net worth as measured by the FFA. However,
capital gains can be quite volatile, particularly for financial assets
such as equities, so relying exclusively on these gains for financial
security, or even to finance longer term needs such as retirement, would
be imprudent.
Furthermore, both the NIPA saving measures and the FFA wealth
measures provide information about all households combined. Because they
do not measure how wealth and saving are distributed across households,
they have limited value for addressing many important policy questions,
including those concerning retirement readiness.
Treatment of Owner-Occupied Housing in the NIPA's
The treatment of homeowners in the national income and product
accounts (NIPA's) is designed to make GDP invariant to how much of
the housing stock is occupied by owners. Homeowners are treated as
landlords in the business sector who produce housing services that they
consume as tenants in the personal sector. Their imputed rental expense
is included in personal consumption expenditures, and their imputed net
rental income is included in personal income.
BEA imputes the rental income of homeowners as a residual by
subtracting the expenses that a landlord would pay from the imputed
rents of residences occupied by their owners. Expenses considered in the
calculation of homeowners' imputed rental income include services
and materials to acquire and maintain the residence (dosing costs,
repairs, and property insurance), which count as intermediate inputs.
Homeowners' expenses also include mortgage interest, indirect
business tax and nontax liability (primarily property taxes), and
consumption of fixed capital (depreciation). The largest and most
variable of these items is mortgage interest, which, as an expense,
reduces imputed rental income, personal income, and personal saving.
Mortgage interest payments are around 2 percent of DPI in the 1960s,
reach a plateau of 5 percent of DPI in 1990, and remain under 4.5
percent of DPI after 1993.
NIPA table 8.21 shows the rental income imputed to homeowners. This
income has slightly exceeded 1 percent of DPI since 1994, compared with
a range of 0.1 to 0.7 percent of DPI in the 1980s. Inclusion of imputed
rental income in personal income raises the value of the denominator in
the calculation of the personal saving rate, but the effect on the
calculation is negligible.
On the other hand, leaving net expenditures to purchase new
residences out of personal consumption expenditures and deducting CFC for these residences from personal income has a substantial effect on
the calculation of the personal saving rate. In most years, these
procedures raise personal saving by enough to add about 3 to 3 1/2
percentage points to the personal saving rate, compared with a measure
that treats these purchases of new residences as current consumption.
However, in 1981-82 and 1991-92, the effect on the personal saving rate
was only about 2 percentage points.
Table 1. Alternative Personal Saving Rates and Related Measures,
1980-2000
1980 1981 1982
Personal saving rate defined by:
Published NIPA's 10.2 10.8 10.9
Excluding defined benefit pension plans 8.3 9.4 9.4
With consumer durables as investment 11.3 12.0 11.7
With inflation adjustment 7.6 9.0 9.4
With capital gains adjustment 10.8 11.4 11.4
Growth of personal sector wealth:
Capital gains, percent of DPI 48.5 19.5 18.8
Change in net worth, percent of DPI 60.0 33.0 31.1
Real capital gains, percent of real DPI 5.3 -11.0 -1.6
Change in real net worth, percent of
real DPI 16.8 2.5 10.7
Saving as percent of net national product:
Personal saving, NIPA definition 8.3 8.8 9.2
Net national saving 8.5 9.4 6.6
1983 1984 1985
Personal saving rate defined by:
Published NIPA's 8.8 10.6 9.2
