Alternative measures of personal saving.
Reinsdorf, Marshall B.
IN 2005, annual personal saving in the national income and product
accounts (NIPAs) was negative for the first time since 1933, dipping to
-0.4 percent of disposable personal income (DPI) (chart 1). This
development, the culmination of a long slide in the personal saving rate
that began in the 1980s, has sparked much interest in how personal
saving is measured and its relation to broader concepts of national
saving and changes in personal wealth. Among the reasons for this
interest are concerns about whether families are saving enough for
retirement and for protection against financial setbacks, whether the
Nation has become too dependent on foreign funding for financing its
investment needs, and whether spending levels that exceed current income
can be sustained.
[GRAPHIC 1 OMITTED]
Different questions require different answers, and the NIPA measure
of personal saving does not provide the answer to every worthwhile
question about the saving behavior of persons. To provide additional
information on this topic, this article presents updated estimates of
alternative measures of personal saving and related concepts. These
measures were introduced in 2002 and updated in 2004. (1)
Personal saving is the portion of personal income that is left over
after personal current taxes and outlays for personal consumption
expenditures, nonmortgage interest payments, and net current transfers
to government and the rest of the world. It excludes capital gains
because capital gains represent changes in the prices of assets that are
already owned, not unspent portions of income receipts. (2) Personal
saving represents the contribution from persons to national saving,
which is the total amount that is available to fund investment in fixed
assets, inventories, or foreign assets.
The alternative measures of personal saving discussed in this
article differ from the NIPA measure in the way that they measure
consumption or disposable personal income. However, they are still
calculated as the residual that remains after consumption and related
outlays are subtracted from disposable personal income. Three of the
alternative measures provide additional detail about the components of
personal saving by changing the definitions of sector boundaries or the
treatment of a payment between sectors. These changes do not imply any
increase or decrease in total national saving, but they do alter the
amounts of saving attributed to each sector of the economy. A fourth
alternative expands the definition of investment, thus implying a higher
level of national saving.
To provide additional context, this article also discusses broader
measures of saving, such as private saving, national saving, and
measures of personal wealth that take capital gains into account.
Alternative Estimates of Personal Saving
Households and nonprofit institutions serving households
The NIPAs divide the domestic economy into three sectors: The
business sector, the government sector, and the personal sector. The
personal sector includes nonprofit institutions serving households
(NPISHs), which account for most nonprofit institutions. This means, for
example, that the medical care component of personal consumption
expenditures (PCE) includes the expenses of nonprofit hospitals for
providing medical care but excludes the sales of services to the
patients of those hospitals.
The common practice of interpreting the personal saving rate as a
measure of the saving behavior of households is reasonable because
households are the predominant component of the personal sector.
Nonetheless, a more precise picture of household behavior can be
obtained by deconsolidating the personal sector into a household sector
and a nonprofit sector and then calculating household saving as the
amount of disposable household income that is left over after all
household outlays. Household income differs from personal income because
it excludes the rental income, interest, and dividends received by
NPISHs and because it includes transfers from NPISHs received by
households. Household outlays differ from personal outlays in two ways:
(1) They exclude expenditures of NPISHs but include the sales of
services to persons by NPISHs, and (2) they exclude transfers from
NPISHs to government and the rest of the world but include transfers
from households to NPISHs. (3)
Until 1995 and again after 2002, the household saving rate was
within 0.2 percentage point of the personal saving rate (chart 2). In
between those years, the household saving rate fell substantially below
the personal saving rate. In the late 1990s, transfers and bequests from
households to NPISHs grew rapidly, partly reflecting large gains in
stock prices, while expenditures of NPISHs accelerated gradually. As a
result, saving by NPISHs increased, and the household saving rate fell
faster than the personal saving rate. After the turn of the millennium,
this process was reversed. Transfers to NPISHs fell or were flat, while
the expenditures of NPISHs maintained their upward momentum. Indeed, the
personal saving rate would have been half a percentage point higher in
2003 if the NPISH saving rate had remained at its value in 2000.
[GRAPHIC 2 OMITTED]
During the late 1990s, declines in the personal saving rate were
often attributed to the effects of increases in personal wealth created
by large capital gains. Yet, when subsequent declines in stock prices
reduced personal wealth, the rebound in personal saving was
disappointingly weak. A detailed look at the components of the personal
sector reveals that household saving had a substantial bounce in 2002,
remaining above its former trend line until 2004. In 2005, household
saving again turned sharply down; just 0.2 of the 2.4-percentage-point
drop in the household saving rate can be dismissed as an aberration due
to the direct effects of Hurricanes Katrina, Rita, and Wilma.
