Assessing cross-industry effects of B2B e-commerce.
Apte, Uday M. ; Nath, Hiranya K.
ABSTRACT
The productivity gain that an industry experiences by engaging in
B2B e-commerce gets transmitted to other industries through input-output
linkages. This paper considers a multi-industry equilibrium model that
explicitly incorporates input-output structure to examine the
propagation of productivity gain across industries and to provide a
framework to quantitatively evaluate the overall impact of B2B
e-commerce. This model also helps identify the industries with potential
for largest impact on other industries. We also demonstrate how this
model can be used to make projections of output growth that would result
from the introduction of B2B in selected industries.
INTRODUCTION
The economic impact of the Internet has already been visible: in
commodity market, in capital market as well as in labor market. There
has been a drop in prices of many consumer items. Online trading of
stocks and bonds has increased over the years. (1) A sizeable portion of
the labor force is employed in Internet related activities. As we will
see shortly, the revenue generated and the number of workers employed by
the Internet based economic activities have been so large that they can
well be described as constituting an independent economic system. One
characteristic feature of these developments is the speed. This Internet
based economy has grown very fast within a very short period of time.
Enough time has not elapsed to observe long-run economic impact of the
Internet. Nevertheless, speculations abound. Economists are divided
between predicting long-run growth and low inflation in one end, and
dismissing it as a temporary phenomenon in the other. Although recent
dot com bust has produced more skeptics than ever, it is important to
recognize that the potential size and overall economic impact of the
Internet is larger than what we can imagine today. However, given that
the Internet has taken the world, or at least the advanced economies, by
storm, it is worthwhile to examine some of the speculations for their
substance.
From the point of view of business and economics, trading over the
Internet, also known as electronic commerce or e-commerce, is the
fastest growing Internet based economic activity in the present time.
The phenomenal growth of e-commerce in recent times has the most visible
effects on the consumption economy. The consumer items are cheaper
online than in conventional stores. (2) Internet cuts down on
transaction costs and makes goods available to consumers at lower
prices. Moreover, consumers are exposed to a wider range of choices.
This proliferation of e-commerce has an indirect effect: competition
from the Internet has forced traditional retailers to cut their prices.
The speculation among the experts, however, is that the
business-to-business (B2B) e-commerce will have the largest impact in
the economy. (3) B2B e-commerce can simply be defined as transactions
between businesses conducted over the Internet. Since it involves
trading of goods in the intermediate stages of the production process
the value and volume of transactions will relatively be high. Moreover,
the gains from engaging in B2B e-commerce in terms of increased
productivity or reduced cost have indirect effects on other businesses
through various linkages. This paper examines the cross-industry effects
of B2B gain that spill over through inter-industry interactions in the
context of a multi-industry equilibrium model. It also identifies the
sectors that have the potential for spreading the beneficial effects
across industries by reducing costs. In particular, we are interested in
direct as well as indirect (which is sometimes referred to as
'second-round effects') impact of B2B e-commerce across
industries. The model provides a framework for quantitatively assessing
the impact of B2B e-commerce across industries. From both qualitative
and quantitative analysis it appears that some industries hold brighter
prospects than others do.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we
provide a discussion on the definition of the Internet economy, its size
and growth. We also discuss various aspects of B2B e-commerce. Section 3
discusses how B2B e-commerce benefits industries directly by reducing
costs or increasing productivity, and indirectly through various
inter-industry linkages. We then present a simple multi-industry
equilibrium model (4) to evaluate how inter-industry linkages help the
gains from B2B in one industry get transmitted to the others. First we
specify the model and then define a competitive equilibrium. By
explicitly introducing the input-output structure into the model we
theoretically examine the impact of using the Internet for B2B
e-commerce on the output and prices of different industries. Then we
calibrate the parameters of the model so that we can make quantitative
statements about the economy-wide impact of introducing B2B e-commerce
in different industries. Section 4 investigates for each individual
industry the effects of introducing B2B e-commerce on output of various
goods in the economy. Quantitative implications of introducing B2B in a
few industries have been worked out and included in this section.
Section 5 includes our concluding remarks.
THE INTERNET ECONOMY AND B2B E-COMMERCE
Electronic commerce is an important and integral part of the
burgeoning Internet economy, which is loosely defined to encompass all
resources related to, and all economic activities based on the Internet
technology. The transactions carried out between different agents, i.e.,
between retailers and consumers, between wholesale traders and
retailers, or between firms, over the Internet, constitute what we know
as e-commerce. Depending on who are on the two sides of these
transactions, e-commerce is given fancy names. For example, when it
involves transactions between business and consumers it is called B2C.
Similarly, when such transactions are between firms, i.e., between
businesses, it is named B2B. Before explaining the notion of B2B
e-commerce and its economic significance we will have an overview of the
Internet economy, its size, structure and growth.
The Internet Economy
In a recent comprehensive study conducted by the Center for
Research in Electronic Commerce of the University of Texas at Austin,
the Internet economy has been defined as 'a complete economic
system consisting of (i) ubiquitous, low cost communication networks
using Internet technologies and standards, (ii) applications and human
capital that enable business to be conducted over this network
infrastructure, (iii) interconnected electronic markets that operate
over the network and applications infrastructure, (iv) producers and
intermediaries providing a variety of digital products and services to
facilitate market efficiency and liquidity, and (v) emerging policy and
legal frameworks for conducting business over the Internet' (page
7). In this new emerging economic system, information plays the key
role, a role that is played by the physical assets in the traditional
economy.