Excluding defined benefit pension plans 7.2 8.9 7.5
With consumer durables as investment 10.4 12.9 11.9
With inflation adjustment 7.3 9.3 7.8
With capital gains adjustment 9.3 11.3 9.6
Growth of personal sector wealth:
Capital gains, percent of DPI 18.4 15.5 35.2
Change in net worth, percent of DPI 32.8 29.3 47.9
Real capital gains, percent of real DPI 1.1 1.4 20.7
Change in real net worth, percent of
real DPI 15.5 15.2 33.4
Saving as percent of net national product:
Personal saving, NIPA definition 7.3 8.8 7.6
Net national saving 4.9 8.2 6.9
1986 1987 1988
Personal saving rate defined by:
Published NIPA's 8.2 7.3 7.8
Excluding defined benefit pension plans 6.9 6.0 6.9
With consumer durables as investment 11.3 10.1 10.2
With inflation adjustment 7.2 5.6 5.9
With capital gains adjustment 9.1 8.8 8.6
Growth of personal sector wealth:
Capital gains, percent of DPI 31.1 17.9 29.3
Change in net worth, percent of DPI 45.1 30.1 41.2
Real capital gains, percent of real DPI 19.7 -0.6 9.7
Change in real net worth, percent of
real DPI 33.7 11.7 21.6
Saving as percent of net national product:
Personal saving, NIPA definition 6.8 6.1 6.5
Net national saving 4.7 5.4 6.9
1989 1990 1991
Personal saving rate defined by:
Published NIPA's 7.5 7.8 8.3
Excluding defined benefit pension plans 6.8 7.2 8.0
With consumer durables as investment 9.9 9.4 9.0
With inflation adjustment 5.5 5.4 6.8
With capital gains adjustment 8.4 8.4 8.8
Growth of personal sector wealth:
Capital gains, percent of DPI 36.2 -3.0 23.8
Change in net worth, percent of DPI 44.5 8.1 32.2
Real capital gains, percent of real DPI 16.6 -25.8 9.6
Change in real net worth, percent of
real DPI 24.8 -14.7 18.0
Saving as percent of net national product:
Personal saving, NIPA definition 6.2 6.5 7.1
Net national saving 6.0 5.2 5.1
1992 1993 1994
Personal saving rate defined by:
Published NIPA's 8.7 7.1 6.1
Excluding defined benefit pension plans 8.5 6.9 5.7
With consumer durables as investment 10.2 9.3 8.2
With inflation adjustment 7.4 6.1 5.0
With capital gains adjustment 9.2 7.7 6.9
Growth of personal sector wealth:
Capital gains, percent of DPI 8.9 15.1 4.1
Change in net worth, percent of DPI 17.8 23.2 12.3
Real capital gains, percent of real DPI -3.9 5.7 -6.5
Change in real net worth, percent of
real DPI 5.0 13.9 1.6
Saving as percent of net national product:
Personal saving, NIPA definition 7.4 6.0 5.1
Net national saving 4.2 3.8 4.3
1995 1996 1997
Personal saving rate defined by:
Published NIPA's 5.6 4.8 4.2
Excluding defined benefit pension plans 5.3 4.8 4.4
With consumer durables as investment 8.0 7.0 7.0
With inflation adjustment 4.6 3.7 3.6
With capital gains adjustment 6.2 5.6 5.6
Growth of personal sector wealth:
Capital gains, percent of DPI 43.8 36.3 58.6
Change in net worth, percent of DPI 49.7 44.6 63.4
Real capital gains, percent of real DPI 34.0 24.6 51.9
Change in real net worth, percent of
real DPI 40.0 33.0 56.7
Saving as percent of net national product:
Personal saving, NIPA definition 4.6 4.0 3.5
Net national saving 5.1 5.7 6.7
1998 1999 2000
Personal saving rate defined by:
Published NIPA's 4.7 2.4 1.0
Excluding defined benefit pension plans 4.8 2.8 1.5
With consumer durables as investment 7.9 5.9 4.4
With inflation adjustment 4.2 1.4 -0.2
With capital gains adjustment 6.1 3.8 2.7
Growth of personal sector wealth:
Capital gains, percent of DPI 47.5 68.4 -10.3
Change in net worth, percent of DPI 53.8 74.4 -7.5
Real capital gains, percent of real DPI 40.3 55.1 -23.7
Change in real net worth, percent of
real DPI 46.7 61.1 -20.9
Saving as percent of net national product:
Personal saving, NIPA definition 3.9 2.0 0.8
Net national saving 7.5 6.8 6.3
DPI Disposable personal income.
NIPA National income product accounts.