Defined benefit pension plans
Pension plans, which are employer-sponsored retirement plans, are
classified as defined benefit (DB) or defined contribution (DC) plans
depending on their benefit formula. In a typical DB plan, pension
benefit levels depend on length of service and some measure of average
or final pay. In DC pension plans, funds for retirement are accumulated from employer and employee contributions, investment income earned on
plan assets, and capital gains on plan assets. Historically, most
employee retirement plans were DB pension plans, and they are still the
predominant type of plan for government employees. In the private
sector, however, for the past two decades, newly established pension
plans have almost always been DC plans.
In the NIPAs, both DC and DB pension plans are included in the
personal sector. In the case of DC plans, this approach is the only
logical one, because the assets in these plans clearly belong to the
plan participants. However, ownership of the assets held by DB plans is
more ambiguous. The inclusion of these plans in the personal sector
rather than in the sector of the employer who sponsors them can be
justified in two ways: (1) Employers face formidable barriers to
accessing DB plan assets for their own use, and (2) the assets of
private DB plans by law should approximate the actuarial value of the
pension promises made to the employees. However, even though employers
cannot directly benefit from money in DB plans, they can benefit
indirectly because growth in DB plan assets relieves employers of future
obligations to make contributions, while plan losses have the opposite
effect. Employers therefore bear the investment risk. Employers also
have control over how DB plan assets are invested. Finally, retirees
undoubtedly think of the benefits they receive from DB plans as income
rather than as liquidations of assets that they owned all along. Tests
of risk-bearing, control, and retiree perceptions can therefore justify
an alternative treatment that treats employers as the owners of the
assets in DB plans.
To calculate disposable personal income with DB pension plans
outside the boundary of the personal sector, employer and employee
contributions to DB plans, along with interest and dividend income from
DB plan assets, are subtracted from the NIPA measure of disposable
personal income. Benefits received by persons from DB plans are then
added. The contributions and investment income exceed the plans'
benefit payments, so the measure of disposable personal income falls
after these adjustments. However, the measure of personal saving falls
less than the measure of disposable personal income, because PCE must
also be adjusted by removing administrative expenses of DB pension
plans. (4)
As is evident from comparing the alternative personal saving rate
without DB pension plans with the NIPA personal saving rate in chart 3,
the adjustments to the measures of personal income and personal
consumption together imply that saving by DB pension plans added about
1.6 percentage points to the NIPA personal saving rate until 1995.
Saving by DB plans then turned down until 2001, when it added just 0.1
percentage point to the personal saving rate. In 2002 and 2003,
increases in contributions resulted in enough saving by DB plans to
bring their contribution to the NIPA personal saving rate back up to 0.8
percentage point. After 1995, many sponsors of private DB plans were
able to reduce their contributions without falling short of targeted
plan funding levels because DB plan assets had large capital gains in
the late 1990s. Conversely, in 2002 and 2003, funding gaps following
capital losses in 2000-2002 compelled many plan sponsors to make large
contributions. Even so, DB plans added only half as much to the NIPA
personal saving rate in 2003 as in 1995. The difference between 2003 and
1995 in the DB plans' saving rate may be attributed to growth in
their benefit expenses and, since 2000, to a lack of growth in their
dividend and interest income.
[GRAPHIC 3 OMITTED]
Taxes on realized capital gains
Ironically, realized capital gains can have a negative effect on
the NIPA measures of disposable personal income and personal saving.
Capital gains are excluded from NIPA concepts of income whether they are
realized or unrealized. However, realized capital gains are subject to
Federal personal income taxes. Disposable personal income in the NIPAs
is calculated by subtracting personal income taxes, including those
attributable to capital gains, from personal income.
Capital gains are not taxed separately from ordinary personal
income, and in a set of accounts that must cover the entire economy, the
need to include capital gains taxes in government current receipts
implies that they should be left in personal current taxes.