According to this study, in 2000 the Internet economy employed
2.476 million workers and generated half a trillion dollars in revenue.
Various studies (5) indicate increased use of internet in every walk of
life. According to a report from the Online Publishers Association and
ComScore, consumer spending on online content in the US totaled USD1.3
billion in 2002, that marks an increase of 95 percent compared to 2001.
eMarketer predicts that by 2004, worldwide e-commerce revenues would
total USD2.7 trillion. According to this research company's latest
report, the US will account for over one-half of worldwide revenues this
year. A study by Nielsen-Netratings reveals that the top traditional
advertisers increased their share of online advertising by 30 percent by
the end of 2002. More than 22 million US Internet users visited an
online tax services website during February 2003. New research from Pew Internet and American Life indicates that two-thirds of politically
engaged Internet users during the 2002 election cycle sent or received
email related to the campaign. The fact that America's leading
cable and DSL providers added a combined 6.4 million high-speed Internet
subscribers during 2002 is evidence of continuing expansion of the
Internet economy. Leichtman Research Group forecasts that the total
number of broadband cable and DSL Internet subscribers in the US will
surpass the number of narrowband subscribers in 2005 and will grow to
nearly 49 million by the end of 2007. New jobs are being created to
cater to the needs of this ever expanding Internet economy. Workers are
being shifted from other vocations to take advantage of new
opportunities. The convenience, flexibility and efficiency of doing
business through the Internet have contributed to this phenomenal growth
of this emerging Internet economy. There is no doubt that the Internet
economy is going to be a major contributor to the U.S. economy.
What is B2B?
E-commerce is the fastest growing segment of the Internet economy.
Within this segment, B2B e-commerce is considered to have the brightest
prospect of future growth and expansion. As we have already mentioned,
it has been projected that the B2B will soon outpace B2C with its
turnover growing up to ten times higher by the end of year 2003. The
Goldman Sachs Report on the e-commerce has defined 'B2B' as
'business-to-business commerce conducted over the Internet'
(page 2). B2B has two major components: 'e-frastructure' and
'e-market'. Auction solutions software, content management
software, and web-based commerce enablers constitute what the report
calls 'e-frastructure'. Essentially, these three components
provide the infrastructure for conducting electronic commerce. On the
other hand, the 'web sites where buyers and sellers come together
to communicate, exchange ideas, advertise, bid in auctions, conduct
transactions, and coordinate inventory and fulfillment' constitute
the marketplace where the e-commerce actually takes place.
HOW DOES B2B AFFECT PRICE AND OUTPUT ACROSS INDUSTRIES?
In addition to the speculation that B2B itself would evolve into a
revenue-and-employment generating business, it can as well be argued
that it would have beneficial impact on traditional industries. Since
B2B e-commerce is directly associated with the production process of the
industries the impact could be widespread. By improving flow of
information it would ensure allocation of resources to their most
productive uses, and thus would make markets more efficient. Efficient
allocation of resources would make production process less costly and
therefore more productive. (6) Since industries are linked to one
another as buyers and sellers of inputs, the productivity gain (7) to an
industry that is engaged in B2B e-commerce, will eventually spill over
to other industries through various linkages. Thus, B2B e-commerce will
have economy-wide effects. (8) However, how the gain in one particular
industry affects other industries in the economy depends on which
industry experiences these productivity gains, and on the nature of its
interactions with other industries in the economy.
Intuitively, a productivity gain in an industry will entail a
reduction in unit cost of its production. It implies that the price of
its output will fall. If this particular good is used as inputs in other
industries then it will lead to a reduction in the cost of production in
the downstream industries, which in its turn will presumably lead to a
fall in prices and rise in output of various commodities. On the other
hand, since industries can now easily procure their intermediate inputs
they would not accumulate large amount of inventory at a particular
period of time. In other words, the scale of operation in terms of
productive capacity will be smaller. Also, as the allocation of
resources improves and as a result the resources become more productive,
the demand for intermediate inputs or other resources might decrease. It
may have negative effects on the upstream industries. Thus B2B
e-commerce potentially has both positive and negative effects.
However, we would like to categorize the effects of B2B gain into
direct and indirect effects. Direct effects are realized in the
industries that purchase intermediate inputs through B2B e-commerce. If
this productivity gain does not affect the demand for its output, these
effects are expected to be in the form of rise in output and fall in
prices. Indirect effects, on the other hand, are realized in other
industries, which have downstream or upstream linkages with the industry
experiencing B2B gain. In downstream industries it would look like a
supply shock: price would fall and output would rise. In upstream
industries it would look like a negative demand shock: both price and
output fall. Total effects depend on the nature (whether positive or
negative) and relative weights of direct and indirect effects.