Table 2. Contributions of Saving and Capital Gains
to Changes in Personal Net Wealth, 1980-2000
FFA
saving
Starting as esti- Capital Other
Year net mated gains factors
worth from or (2)
invest- losses
ment (1)
1980 8,356.9 238.6 980.3 -6.7
1981 9,569.1 319.8 439.0 -17.6
1982 10,310.3 329.9 452.5 -33.4
1983 11,059.3 335.7 476.5 37.1
1984 11,908.6 412.5 447.7 -14.0
1985 12,754.8 372.4 1,085.7 21.8
1986 14,234.7 481.1 1,013.1 -24.4
1987 15,704.5 409.5 620.5 12.9
1988 16,747.4 458.8 1,099.9 -12.6
1989 18,293.5 353.3 1,455.7 -23.1
1990 20,079.4 512.6 -128.1 -36.8
1991 20,427.1 386.0 1,064.2 -11.2
1992 21,866.1 429.4 422.8 -6.8
1993 22,711.5 419.0 743.6 -16.0
1994 23,858.1 398.8 214.1 22.2
1995 24,493.2 366.3 2,372.8 -42.8
1996 27,189.5 403.1 2,058.4 68.9
1997 29,719.9 329.6 3,497.4 -45.7
1998 33,501.2 429.1 3,018.4 -25.3
1999 36,923.4 337.4 4,523.7 62.2
2000 41,846.7 249.6 -725.5 -50.7
Addenda:
Items
in FFA FFA
Ending NIPA saving measure
Year net personal but not of NIPA
worth saving NIPA saving
saving concept
(3)
1980 9,569.1 205.6 14.1 224.5
1981 10,310.3 243.7 16.7 303.1
1982 11,059.3 262.2 10.4 319.5
1983 11,908.6 227.8 34.4 301.3
1984 12,754.8 306.5 61.2 351.3
1985 14,234.7 282.6 77.7 294.7
1986 15,704.5 267.8 94.6 386.5
1987 16,747.4 252.8 89.4 320.1
1988 18,293.5 292.3 79.7 379.1
1989 20,079.4 301.8 84.5 268.8
1990 20,427.1 334.3 54.7 457.9
1991 21,866.1 371.7 18.6 367.4
1992 22,711.5 413.7 56.6 372.8
1993 23,858.1 350.8 90.1 328.9
1994 24,493.2 315.5 91.8 307.0
1995 27,189.5 302.4 112.6 253.7
1996 29,719.9 272.1 104.5 298.6
1997 33,501.2 252.9 141.5 188.1
1998 36,923.4 301.5 175.5 253.6
1999 41,846.7 160.9 196.5 140.9
2000 41,320.1 67.7 210.8 38.8
(1.) Equals investment in financial assets minus borrowing, plus
investment in tangible assets minus consumption of fixed capital.
Source: Table F.100 in the December 2001 release of the FFA.
(2.) Consists of statistical discontinuities, and differences
between NIPA series for consumption of fixed capital.
Source: Table R.100 from the FFA.
(3.) Consists primarily of net investment in consumer durables,
but it also includes Federal employee life insurance reserves.
Railroad Retirement Board reserves, and immigrants' transfers,
less estate and gift taxes.
FFA Flow of funds accounts.
NIPA National income product accounts.
Table 3. Personal Sector Real Net Worth, Real Saving, and
Real Capital Gains, 1980-2000
[Billions of chained (1996) dollars]
Real
Starting FFA Real Memo: Memo:
Year real net per- capital Real Real
worth sonal gains DPI NIPA
(1) saving (2) saving
1980 15,930.8 432.1 192.5 3,658.0 372.4
1981 16,543.3 532.3 -411.0 3,741.1 405.6
1982 16,635.4 519.7 -56.1 3,791.7 413.1
1983 17,046.2 507.2 41.1 3,906.9 344.2
1984 17,650.6 601.1 58.1 4,207.6 446.7
1985 18,289.5 524.6 898.6 4,347.8 398.1
1986 19,743.4 661.6 885.6 4,486.6 368.3
1987 21,257.1 542.5 -25.6 4,582.5 334.9
1988 21,791.2 585.0 462.8 4,784.1 372.7
1989 22,822.9 431.6 812.5 4,906.5 368.7
1990 24,038.8 598.6 -1,294.1 5,014.2 390.4
1991 23,300.2 434.1 486.7 5,033.0 418.1
1992 24,208.4 468.7 -198.6 5,189.3 451.5
1993 24,471.1 446.7 298.2 5,261.3 374.0
1994 25,198.7 416.7 -350.1 5,397.2 329.7
1995 25,288.6 374.2 1,883.8 5,539.1 308.9
1996 27,503.1 403.1 1,398.3 5,677.7 272.1
1997 29,373.3 323.3 3,030.7 5,854.5 248.1
1998 32,682.5 416.5 2,529.7 6,168.6 292.6
1999 35,604.2 322.2 3,441.9 6,320.0 153.7
2000 39,427.7 232.1 -1,633.1 6,539.2 63.0
(1.) Changes in real net worth do not equal the sum of real saving and
real capital gains because of "other factors," which are shown in
current dollars in table 2.
(2.) Real capital gains are calculated as the difference between the
value of inflation-adjusted net wealth at the close of each year and
the total of inflation-adjusted opening net wealth and
inflation-adjusted FFA saving during the year adjusted for "other
factors."
