Theorizing Japanese FDI to China.
Rahman, Khondaker Mizanur
Using mainly archival data, this paper examines the nature and
causes of Japanese foreign direct investment (FDI) to China and
theorizes it with inductive arguments. It proceeds as follows. After a
brief introduction on China's robustness in the global investment
market, it introduces the position of Japan as investor in this country,
and proceeds with an examination of the major theories of FDI. It then
examines the underlying causes of Japanese FDI to China in view of those
theories. The paper concludes that, in addition to many
investment-alluring incentives, most prominently China over time has
infused, fostered, created, and nurtured numerous competitive advantages
(pull-factors) within its investment proliferating environment, which
ultimately ushered FD! from Japan to it. Domestic factors as well as
global investment competitors drive (push-factors) toward China further
induced Japanese multinational corporations (MNCs to boost investment
into China.
Introduction
From its centrally planned economic system (1949-1978), transition
to market economic mechanisms in China started since 1978 with the
introduction of major economic policy-reforms and open-market strategies
under the leadership of Deng Xiaoping. Establishment of the special
economic zones (SEZs) in the coastal region of Guangdong province was
the milestone in its economic relations policy, which heralded the
advent of a new era of embracing foreign capital, technology, and
business management. In the initial stage of reform and transition (1979
to 1985), it received foreign funds mostly in development projects, and
investments in business ventures were mostly with the state owned
enterprises (SOEs) and to some extent in Greenfield sectors. Outside
Chinese populated regions/territories, the sources of such investments
and development funds were the World Bank, the International Monetary
Fund (IMF), governments of Japan, the United States of America (USA),
the United Kingdom (UK), Italy, Germany, Singapore, and Australia, and
private business companies mostly from these countries. This amounted to
$1.2 billion, $0.9 billion, $1.4 billion, and $2.0 billion respectively,
in 1979-82, 1983, 1984, and 1985. The actual take-off of foreign direct
investment (FDI) took place since 1985, when all the SEZs developed in
the coastal region went into full operation and exhibited lofty business
success without impediment, and with rather dynamic tutelage of the
central government and regional governments. As of 2005, China holds the
second position in the list of the FDI countries and receives a big
share in Japan's FDI. Using archival data, this paper examines the
nature and causes of Japanese FDI to China and theorizes it with
inductive arguments.
China's Performance in Attracting FDI
FDI from All Sources: The amount of FDI in China from all sources
reached from US$1.9 billion in 1986 to US$3.5 billion in 1990,
registering an increase of about 86 percent in five years. Other than
Hong Kong and Macao, Japan and the USA were the biggest investor
countries. Taiwan Province emerged into the spotlight since 1986 and
soon assumed the position the fourth biggest investor, although its
political relation with the mainland was not all through lukewarm. The
Chinese investors from other Southeast Asian countries assumed leading
positions. From Asia, Singapore and South Korea and from Europe, UK,
Germany, France, and Italy continued to invest at a constant pace, but
investment from these four European countries remained within the range
of 5 to 8 percent of the total inflow. Virgin Islands came to the
limelight since 1993, progressively increased investment throughout the
second-half of the 1990s, and led even the USA and Japan in the 21C with
a share of 11 to 12 percent (Nakajima, 2005, pp. 180-1). Lax tax regimes
of this region might have enticed the US/UK investments to make a detour
to China through Virgin Islands.
Transfer of Hong Kong in 1997 and of Macao in 1999, and liberal
politics in Taiwan together with an absence of its virtual embargo on
investment to China added further to the plight of Taiwanese capital to
the mainland. Japanese FDI remained more or less flattened from 1988 to
1992 and increased almost constantly from 1993 until 2004. The
fluctuations in 1999 and 2000 cannot be traced to any specific changes
in its domestic and global investment environments.