In order to help us understand the direct effects, let us consider
a partial equilibrium framework. Consider figure 1.a. In the short-run,
industry i has an upward sloping supply curve [S.sub.i] and faces a
downward sloping demand curve [D.sub.i]. Suppose the industry is in
short-run equilibrium at [E.sub.i] with equilibrium price [P.sub.i] and
output [Q.sub.i]. As productivity increases as a result of B2B
e-commerce the supply curve shifts to the right. This is represented in
the diagram by [S.sub.i]'. In the new equilibrium [E.sub.i]',
price declines to [P.sub.i]' and output increases to
[Q.sub.i]'. Note that in this illustration we have assumed that the
B2B has not affected the demand for the output of industry i. B2B has
similar indirect effects in the downstream industries. Indirect effects
in the upstream industries, on the other hand, would look like negative
demand shock. In figure 1.b, the demand curve faced by industry j, which
provides intermediate inputs to the industry i experiencing B2B gain,
shifts to the left for reasons explained above. The new equilibrium
price and output are [P.sub.j] and [Q.sub.j] respectively.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
However, in a more general framework industries interact in such a
complicated fashion that it is difficult to distinguish between
downstream and upstream linkages among industries. Two industries may be
linked to one another both as downstream and upstream industries. In
such cases, it is difficult to infer what the net effect would be for
each of these industries. Moreover, the industry that experiences B2B
gain could also be a major provider of intermediate inputs to itself. In
such a situation, the positive impact of B2B gain could be neutralized by the negative impact of an opposite demand effect. In other words,
since the industry now becomes more productive it uses less of its
output as intermediate inputs. That is, the demand for its output falls.
The net effect would depend on the relative magnitudes of the positive
supply effect of productivity growth and the negative demand effect of
fall in inventory accumulation.
In brief, the productivity gain that is induced by the B2B
e-commerce would set out a chain of changes that would work out through
a complicated network of interactions among industries. Intuitively, it
is not clear what the final effects would be. In order to capture the
interactions among industries in the form of input-output relationship,
we now construct a simple multi-industry equilibrium model that is
capable of predicting the cross-industry effects of a B2B gain in
individual industries. Note that this is a static model. However, there
could well be dynamic effects of this type of productivity shock. After
all, it is very likely that these productivity shocks will affect the
economy with time lags. Also, there are other factors in the economy,
which are important for the behavior of the economic variables. Since
our aim is to evaluate short-run direct and indirect effects of B2B gain
across industries, we are considering a simple production economy with
an explicit input-output structure that captures inter-industry
interactions. In the model, it is assumed that introduction of B2B
e-commerce is an exogenous factor or a 'shock' that has
positive productivity effect on the industries.
A Simple Multi-Industry Equilibrium Model
Model Specification
We assume that there are n industries in the economy. Each industry
consists of large number of identical firms. The production technology
available to a representative firm in industry i is given by the
following production function (9)
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
where [a.sub.ij] > 0 and [n.summation over (j=1)] < 1 for i =
1,2, .... n. [Y.sub.i] is the output of industry i, (10) [Z.sub.i] is a
random variable that denotes a shift in total factor productivity in
industry i due to B2B e-commerce. (11) Thus use of Internet will
presumably increase productivity and that will be captured by [Z.sub.i]
s in our model. [X.sub.ij] is the quantity of industry j output used as
input in industry i. Since we have not explicitly introduced labor and
capital in this production function one can interpret it as a short-run
production function. That is, capital and labor do not change while
intermediate inputs are the only variable factors. Thus the production
function exhibits decreasing returns to scale in intermediate inputs.
The firm maximizes its short-run profits subject to a constraint imposed
by the technology given by (1). The short-run profit function for firm i
is given by
[[product].sub.i] = [P.sub.i] [Y.sub.i] - [n.summation over (j=1)]
[P.sub.j][X.sub.ij] (2)
where [P.sub.i] is the price of industry i output.
A market clearing condition for each industry completes the
specification of the model. Thus
[Y.sub.i[ = [F.sub.i] + [n.summation over (j=1)] [X.sub.ji] (3)
where [F.sub.i] is the amount used for final uses. This implies
that available output of industry i is used either for final uses such
as consumption, investment and government purchases or as inputs in
other industries (including industry i). To highlight the importance of
demand and supply of intermediate inputs in determining output and
prices, however, we assume that [F.sub.i]'s are fixed. The model is
now solved for competitive equilibrium.
First-Order Conditions for Firm's Profit Maximization
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
for all i, j = 1,2,....n
This condition states that the marginal revenue product of input j
in industry i is equal to its price. Manipulation of the equilibrium
condition (4) yields
(5) [X.sub.ij] = [a.sub.ij] [P.sub.i]/[P.sub.j] [Y.sub.i]
It is not difficult to see from this equation that as [Y.sub.i]
increases as a result of the exogenous productivity gain, ceteris
paribus, [P.sub.i] decreases. On the other hand, as [P.sub.i] decreases,
demand for ith input in industry k rises, i.e. [X.sub.ki] increases,
which in turn leads to an increase in [Y.sub.k] as we can see from the
production function. This will set out another chain of changes in
prices and output. Thus it is the constant interactions between demand
and supply that lead to cross-industry effects on prices and output.
A Competitive Equilibrium
A competitive equilibrium for this simple economy is defined as the
quantity vectors X and Y and price vector P such that for a given vector
Z of productivity shift,
(i) the firms' profit maximization problems are solved.
(ii) all markets clear.
Let [[bar.X].sub.ij] [[bar.Y].sub.i] [[bar.P].sub.i] be the
competitive equilibrium solutions of [X.sub.ij], [Y.sub.i] and
[P.sub.i]'s in terms of [Z.sub.i] = [[bar.Z].sub.i]'s. Since
we are interested in the effects of displacements in total factor
productivity from [[bar.Z].sub.i]'s on the choices variables
[X.sub.ij], [Y.sub.i] and [P.sub.i]'s, we state the following
theorem.