NOTE. The price level at the start of any year y is measured by an
average of the implicit PCE price indexes for the fourth quarter of y-1
and the first quarter of y. The index used to adjust saving flows
during a year is an average of the four quarterly PCE price indexes for
that year.
DPI Disposable personal income.
FFA Flow of funds accounts.
NIPA National income product accounts.
PCE Personal consumption expenditures.
(1.) Many authors have examined alternative measures of personal
saving, including those presented in this paper. For a sampling of the
most recent work, see Gale and Sabelhaus (1999), Peach and Steindel
(2000), and Lusardi, Skinner, and Venti (2001).
(2.) NIPA table 2.1 shows personal consumption expenditures and two
additional items, personal interest payments and net transfers to the
rest of the world, as subtractions from DPI in the calculation of
personal saving. For simplicity, this article refers to all these items
collectively as "consumption." Capital transfers and other
special factors that change wealth but count neither as capital gains
nor as income are ignored.
(3.) Net worth from the FFA is not valued strictly at market
prices. Most tangible assets, as well as corporate equities and mutual
funds, are valued at market prices, but fixed income assets (such as
bonds) and liabilities are recorded at book value.
(4.) The net acquisition of tangible assets equals gross
acquisition minus depreciation, or "consumption of fixed
capital." Although the national saving measure highlighted at the
top of NIPA table 5.1 is a gross measure, personal saving is a net
measure because depreciation expenses are deducted from personal rental
income, including homeowners' imputed rental income, and from
proprietors' income. Net capital transfers received by the personal
sector are composed primarily of Federal and State estate and gift tax
payments and hence are typically negative. The treatment of net capital
transfers is discussed in Moulton, Parker, and Seskin (1999).
(5.) Social security and other government transfer programs are
included in the government sector.
(6.) Since employer contributions to pension plans, which represent
funds set aside by business or government to pay retirement benefits,
count as part of personal income, they are part of personal saving.
Retirement plans with no employer contribution, such as individual
retirement accounts, fall outside the definition of pension plans in the
NIPA's.
(7.) Employer-sponsored group insurance plans are treated similarly
to pension plans in the NIPA and thus could logically be included in any
alternative treatment given to DB pension plans. Interest in an
alternative treatment for benefit plans other than DB pensions has,
however, been limited, in part because the effect of changing the
treatment of these plans would be relatively small.
(8.) While a DB pension plan can be either underfunded or
overfunded, there are rules against significant levels of underfunding,
and there are disincentives to large amounts of overfunding.
(9.) Net private saving is unaffected by such changes in pension
plan contributions because it combines personal and business saving.
Like personal saving, net private saving falls relative to DPI,
beginning in 1992, but it falls about 1 percentage point less.
(10.) Howrey and Hymans (1992) present estimates of "loanable
funds saving," which treats all pension funds the way that social
insurance is treated, that is, as part of the business or government
sectors rather than the personal sector.
(11.) The net saving of DB plans is equal to income less
administrative expenses; only the income component of net saving
(contributions plus interest plus dividends less benefits) is subtracted
from DPI to construct the adjusted DPI used to calculate the saving
rate. Administrative expenses are part of PCE and are therefore excluded
from saving but not from income.
(12.) The stock market boom of the late 1990s is likely the major
reason for the reductions in employer contributions to DB plans, but the
decline in DB pension saving also reflects a shift away from DB plans in
favor of DC plans. See Poterba, Venti, and Wise (2001).
(13.) In the NIPA's, net investment in housing is incorporated
by imputing a housing service flow to PCE equal to the rental value of
the house and by imputing an associated rental income to personal income
(which is simply the imputed rental value net of depreciation and other
costs). See the box "Treatment of Owner-Occupied Housing in the
NIPA's."
(14.) Expanding the definition of tangible assets to include
consumer durable goods is a minor adjustment compared with some
proposals for &fining investment. In particular, since the discovery
and diffusion of knowledge are important sources of economic growth, an
expansion of measures of investment to include expenditures on
intangible assets such as training, education, and research and
development may be appropriate for some types of analysis. Some
estimates imply that adding knowledge capital to investment boosts the
net national saving rate between 15 percent and 25 percent of DPI from
1950 to the early 1990s (Nordhaus 1995). Similarly, as Jorgenson and
Fraumeni (1989) found, investment in human capital is several times
larger than investment in tangible assets. Nevertheless, the value and
rates of depreciation of such intangible assets are subject to
considerable uncertainty; therefore, most intangible assets are excluded
from investment in the NIPA's.