Nevertheless, an alternative treatment of capital gains taxes that
classifies them as capital transfers to government can provide a useful
perspective on the saving behavior of persons. This alternative
treatment raises the measures of disposable personal income and personal
saving because capital transfers from persons to government are excluded
from personal current taxes. (5)
To disentangle taxes on capital gains from taxes on ordinary
income, an assumption is needed. The assumption is that the ordinary
taxable income is received first, so that capital gains are the marginal
source of taxable income. For any income tax return that reports capital
gains, the tax on those gains can then be estimated as the absolute
value of the change in the total tax due when capital gains are set
equal to zero. (6)
The alternative saving rate that treats capital gains taxes as
capital transfers averages almost 1 percentage point higher than the
NIPA measure (chart 4). Moreover, the steepness of the decline in the
personal saving rate between the early 1990s and 2005 is slightly
reduced by the new treatment of capital gains taxes, so the alternative
saving rate remains positive in 2005 at 0.6 percent of DPI. On the
whole, however, the alternative personal saving rate has the same
profile as the NIPA personal saving rate. A significant difference in
slope is visible only from 1996 to 2000, which corresponds to the bull
market period of the late 1990s with a 1-year lag.
[GRAPHIC 4 OMITTED]
Consumer durable goods as investment
In the NIPAs, purchases by persons of motor vehicles and other
consumer durable goods are treated as consumption expenditures rather
than as investment. Un like real estate, these goods cannot be resold
for at least as much as the original purchase price, so they are not a
good store of value or a source of funding for retirement. They do,
however, provide services over a number of years, and consumers reduce
their future expenses when they purchase a durable good because a repeat
purchase of that same good becomes unnecessary for the next few years.
Therefore, purchases of durable goods may be treated as investment for
some purposes. This treatment raises the measure of personal saving,
because investment expenditures are not subtracted from disposable
personal income in the calculation of personal saving.
One way to implement a treatment of consumer durable goods as
investment would be to replicate the treatment of owner-occupied housing
in the NIPAs. This treatment would require the estimation of a rental
value for the use of the stock of consumer goods from which owners'
expenses for depreciation, interest, and personal property taxes would
be subtracted in order to obtain an imputed profit. This imputed profit
would then be added to the rental income component of disposable
personal income, resulting in a small rise in the denominator used to
calculate the alternative personal saving rate. However, a much simpler
method that gives a result that is identical for practical purposes is
just to add the net investment in consumer durable goods to the NIPA
measure of personal saving, keeping the NIPA measure of disposable
personal income as the denominator of the rate calculation. Net
investment rather than gross investment is added because if durable
goods are recognized as part of wealth, the decay in this wealth caused
by their wearing out or obsolescence cannot be ignored.
Net investment in consumer durable goods ranges from under 1.0
percent of disposable personal income in the recession year of 1991 to
around 3.0 percent of disposable personal income in 1985-87 and in
1999-2000 (chart 5). Since 2003, it has been 2.5 percent or less, so
from 1985 to 2005, the cumulative decline in the personal saving rate
with consumer durable goods is greater than the decline in the NIPA
personal saving rate (a drop of 10.0 percentage points, compared with a
drop of 9.4 percentage points). However, the timing of some of the
decline is shifted to earlier years. Indeed, in the most recent decade,
the inclusion of consumer durable goods slows the decline in the saving
rate slightly. In 2005, adding consumer durable goods raises the
measured saving rate to nearly 2.0 percent.
[GRAPHIC 5 OMITTED]
Broader Measures of Saving
Low personal saving is a less critical problem if saving in the
other sectors of the economy is strong because saving in other sectors
can substitute for personal saving for some purposes. In particular,
financing the Nation's investment needs is an important role of
personal saving, but saving by business (which consists of undistributed corporate profits) and by government also provides funds for this
purpose. Saving by businesses may also increase the value of equity
assets held by persons, helping their wealth to grow even if they are
not saving any of their own income. For this reason, crediting the
saving done by businesses to the persons who own the businesses may be
viewed as a reasonable alternative way to measure personal saving.
The NIPAs, however, already contain a close approximation for this
measure, because net private saving in NIPA table 5.1 combines saving by
business and saving by persons. (7) Net private saving as a percent of
national income falls a bit less than personal saving after 2000 because
saving by business increased (chart 6). Over the longer run, however,
business saving as a percent of national income has been relatively
stable, so that the long-run trend line of net private saving is roughly
parallel to that of personal saving, with a difference in level of about
3.0 percentage points.