Theorem 1: In a production economy, if industries are inter-linked
through input-output structure, then the percentage deviations in
[X.sub.ij], [Y.sub.i] and [P.sub.i]'s from these equilibrium values
respectively, are given by linear functions of [z.sub.i]'s where
[z.sub.i]'s are the percentage deviations of [Z.sub.i]'s from
[[bar.Z].sub.i]'s.
Proof: (see Appendix)
Calibration
In order to make some quantitative statements about the effects of
B2B productivity gains across different industries we now calibrate the
model for thirty-five industry groups (12) of the U.S. economy. We
follow the industry classification scheme of Jorgenson, Gollop and
Fraumeni (1987). These thirty-five industries roughly match the 2-digit
Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) of U.S. industries. The
parameters that we need to calibrate are [a.sub.ij]'s and
[s.sub.ij]'s. Fortunately, the Input-Output (I-O) Tables provide
information on how the industries at various levels of aggregation
interact among themselves, which can be used to obtain the values of
these parameters. In 1996 annual I-O tables, 95 industries are covered
at the two-digit level. (13) We consolidate the 1996 I-O direct
requirement table to thirty-five sectors that we are considering here.
Note that [a.sub.ij] = [X.sub.ij]/[Y.sub.i], where [X.sub.ij] is the
amount of industry j output used as input in industry i and [Y.sub.i] is
the total output of industry i. On the other hand, we use 1996 I-O use
table to calibrate the parameter values [s.sub.ij]'s. [s.sub.ij] =
[X.sub.ij]/[Y.sub.j], where [X.sub.ij] is the amount of industry j
output used as input in industry i and [Y.sub.j] is the total output of
industry j.
CROSS-INDUSTRY EFFECTS OF INDIVIDUAL B2B GAIN
In this section, we examine how a B2B productivity gain gets
propagated to other industries. First we look into the effects on real
output in different industries of a one percent increase in productivity
in a particular industry. We then use the potential savings and Internet
penetration ratios estimated by Goldman Sachs for different industries
to estimate the potential output gain in the economy, as implied by our
model.
What Does a 1 Percent Productivity Gain in an Industry Imply for
Real Output across Industries?
Figure 2 illustrates how a one percent productivity gain (14) in
each of the thirty-five industries affects real output across
industries. As we can see from this figure, for each industry the
effects on other industries are both positive and negative. It is
difficult to discern a general pattern. As we have discussed, positive
supply shock and negative demand shocks are simultaneously at work to
determine cross-industry effects of B2B gain. However, the net effect
depends on the relative strength of the demand and supply factors.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
From the figure, we can make a few general observations. First,
when predominantly intermediate inputs or investment goods producing
industries (15) experience B2B gain, the magnitudes of changes in real
output across industries are relatively large. For example, B2B gain to
intermediate goods producing industries such as 'agriculture',
'crude petroleum and natural gas', 'chemicals',
'petroleum refining', 'primary metal',
'electrical machinery', 'transportation' and
'communications' and investment goods producing industries
such as 'construction' and 'machinery' have large
impact across industries. Second, three service industries, namely,
'wholesale and retail trade', 'finance, insurance and
real estate' and 'services' have the largest impact
across industries. As we can see from Table 1, more than half of their
output is used for consumption purposes.
Third, direct effects are not always positive. For example, the
'construction' industry and 'transportation'
experienced negative direct effects. This implies that in these
industries, the demand factors are more powerful so much so that the
negative effects outweigh the positive impact of the productivity gain.
This model can be used to quantitatively evaluate the impact of B2B
gain. We shall illustrate this with an example. Note that the matrix
[??] in the appendix describes how B2B gain to an industry affects other
industries through input-output linkages. Each column represents the
percentage changes in output of different industries as a result of 1
percent productivity gain that a particular industry experiences as a
result of B2B e-commerce. For example, the first column represents the
percentage changes in output of 35 industries when the
'Agriculture' industry experiences a 1 percent productivity
gain due to B2B e-commerce. In order to calculate overall effects in
terms of change in total output as a result of 1 percent increase in
productivity in each of the 35 industries we follow the following steps:
1) First we calculate changes in output of individual industries by
applying the percentage changes along the corresponding column of the
[??] to respective gross output.
For example, when the agriculture industry experience 1 percent
productivity growth, we apply the percentage changes along the first
column to the gross output of 35 industries in 1996.
2) We then add up the changes in individual industries to obtain
the overall effect of B2B gain in the agriculture industry. However,
this total effect can be divided into 'direct effect' and
'indirect effect'. Note that the diagonal elements of [??]
represent direct effects of B2B gain. Once we calculate total effects
and direct effects, we can obtain indirect effects by subtracting the
direct effects from the total effects.
We use 1996 GPO data obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analysis
to illustrate how we use the model to calculate the effects. The results
are reported in Table 2. As we can see, B2B e-commerce in
'Services', 'Finance, insurance and real estate' and
'Wholesale and retail trade' industry has the largest effects
in terms of overall changes in output. These industries also have
relatively large direct effects. B2B gain in the
'Construction' industry, on the other hand, has a large
negative direct effect.
How Much Does the Economy Gain if the Cost Savings are as High as
Estimated?