(15.) Adding net investment in consumer durables to saving gives
the same estimate of personal saving as imputing rental expenditures and
rental income from durables. Under the latter approach, however, the
measure of DPI in the denominator of the personal saving rate
calculation would be larger by the amount of durable goods owners'
imputed rental income, but not by enough to have an appreciable effect
on the saving rate.
(16.) The rental-equivalence approach used to impute income and
consumption for owner-occupied housing can also be applied to impute
income and consumption for consumer durable goods. With this approach,
the increment to saving from durable goods is equal to gross investment
in durable goods plus the income generated from those goods less the
consumption associated with them. As with owner-occupied housing, the
imputed service flow from consumer durables is equal to an imputed
rental value, and the imputed rental income from durables is calculated
as the rental value less depreciation, personal property taxes, and
interest on consumer loans. However, because property taxes and interest
on consumer loans are already excluded from saving as part of tax
payments and interest outlays, the net addition to saving from adopting
rental equivalence for durables would equal gross investment in durables
less depreciation on the stock of durables.
(17.) The FFA have always featured a measure of personal saving
that includes net investment in consumer durable goods. This treatment
is consistent with the net worth concept in the FFA, which counts
consumer durables as a component of wealth on the household balance
sheet.
(18.) Net investment in durable goods differs slightly from PCE for
durable goods (less depreciation) because of the treatment of used
automobiles. In particular, net investment in automobiles is calculated
as the change in the value of the depreciated stock of automobiles,
whereas consumption expenditures include premiums charged by
incorporated auto dealers.
(19.) The precise adjustment to nominal rates required to make the
consumer as well off in an inflationary economy (where the inflation
rate is given by [[pi].sub.t]) as in a noninflationary economy is
[[pi].sub.t] + [[pi].sub.t][i.sub.t], where the first term compensates
for the loss in purchasing power of the value of the asset and the
second term compensates for the loss in purchasing power of the interest
income generated by that asset. The adjustment can be derived by
adjusting all the variables in equation I for inflation.
(20.) To a large extent, inflation-induced increases in saving by
the personal sector will be offset by inflation-induced reductions in
saving by the business sector and the government sector, leaving
national saving little changed. Net foreign borrowing or lending
prevents this offset from being complete.
(21.) However, the NIPA's do not include estate and gift taxes in personal tax payments because those taxes are classified as net
capital transfers. A defining feature of a net capital transfer is that
it is a transaction in which one party gets something for nothing.
Capital gains realized in the sale of stock or some other appreciated
asset do not qualify under this criterion, as one investor pays an
appreciated price for the asset that another investor is selling.
(22.) The phenomenon of reduced household saving in response to
rising wealth has been dubbed the wealth effect on consumption. Recent
work indicates that the magnitude of this effect is in the range of 3-5
cents of additional consumption per dollar of additional wealth (see,
for example, Poterba 2000).
(23.) The net worth figures include capital gains on real estate as
well as capital gains on corporate equity, held directly or indirectly
through mutual funds, pension funds, life insurance contracts, and bank
personal trusts and estates. Other financial instruments, such as bonds,
are carried at book value; hence, the net worth figures do not include
capital gains or losses on those assets and liabilities.
References
Blumenthal, Robin. 2001. "Red-Handed Analysts Worry That
Pension Gains Smack of Cookie-Jar Accounting." Barrons (July 9):
17-18.
Boskin, Michael J. 1990. "Issues in the Measurement and
Interpretation of Saving and Wealth." In Fifty Years of Economic
Measurement: The Jubilee of the Conference on Research in Income and
Wealth. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 54, edited by Ernst R. Berndt
and Jack E. Triplett, 159-83. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Commission of the European Communities, International Monetary
Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, United
Nations, and World Bank. 1993. System of National Accounts 1993.
Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris, and Washington, DC.
de Leeuw, Frank. 1984. "Conflicting Measures of Private
Saving" SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS 64 (November): 17-22.
Engen, Eric, William Gale, and Cori Uccello. 1999. "The
Adequacy of Household Saving." In Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, no. 2, 65-187.
Fisher, Irving. 1906. The Nature of Capital and Income. New York:
Macmillan.
Gale, William G., and John Sabelhaus. 1999. "Perspectives on
the Household Saving Rate." In Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, no. 1, 181-223.
Haig, Robert M. 1921. The Federal Income Tax. New York: Columbia
University Press.
Hendershott, Patric H., and Joe Peek. 1989. "Aggregate U.S.