[GRAPHIC 6 OMITTED]
Net national saving is a comprehensive measure of net saving by
government, business, and persons. In 1995-2001, net national saving was
substantially higher than personal saving, an exception to the pattern
that prevailed in 1976-94, when dissaving by government roughly
cancelled out saving by business so that net national saving was similar
to personal saving.
Net saving includes as an expense consumption of fixed capital,
which is an estimate of the cost of wear and tear and obsolescence of
the capital stock. Measures of gross saving ignore this noncash expense.
Gross national saving has declined slightly less than net national
saving. In 2001-2005, consumption of fixed capital ranged from 14.0 to
14.8 percent of national income, compared with about 13.5 percent in
many earlier years. Since 2000, large losses due to the attacks of
September 11, 2001, and to the hurricanes in 2004 and 2005 are one cause
of the slightly higher expense for consumption of fixed capital after
2000. Changes in the composition of the capital stock have also
contributed to it.
After adjustment for the statistical discrepancy, the excess of
gross domestic investment over gross national saving equals the
Nation's net borrowing, the amount of foreign saving that the
Nation relies on to fund its investment needs. Domestic investment has
not followed the same downward trajectory as national saving. As a
result, the Nation's reliance on foreign saving to fund its
investment needs has grown to levels that are unprecedented during the
period for which BEA has data, 1929 to the present. Whether the current
level of net borrowing represents an unsustainable imbalance has been
the topic of much discussion, and questions have also been raised about
the growing exposure of U.S. financial markets to foreign changes in
investment philosophy or saving behavior.
Sources of Wealth Accumulation
Growth in personal wealth occurs either when current income is
saved and used to acquire assets or to retire liabilities or when the
prices of assets that persons already own rise and generate capital
gains. Information on changes in personal wealth is not part of the
NIPAs, but this information is available in the Federal Reserve
Board's flow of funds accounts.
Capital gains and losses are generally a much more important source
of change in personal wealth than saving out of current income (chart
7). They are, however, quite volatile. Furthermore, if indirect effects
are considered, capital gains are responsible for a smaller share of
growth in personal wealth than is suggested by the proximity of capital
gains in chart 7 to change in net worth.
[GRAPHIC 7 OMITTED]
The change in the net worth in the personal sector's balance
sheet generally has three significant components: A positive effect from
net acquisitions of assets, a negative effect from growth in
liabilities, and an effect from capital gains or losses. To analyze the
change in net worth, the effect of growth in liabilities is
conventionally offset against the net acquisitions of assets because
this yields an estimate of personal investment. The convention of
subtracting growth in liabilities from asset acquisitions might lead one
to infer that growth in liabilities has no connection to capital gains,
but this may not be true. In particular, ignoring the links between
capital gains and liability growth can give an exaggerated impression of
the degree to which capital gains drive increases in net worth.
Capital gains in general have been found to have positive effects
on consumption, and some of the funds for this additional consumption
are likely to come from debt. Moreover, capital gains on real
estate-which have accounted for most of the personal sector's
capital gains since 1999--tend to be coincident in timing with the
growth of mortgage debt. Among the reasons for this pattern is that a
fall in interest rates or a liberalization of credit standards raises
both mortgage borrowing and demand for houses. Causality can run in the
other direction, too, if decreases in home affordability induce buyers
to choose larger or longer loans or if the rising ability of homeowners
to furnish collateral induces them to do a cash-out refinancing or open
up a home equity line of credit. In 2003-2005, increases in mortgage
debt averaged 11.2 percent of disposable personal income. About
three-quarters of this amount is linked to capital gains on real estate
under the assumption that changes in persons' real estate equity
equal 55 percent of changes in the value of their real estate assets?
Conclusion
Alternative measures of personal saving neither change the
conclusion that personal saving has fallen dramatically in the past two
decades, nor do they imply any decrease in the record levels of national
borrowing of recent years. They do, however, shed light on some of the
underlying sources of influence on trends in personal saving.
Jennifer Mykijewycz assisted with the preparation of this article.
(1.) See Marshall B. Reinsdorf, "Alternative Measures of
Personal Saving," SURVEY OF CURRENT BUSINESS 84 (September 2004):
17-27, and Maria G. Perozek and Marshall B. Reinsdorf, "Alternative
Measures of Personal Saving," SURVEY 82 (April 2002): 13-24. These
articles explain the advantages and disadvantages of the various
measures in detail. They also provide an overview of the conceptual
framework for measuring saving in the national accounts.