In the study 'E-Commerce/Internet' conducted by Goldman
Sachs, the percentage savings made possible by adopting B2B throughout
specific industries have been estimated (see Table 2 in Goldman
Sachs(1999)). At the end of the report they also provide the Internet
penetration ratios for different industries. These are the estimated
percentage shares of total sales that are or would be Internet based
between 1998 and 2004. These two sets of industries they have studied do
not match exactly. However there are a few overlapping industries. We
take these overlapping or roughly matching industries from these two
tables and match with the industrial categories we are considering in
this paper. We select seven of our thirty-five industries, which roughly
match their industries. Table 3 presents the estimated cost savings and
Internet penetration ratios for the years 2000, 2002 and 2004 for these
industries. We multiply the cost saving figures with the Internet
penetration ratios to arrive at total cost saving for each of these
industries. Then we calculate the total gain in terms of increase in
real GPO for the economy as implied by our model. We take one industry
at a time and see the direct, indirect and total effects of introducing
B2B e-commerce. The results are presented in Table 4.
We observe that B2B gain in the transportation industry would have
the largest impact in the economy. Interestingly enough, it has negative
impact on its own real output. However, the indirect effects are
substantial. 'Transportation' is followed by
'chemicals' and 'crude petroleum and natural gas'
respectively. The gain from B2B in the 'transportation'
industry would grow by more than five times, those from the
'chemicals' industry and the 'crude petroleum'
industry by more than four times and more than three times respectively.
In case of all industries that we have considered here, the indirect
effects are several times higher than direct effects. It may be noted
that the increase in the total gain from introducing B2B in the
'paper' industry would grow dramatically over the years. As
for the overall impact, we see in last two rows that the total increase
in output due to B2B in these seven industries accounts for only 0.21
percent of the US real GDP in 2000 whereas these seven industries
together account for 10 percent. In 2004, this increase would account
for 1 percent of real GDP whereas the projected share of these
industries is only about 9 percent. However, one should keep in mind
that these estimated numbers are not actual projection of the output
gain in the economy. Nevertheless, given the data limitations this is
the best we can do. Moreover, they give a very good idea of potential
gain from B2B.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
In this paper, we examine cross-industry effects of the
productivity gain that emanates from B2B e-commerce in various sectors.
Within the simple framework of a multi-industry equilibrium model we
introduce B2B e-commerce as an exogenously given productivity gain. Then
we let the sectors interact among themselves to see how this exogenous
productivity gain leads to change their input decisions, which
eventually change price and output in each sector, by changing supply
and demand. We observe that a B2B productivity rise in industries that
mainly supply intermediate inputs or investment goods leads to fall in
prices in a wider range of industries. In case of consumption goods
industries, on the other hand, the effects are industry specific.
Given the simplistic nature of our model, the scope of our analysis
is very narrow. However, in future research we would like to consider a
more general setup and also to introduce dynamics. This will allow us to
examine broader issues like effects of the Internet on long-run growth
and inflation.
APPENDIX: PROOF OF THEOREM 1
Firm i maximizes short-run profit given by
[product].sub.i] = [P.sub.i][Y.sub.i] - [n.summation over
(j=1)][P.sub.j][X.sub.ij] (A.1)
subject to the constraint imposed by the technology
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A.2)
The resource constraint for each sector i is given by
[Y.sub.i] = [F.sub.i] + [n.summation over (j=1)] [X.sub.ji] (A.3)
Substituting (A.2) into (A.1) and taking first-order derivative of
i with respect to [X.sub.ij], we obtain the following first-order
condition
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A.4)
for all i, j = 1,2,....n
After algebraic manipulation and substitution of (A.2), we can
rewrite (A.4) as
a.sub.ij][P.sub.i][Y.sub.i] = [P.sub.j][X.sub.ij] (A.5)
Note that (A.2), (A.3) and (A.5) provide a system of n2 + 2n
non-linear equations in [n.sup.2] + 2n unknowns. This system can be
solved for X, Y and Ps as functions of Zs. Let [[bar.X].sub.ij],
[[bar.Y].sub.i] & [[bar.P].sub.i] be the solutions of X, Y and P in
terms of [Z.sub.i] = [[bar.Z].sub.i].
However, in this model we are interested in the effects of
displacements in total factor productivity from [[bar.Z].sub.i]'s
on the choices of variables X, Y and Ps. Let us define [X.subij] =
[X.sub.ij]-[[bar.X].sub.ij]/[[bar.X].sub.ij], [Y.sub.i] = [Y.sub.i]-
[[bar.Y].sub.i]/[[bar.Y].sub.i], [P.sub.i] =
[P.sub.i]-[[bar.P].sub.i]/[[bar.P].sub.i] & [Z.sub.i] = [Z.sub.i]-
[[bar.Z].sub.i]/[[bar.Z].sub.i] where lower case letters denote percentage deviations from the equilibrium solutions.