Private Saving: Conceptual Measures." In The Measurement of Saving,
Investment, and Wealth. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 52, edited by
Robert E. Lipsey and Helen Stone Tice, 185-223. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Hicks, John R. 1946. Value and Capital. 2nd ed. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Holloway, Thomas M. 1989. "Present NIPA Saving Measures: Their
Characteristics and Limitations" In The Measurement of Saving,
Investment, and Wealth. Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 52, edited by
Robert E. Lipsey and Helen Stone Tice, 21-100. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Howrey, E. Philip, and Saul H. Hymans. 1978. "The Measurement
and Determination of Loanable-Funds Saving." Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, no. 3, 655-85.
Jorgenson, Dale W, and Barbara M. Fraumeni. 1995. "The
Accumulation of Human and Nonhuman Capital, 1948-84." In
Productivity: Postwar Economic Growth, vol. 1. Cambridge: MIT Press,
273-332.
Jump, Gregory V. 1980. "Interest Rates, Inflation
Expectations, and Spurious Elements in Measured Real Income and
Saving," American Economic Review 70 (December): 990-1,004.
Kopcke, Richard W., Alicia H. Munnell, and Leah M. Cook. 1991.
"The Influence of Housing and Durables on Personal Saving."
New England Economic Review (November/December): 3-16.
Kuznets, Simon. 1934. National Income, 1929-32. 73rd Cong., 2nd
sess. Senate doc. 124.
Lusardi, Annamaria, Jonathon Skinner, and Steven Venti. 2001.
"Saving Puzzles and Saving Policies in the United States."
Working paper no. 8237. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic
Research, April. <papers.nber.org/papers/W8237>.
Malinvaud, E. 1987. "Capital Gains and Losses." In The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Edited by John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman. London: Macmillan Press.
Moulton, Brent R., Robert P. Parker, and Eugene P. Seskin. 1999.
"A Preview of the Comprehensive Revision of the National Income and
Product Accounts: Definitional and Classificational Changes."
SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS 79 (August): 7-20.
Nordhaus, William R. 1995. "How Should We Measure Sustainable
Income?" Discussion paper no. 1101. New Haven: Cowles Foundation at
Yale University, May. <cowles.econ.yale.edu>.
Parker, Jonathan A. 1999. "Spendthrift in America? On Two
Decades of a Decline in the U.S. Saving Rate," In NBER
Macroeconomics Annual. Edited by Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg.
Cambridge: MIT Press.
Peach, Richard, and Charles Steindel. 2000. "A Nation of
Spendthrifts? An Analysis of Trends in Personal and Gross Saving."
Current Issues in Economics and Finance 6, no. 2 (September): 1-6.
Poterba, James M. 2000. "Stock Market Wealth and
Consumption." Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, no. 2 (Spring):
99-118.
Poterba, James M., Steven F. Venti, and David A. Wise. 2001.
"The Transition to Personal Accounts and Increasing Retirement
Wealth: Macro and Micro Evidence." Working paper no. 8610.
Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, November.
<papers.nber.org/papers/W8610>.
Rogers, R. Mark. 1990. "Measuring the Personal Savings Rate:
Some Technical Perspectives." Atlanta Federal Reserve Bank Economic
Review 75, no. 4 (July/ August): 38-49.
Simons, Henry C. 1938. Personal Income Taxation: The Definition of
Income as a Problem of Fiscal Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Scitovksy, Tibor. 1995. "Why the U.S. Saving Rate is Low: A
Conflict between the National Accountant's and Individual
Saver's Perspectives." In Economic Theory and Reality:
Selected Essays on their Disparities and Reconciliation. Brookfield, VT:
E. Elgar, 188-196.
Wilcox, David W. 1991. "Household Spending and Saving:
Measurement, Trends, and Analysis." Federal Reserve Bulletin 77
(January): 1-17.
Yan, Xiaoyi. 2000. "Understanding Saving and Wealth
Accumulation." Manuscript. Ottawa: Statistics Canada, Income and
Expenditure Accounts Division, July.
Zacharias, Ajit. 2002. "A Note on the Hicksian Concept of
Income." Working paper no. 342. Annandaleon-Hudson, NY: The Levy
Economics Institue at Bard College, February. <www.levy.org>.
Maria Perozek is an economist at the Federal Reserve Board, and
Marshall Reinsdorf is an economist at the Bureau of Economic Analysis.
The authors are grateful to Eric Engen, Brent Moulton, Larry Slifman,
and David Wilcox for helpful comments.