(2.) For more information on the treatment of capital gains in
national income accounting, see Marshall B. Reinsdorf, "Saving,
Wealth, Investment, and the Current-Account Deficit," SURVEY 85
(April 2005): 3.
(3.) See NIPA table 2.9 and Charles Ian Mead, Clinton P. McCully,
and Marshall B. Reinsdorf, "Income and Outlays of Households and of
Nonprofit Institutions Serving Households," SURVEY 83 (April 2003):
13-17.
(4.) In making these calculations, state and local pension plans
are all treated as DB plans because of a lack of separate data on the DB
and DC plan components of their plan totals. These plans, however, are
predominately DB plans.
(5.) In the NIPAs, capital transfers to government consist of gift
and estate taxes.
(6.) Quarterly estimated taxes on capital gains realized in the
fourth quarter (which include most of the capital gains distributions
made by mutual funds) are not due until the following January, and
taxpayers can wait until they file their tax return to pay the taxes if
their capital gains are not large. Consequently, capital gains taxes are
more likely than taxes on ordinary income to affect spending in the next
calendar year. Chart 4 assumes that a fourth of the taxes on the capital
gains realized in any calendar year are paid in the following calendar
year. This raises the alternative saving rate by 0.2 percentage point in
2001 but lowers it by 0.1 percentage point in each of the 2 preceding
years.
(7.) To consolidate corporate businesses with resident households
and institutions that own them in a precise way, foreign business
ownership by U.S. residents and U.S. business ownership by foreign
residents would have to be taken into account. Net private saving is a
good approximation for this precise concept because most of the equity
of U.S. corporations is owned by households and nonprofit institutions
in the personal sector, and a subtraction from private saving to account
for the portion of the equity of U.S. businesses owned by nonresidents
would be approximately offset by an addition to account for the equity
in foreign businesses owned by U.S. residents.
(8.) In 2003-2005, homeowner's equity averaged 54.7 percent of
the value of their real estate. As the large capital gains of those
years pushed up the value of personal real estate, the change in
homeowner's equity was actually less than 55 percent of the change
in the value of real estate. The assumption that 55 percent of the
capital gains went into homeowner's equity may therefore be too
high, implying that an even larger effect on growth of liabilities.
Table 1. Alternative Measures of the Personal Saving Rate
[Percent]
1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991
Households ... ... ... ... ... ... ...
Defined benefit
pension plans
excluded ... ... ... 5.6 5.5 5.4 5.7
Capital gains
taxes included 9.7 9.4 8.0 8.2 8.0 7.6 7.8
Consumer durable
goods as
investment 11.9 11.4 9.8 10.0 9.4 8.8 8.2
Addenda:
NIPA personal
saving rate 9.0 8.2 7.0 7.3 7.1 7.0 7.3
Change in net
worth rate (1) 47.0 44.2 29.6 40.0 41.7 7.9 35.3
NPISH saving
rate (2) ... ... ... ... ... ... ...
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
Households 7.5 5.6 4.7 4.4 3.7 3.0 3.8
Defined benefit
pension plans
excluded 6.3 4.3 3.2 3.0 2.7 2.5 3.2
Capital gains
taxes included 8.2 6.4 5.5 5.4 5.0 4.9 5.6
Consumer durable
goods as
investment 8.8 7.3 6.6 6.4 6.0 5.8 6.8
Addenda:
NIPA personal
saving rate 7.7 5.8 4.8 4.6 4.0 3.6 4.3
Change in net
worth rate (1) 20.2 27.2 15.0 50.1 45.4 60.7 53.0
NPISH saving
rate (2) 3.0 2.7 2.2 3.0 3.9 7.0 5.8
1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005
Households 1.7 1.6 1.4 2.2 2.0 1.9 -0.5
Defined benefit
pension plans
excluded 1.4 1.6 1.6 1.8 1.3 1.4 -1.1
Capital gains
taxes included 3.9 4.0 2.8 3.0 2.7 2.8 0.6
Consumer durable
goods as
investment 5.3 5.2 4.4 5.0 4.6 4.4 1.9
Addenda:
NIPA personal
saving rate 2.4 2.3 1.8 2.4 2.1 2.0 -0.4
Change in net
worth rate (1) 73.4 -9.8 -13.3 -20.1 63.2 46.0 42.0
NPISH saving
rate (2) 6.7 7.2 3.3 2.0 1.0 1.3 1.6
(1.) As a percent of disposable personal income.