Now in order to obtain linear solutions of these transformed
variables in terms of z's we first take logarithmic transformation
of (A.5)
log([a.sub.ij] + log([P.sub.i]) + log([Y.sub.i]) = log([P.sub.j]) +
log([X.sub.ij]) (A.6)
Using first-order Taylor series expansion around on both sides we
obtain [[bar.X].sub.ij], [[bar.Y].sub.i] & [[bar.P].sub.i] on both
sides we obtain
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Using (A.6) and notations we have already introduced we can rewrite
this as
[p.sub.i] + [y.sub.i] = [p.sub.j] + [x.sub.ij] (A.7)
Similarly, logarithmic transformation of the production function
(A.2) first- order Taylor series expansion yield,
[y.sub.i] = [z.sub.i] + [n.summation over
(j=1)][a.sub.ij][x.sub.ij] (A.8)
Taking logarithm of the resource constraint, we obtain
log([Y.sub.i]) = log([F.sub.i] + [n.summation over (j=1)]
[X.sub.ji]) (A.9)
Using first-order Taylor series expansion around [sub.i]Y and
[[bar.X].sub.ji] we now obtain
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
After algebraic manipulation, we can rewrite the above equation as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
or,
[y.sub.i] = [n.summation over (j=1)][s.sub.ji][x.sub.ji] (A.10)
where [s.sub.ji] = [[bar.X].sub.ji]/[[bar.Y].sub.i]. Now
substituting for y from (A.8) into (A.7) and (A.10), we obtain
[p.sub.i] = [z.sub.i] + [n.summation over (j=1)]
[a.sub.ij][x.sub.ij] = [p.sub.j] + [x.sub.ij] (A.11)
and
[z.sub.i] + [n.summation over (j=1)] [a.sub.ij][x.sub.ij] =
[n.summation over (j=1)][s.sub.ji][x.sub.ji] (A.12)
In matrix form we can write equations (A.11) and (A.12) as follows
[M.sub.v] = [E.sub.z] (A.13)
where M is a ([n.sup.2]+n)x ([n.sup.2]+n) matrix containing
parameters a's, s's, 1's and 0's; v is a
([n.sup.2]+n)x1 vector of x's and p's; E is a ([n.sup.2]+n)xn
matrix of 1's and 0's and z is an nx1 vector of exogenous
productivity displacements. Rewriting (A.13), v = [M.sup.-1] [E.sub.z]
or,
v = [[product].sub.z] (A.14)
We can partition the vectors and matrix to derive the explicit
solutions as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (A.15)
where x is an ([n.sup.2] x 1) vector of intermediate inputs (in
percentage deviation form) and p is an (n x 1) vector of prices. [??] is
an ([n.sup.2] x n) matrix that describes how B2B gain affects
intermediate inputs and [[product].sub.p] is an (n x n) matrix that
describes how B2B gain affects prices.
Thus, p = [[product].sub.p]z (A.16)
and from (A.8) we obtain
y = (I+A[[product].sub.x] z = [[product].sub.y]z (A.17)
where [[product].sub.y] = I + A[[product].sub.x] is an (n x n)
matrix. Note that A is an (n x n2) matrix of [a.sub.ij]s and 0s.
ENDNOTES
(1.) As various surveys indicate, online brokerage in the United
States has slowed down since the recession while in Asia and Europe it
has increased substantially. See various articles at www.nua.ie/surveys/
(2.) 'Prices of goods bought online, such as books and CD s,
are, on average, about 10% cheaper (after including taxes and delivery)
than in conventional shops.' The Economist, April 1, 2000.
(3.) Gartner Group forecasts that global B2B turnover could reach
$4 trillion in America in 2003, compared with less than $400 billion of
online sales to consumers.
(4.) This model qualifies to be a general equilibrium model in a
very limited sense. It represents a production economy that does not
have consumers and other agents. Nevertheless, it captures what we
intend to analyze in this paper.
(5.) These studies are cited and reported at www.nua.ie/surveys/
(6.) It is easier and more obvious to argue in terms of cost saving
effect of B2B e-commerce rather than in terms of productivity gain.
However, in order to help explain the specification of our model, we
would stick to the productivity gain argument. But they are essentially
the same.
(7.) We will refer to it as 'B2B gain'. In the business
cycle literature it would have been referred to as a positive technology
shock. In our exposition B2B gain is essentially a positive technology
shock.
(8.) In fact, there is evidence of productivity gain from
e-commerce in the U.S. economy in recent times. For example, as Oliner
and Sichel (2000) have pointed out, if e-commerce enables goods and
services to be produced and delivered using fewer resources, it could be
one factor that has pushed up MFP (multi-factor productivity) growth in
recent years'.
(9.) The Cobb-Douglas production function is the most widely used
production function in economics. Its wider acceptance is rooted in the
fact that one of its inventors Paul Douglas inferred its properties from
empirical observations of the US manufacturing during 1899-1922. Even
now empirically, Cobb Douglas form well represents the production
technology. In addition to the empirical appeal it has nice properties
such as convexity, twice differentiability and homogeneity. For detailed
discussion see Heathfield and Wibe (1987) and Johansen (1972). In recent
times, most of the business cycle literature uses CD production
function. For example, see King, Plosser and Rebelo (1988).
(10.) Actually this is the output of a typical firm in industry i.
Since firms are identical we will use industry and firm interchangeably.
(11.) It could be any technological change that affects
productivity.
(12.) A list of these thirty-five industries along with the uses of
their output is provided in Table
(13.) I-O classification is slightly different from SIC
classification.
REFERENCES
Center for Research in Electronic Commerce (2000). Measuring the
Internet Economy. Austin, TX: University of Texas and Cisco Systems.
Goldman Sachs Investment Research (1999). E-commerce/ Internet.
Gordon, R. J. (2000). Does the "new economy" measure up
to the great inventions of the past? Forthcoming, Journal of Economic
Perspective.
Heathfield, D. F. & S. Wibe (1987). An introduction to cost and
production functions. Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities Press
International, Inc.
Internet, impact on business efficiency and economic growth: A
thinkers guide. (2000). The Economist, April 1.
Johansen, L. (1972). Production functions. Amsterdam: North-Holland
Publishing Company.
Jorgenson, D. G., F. Gollop & B. Fraumeni (1987). Productivity
and U.S. economic growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Jorgenson, D.G. & K. J. Stiroh (2000). Raising the speed limit:
U.S. economic growth in the information age. Manuscript.
Long, Jr., J. B. & C. Plosser (1983). Real business cycles.
Journal of Political Economy, 91, 39-69.
Oliner, S. D. & D. E. Sichel (2000). The resurgence of growth
in the late 1990s: Is information technology the story? Manuscript.
Productivity on stilts. (2000). The Economist, June 10.
Shapiro, C. & H. R. Varian (1999). Information rules: A
strategic guide to the network economy. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
U.S. Department of Commerce: Bureau of Economic Analysis (1994).
Benchmark input-output accounts for the U.S. economy, 1987. Survey of
Current Business 74.
Uday M. Apte, Southern Methodist University
Hiranya K. Nath, Sam Houston State University
Table 1: Fractions of gross output in different uses by industry in
1996
Intermediate Gross
Commodity/Industry inputs Consumption investment
1 Agriculture 0.835 0.116 0.000
2 Metal mining 0.705 0.000 0.074
3 Coal mining 0.885 0.002 0.000
4 Crude petroleum and 1.551 0.000 0.001
natural gas
5 Mineral mining 0.979 0.003 0.000
6 Construction 0.227 0.000 0.555
7 Food and kindred 0.384 0.589 0.000
products
8 Tobacco products 0.067 0.796 0.000
9 Textile 0.849 0.134 0.044
10 Apparel 0.334 1.107 0.000
11 Lumber and wood products 0.946 0.026 0.080
12 Furniture and 0.158 0.512 0.381
fixtures
13 Paper 0.876 0.113 0.000
14 Printing 0.601 0.304 0.000
15 Chemicals 0.673 0.264 0.005
16 Petroleum refining 0.569 0.346 0.000
and related products
17 Rubber 0.897 0.127 0.002
18 Footwear, leather, 0.481 2.152 0.000
and leather products
19 Stone 0.993 0.058 0.000
20 Primary metal 1.096 0.001 0.001
21 Fabricated metal 0.920 0.037 0.042
22 Machinery 0.457 0.038 0.510
23 Electrical machinery 0.722 0.165 0.175
24 Motor vehicle 0.321 0.300 0.360
25 Transportation equipment 0.109 0.421 0.244
26 Instruments 0.304 0.095 0.408
27 Miscellaneous 0.312 0.949 0.151
manufacturing
28 Transportation 0.583 0.238 0.020
29 Communications 0.475 0.433 0.021
30 Electric utility 0.489 0.413 0.000
31 Gas production and 0.628 0.320 0.000
distribution
32 Wholesale and retail 0.301 0.555 0.068
trade
33 Finance, insurance and 0.374 0.561 0.019
real estate (FIRE)
34 Services 0.391 0.570 0.037
35 Government enterprises 0.563 0.377 0.000
Net
Exports
Govt. Exports
Commodity/Industry purchase -Imports Total
1 Agriculture 0.009 0.022 1.0
2 Metal mining -0.023 0.251 1.0
3 Coal mining 0.004 0.098 1.0
4 Crude petroleum and -0.004 -0.551 1.0
natural gas
5 Mineral mining 0.005 -0.021 1.0
6 Construction 0.218 0.000 1.0
7 Food and kindred 0.024 -0.001 1.0
products
8 Tobacco products -0.001 0.131 1.0
9 Textile 0.007 -0.024 1.0
10 Apparel 0.030 -0.475 1.0
11 Lumber and wood products 0.002 -0.058 1.0
12 Furniture and 0.063 -0.119 1.0
fixtures
13 Paper 0.033 -0.018 1.0
14 Printing 0.083 0.009 1.0
15 Chemicals 0.049 0.001 1.0
16 Petroleum refining 0.099 -0.024 1.0
and related products
17 Rubber 0.023 -0.056 1.0
18 Footwear, leather, 0.031 -1.692 1.0
and leather products
19 Stone 0.012 -0.070 1.0
20 Primary metal 0.005 -0.112 1.0
21 Fabricated metal 0.019 -0.027 1.0
22 Machinery 0.048 -0.054 1.0
23 Electrical machinery 0.054 -0.118 1.0
24 Motor vehicle 0.104 -0.093 1.0
25 Transportation equipment 0.247 -0.030 1.0
26 Instruments 0.197 -0.005 1.0
27 Miscellaneous 0.058 -0.490 1.0
manufacturing
28 Transportation 0.051 0.107 1.0
29 Communications 0.055 0.015 1.0
30 Electric utility 0.102 -0.003 1.0
31 Gas production and 0.048 0.004 1.0
distribution
32 Wholesale and retail 0.015 0.059 1.0
trade
33 Finance, insurance and 0.018 0.028 1.0
real estate (FIRE)
34 Services -0.004 0.006 1.0
35 Government enterprises 0.057 0.003 1.0
Source: Compiled from the 1996 Input-Output Use Table, Bureau of