(2.) As a percent of income of nonprofit institutions serving
households (NPISHs) plus receipts from sales. NIPAs National
income and product accounts
Table 2. National Saving, Investment, and Borrowing
[As a percent of national income]
1985 1986 1987 1988 1989
Personal saving
with accrued wages 7.5 6.9 5.8 6.0 5.9
Plus: Undistributed
corporate profits 3.6 2.7 3.0 3.5 2.5
Equals: Net
private saving 11.1 9.5 8.8 9.5 8.5
Plus: Net
government saving -4.1 -4.4 -3.2 -2.6 -2.3
Equals: Net
national saving 7.0 5.2 5.6 7.0 6.2
Plus: Consumption
of fixed capital 13.6 13.6 13.5 13.1 13.3
Equals: Gross saving 20.6 18.8 19.1 20.1 19.6
Net saving plus
statistical
discrepancy 7.5 6.4 6.1 6.5 7.0
Less: Net domestic
investment 10.4 10.0 9.8 9.0 8.9
Less: Capital account
transactions 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Equals: Net lending (1) 0.0 -3.6 -0.6 -2.5 -1.8
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994
Personal saving
with accrued wages 5.9 6.2 6.4 5.0 4.4
Plus: Undistributed
corporate profits 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.9 2.8
Equals: Net
private saving 8.3 8.7 8.9 7.9 7.2
Plus: Net
government saving -3.2 -4.2 -5.4 -4.7 -3.3
Equals: Net
national saving 5.1 4.6 3.6 3.2 3.9
Plus: Consumption
of fixed capital 13.4 13.9 13.6 13.4 13.6
Equals: Gross saving 18.5 18.4 17.2 16.7 17.5
Net saving plus
statistical
discrepancy 6.4 5.9 5.4 5.6 6.2
Less: Net domestic
investment 7.7 5.7 6.1 6.9 7.9
Less: Capital account
transactions 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0
Equals: Net lending (1) -1.5 0.2 -0.7 -1.2 -1.7
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
Personal saving
with accrued wages 4.1 3.4 3.0 3.6 2.0
Plus: Undistributed
corporate profits 3.5 3.8 3.9 2.6 3.1
Equals: Net
private saving 7.6 7.1 6.9 6.2 5.1
Plus: Net
government saving -2.9 -1.7 -0.2 1.2 1.9
Equals: Net
national saving 4.7 5.5 6.7 7.3 7.0
Plus: Consumption
of fixed capital 13.6 13.4 13.4 13.3 13.4
Equals: Gross saving 18.4 18.9 20.0 20.6 20.3
Net saving plus
statistical
discrepancy 6.3 6.8 7.6 7.1 6.5
Less: Net domestic
investment 7.7 8.3 9.2 9.6 9.8
Less: Capital account
transactions 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1
Equals: Net lending (1) -1.4 -1.5 -1.5 -2.4 -3.4
2000 2001 2002
Personal saving
with accrued wages 1.9 1.5 2.0
Plus: Undistributed
corporate profits 2.0 2.1 3.2
Equals: Net
private saving 3.9 3.6 5.2
Plus: Net
government saving 2.7 0.6 -3.1
Equals: Net
national saving 6.6 4.2 2.1
Plus: Consumption
of fixed capital 13.5 14.3 14.0
Equals: Gross saving 20.1 18.5 16.1
Net saving plus
statistical
discrepancy 5.2 3.2 1.9
Less: Net domestic
investment 9.7 7.3 6.9
Less: Capital account
transactions 0.0 0.0 0.0
Equals: Net lending (1) -4.5 -4.1 -5.0
2003 2004 2005
Personal saving
with accrued wages 2.0 1.6 -0.3
Plus: Undistributed
corporate profits 3.4 3.3 3.3
Equals: Net
private saving 5.3 4.9 3.0
Plus: Net
government saving -4.1 -3.9 -2.9
Equals: Net
national saving 1.3 1.0 0.1
Plus: Consumption
of fixed capital 13.9 14.0 14.8
Equals: Gross saving 15.1 15.1 14.9
Net saving plus
statistical
discrepancy 1.8 1.7 0.7
Less: Net domestic
investment 7.1 8.0 7.9
Less: Capital account
transactions 0.0 0.0 0.0
Equals: Net lending (1) -5.4 -0.4 -7.2
(1.) Net lending is the negative of net borrowing