Economic Analysis
Table 2: Direct and Indirect Effects of B2B Gain: An Example
(Values in billions of 1996 dollar)
Direct Indirect Total
Industry experiencing B2B gain effect effect effect
1 Agriculture 3.48 5.57 9.05
2 Metal mining 0.05 0.62 0.68
3 Coal mining 0.14 0.98 1.12
4 Crude petroleum and natural gas 1.10 7.15 8.25
5 Mineral mining 0.10 0.35 0.45
6 Construction -10.09 24.79 14.71
7 Food and kindred products 1.19 7.36 8.55
8 Tobacco products 0.00 0.19 0.19
9 Textile 0.25 0.69 0.94
10 Apparel 0.01 1.15 1.16
11 Lumber and wood products 0.37 2.66 3.03
12 Furniture and fixtures 0.04 0.50 0.54
13 Paper 0.65 3.93 4.58
14 Printing 0.90 2.17 3.07
15 Chemicals 1.63 6.60 8.22
16 Petroleum refining and related products 0.28 4.64 4.91
17 Rubber 0.14 4.95 5.08
18 Footwear, leather, and leather products 0.03 0.14 0.17
19 Stone 0.37 3.01 3.38
20 Primary metal 0.75 5.65 6.41
21 Fabricated metal 1.45 3.34 4.79
22 Machinery 0.35 6.78 7.13
23 Electrical machinery 1.85 8.27 10.11
24 Motor vehicle 0.59 4.00 4.58
25 Transportation equipment 0.08 0.40 0.48
26 Instruments 0.29 2.04 2.34
27 Miscellaneous manufacturing 0.11 0.95 1.06
28 Transportation -1.09 19.30 18.21
29 Communications 0.06 8.39 8.45
30 Electric utility 1.76 5.78 7.54
31 Gas production and distribution 5.34 2.83 8.16
32 Wholesale and retail trade 7.30 24.61 31.92
33 Finance, insurance and real estate 25.01 29.10 54.11
(FIRE)
34 Services 40.14 42.06 82.20
35 Government enterprises 8.50 0.44 8.94
Source: Authors' calculations
Note: The assumption is that there is 100 percent penetration of B2B.
Table 3: Estimated savings and penetration of B2B in selected
industries for 2000, 2002 and 2004
Estimated penetration
of B2B (% share of
Estimated projected sale based
Industry * with B2B savings (@) on Internet)
2000 2002 2004
Coal mining 2.0% 4.5 10.0 16.0
Crude petroleum and natural gas 10.0% 4.5 10.0 16.0
Food and kindred products 4.50% 1.1 1.3 1.6
Paper 10.0% 1.2 6.7 12.2
Chemicals 10.0% 5.0 10.5 20.0
Transportation 15.0% 2.5 6.5 11.0
Communications 10.0% 1.5 5.5 11.0
Notes: * The specific industries studied by Goldman Sachs have roughly
been matched with our classification of industries
(@) Wherever estimated savings are given by a range we have taken the
average.
Source: Compiled from Table 2 and Table 8 of Goldman Sachs(1999)
Table 4: Estimated direct and indirect effects of B2B in selected
industries for the years 2000,2002 and 2004: Changes in real gross
value added (millions of 1996 constant dollars)
2000
Direct Indirect Total
Industry effect effect effect
Coal mining 16 112.8 128.8
Crude petroleum and natural gas 328.8 3839.4 4168.2
Food and kindred products 41.5 420.6 462.1
Paper 95.8 559.7 655.5
Chemicals 935.5 3635.7 4571.2
Transportation -467.1 8914.2 8447.1
Communication 7.7 1106.1 1113.8
Total 958.2 18588.5 19547
Total effect as % of real GDP 0.01 0.20 0.21
Share of these 7 industries in real GDP 10.00
2002
Direct Indirect Total
Industry effect effect effect
Coal mining 39.2 285.6 324.8
Crude petroleum and natural gas 577.3 8988.9 9566.2
Food and kindred products 42.3 579.4 621.7
Paper 574.8 3467 4041.8
Chemicals 2039 7989.9 10028.9
Transportation -1256.6 26153 24896.4
Communication 28.9 4389.9 4418.8
Total 2044.9 51853.7 53898.6
Total effect as % of real GDP 0.02 0.53 0.55
Share of these 7 industries in real GDP 9.42
2004
Direct Indirect Total
Industry effect effect effect
Coal mining 68.8 532.1 600.9
Crude petroleum and natural gas 721.8 14862.7 15584.5
Food and kindred products 44.5 860.5 905
Paper 1112.8 7258.7 8371.5
Chemicals 3987.3 16232 20219.3
Transportation -2176.7 51451.5 49274.8
Communication 58.8 9694.3 9753.1
Total 3817.3 100892 104709
Total effect as % of real GDP 0.04 0.96 1.00
Share of these 7 industries in real GDP 8.81
Notes: Gross value-added at 1992 constant dollars by industries are
available from BEA until 1997. In order to be consistent with the 1996
I-O tables we converted them into 1996 constant dollars. Then we
forecast GPO for the years 1998-2004 using growth rates for 1996. Note
that we could have used the average growth rates for the decade of the
1990s. Since the beginning of the 1990s is characterized by recession
that would not yield good forecasts.
Source: Authors' calculations