World Investment Reports (WIRs) compiled by the UN/UNCTAD show that
year-to year cross-border investments in the world have increased with
negligible fluctuation in the second-half of the 1980s; unabatedly
throughout the 1990s to a record high level of 1.492 trillion in 2000,
but fell within the range of $735 to $632 billion in the first four
years of the millennium decade. China's average share ranged at 2.8
billion (1.9 percent) in the second half of the 1980s, 22.9 billion (9.9
percent) and 41.9 billion (6.8 percent) respectively in the first and
second halves of the 1990s, and 53.4 billion (7.9 percent) in the first
four years of the 21C. This amounted from 20 to 50 percent of gross FDI
flows to all developing countries (except China), and it demonstrates
robustness of the Chinese market as investment destination. The USA
throughout the 1990s, the UK in 1998, 1999, and 2000 received more FDI
than China (UNCTAD, 2002, p. 283). In this decade of 21 C, as investment
host, China turned out as the champion over all developing countries/
economies, ASEAN countries, but was bitten by only the USA, Luxembourg
(2003 and 2004), UK (2001, 2002, and 2004) (UNCTAD, 2005, p. 303), and
France and the Netherlands in 2001 (UNCTAD, 2002, p. 303). FDI to Hong
Kong and Macao, which are shown separately in the WIRs, if included as
FDI host China will rank next to only the USA. Although its target of
$200 billion FDI by 2005 could not be unachieved, China has turned out
as the single largest FDI recipient among all developing countries with
an amount of $60.6 billion in 2004 (UNCTAD, 2005, p. 303).
FDI from Japan: China's share in Japan's FDI in the 1980s
was always less than 1 percent of its total FDI, except in 1987 when it
recorded at 3.7 percent. The aggregate amount of FDI (world) increased
almost constantly during the 1990s, but decreased in the 2000s.
Investment to China increased to $4.5 billion in 1995, which accounted
to 8.8 percent of its total FDI of that year, but throughout the second
half of the 1990s it declined, and reached even to US $751 million or
1.1 percent in 1999. It rebounded again since 2001 and reached US $4.6
billion or 12.8 percent of aggregate FDI in 2004. While in the 1980s
Japan's year-to-year FDI amounted to $67.5 billion in 1989 as
against the record of $8.9 billion in 1981, where Asia, including China
also, held the biggest share of $3.3 billion or 37.4 percent (1981),
which stood at $8.2 billion in 1989 (JETRO, various years).
In this decade, Japan's total FDI, FDI to Asia as a whole, and
FDI to China increased. It must be the impact of Plaza Accord, needing
Japan to spread investment bases to ASEAN, Asian NIEs, and China.
Up-and-down in the 1990s show no specific pattern, but it registered at
$66.7 billion in 1999, where Asia's share in percentage and
aggregate constantly increased, and reached at the peak of this decade
in 1999, then declined from 2000. Explosion of economic bubble, malaise
in the banking sector, and above all corporate restructuring led to this
tide and wave. China increased its share constantly until 1995, but it
fell constantly from 1996 to 2000. Contrary to the above pattern in the
1990s, China increasingly bagged more Japanese FDI during 2001-2005.
Japan's cumulative FDI (from 1951-2004) stood at $915.5 billion,
where Asia as a whole hosted 17.5 percent, and China 3.4 percent or
$31.5 billion. As one country, the USA is the biggest host of
Japan's FDI over the UK, the Netherlands, Caiman Island, and
Panama, and China holds the sixth position if countries in the regional
blocs (NIEs, ASEAN, EU15, and Oceania) are taken into account separately
(JETRO, Ibid.).
Theories of FDI: A Brief Overview
FDI theories are indeed extensions of international trade theories,
which were formulated to theorize the nature and causes of international
trade and to logically approach the issues and circumstances that
condition the same. All existing theories enormously incorporate
elements from a wide array of research and practical disciplines of pure
economics, development economics, international economics, business
history and management, econometrics, statistics, mathematics, public
administration, international business and management, industrial
organization, industrial development theory, and international
development. Here some important theories will be introduced in a
nutshell.
Adam Smith has introduced the "doctrine of absolute
advantage" and David Richardo, the "doctrine of comparative
advantage" in connection with production and distribution of goods.
The former theory is built on the "scale of economies", and
the latter on the "specialization" or efficiency in allocating
"limited factors of production" (factor endowments), which
lead to exchange of commodities amongst countries or regions.
The theory of Heckscher-Ohlin, also called "factor proportions
theory", on the other hand, is founded on the assumption of
"uneven distribution of factors of production" among
countries, but unlike Ricardo, it argues that manifold factors might
exist in a country, and comparative advantage is influenced by the
interaction among those factors or resources (Krugman and Obstefld,
2002, pp. 66-86). Trade between countries, in other words, international
trade takes place due to intensity in the use of those factors in which
they abound. All these theories are known as "conventional trade
theories", and these assume a state of perfect competition in the
market.
Theories of FDI, in fact, received vital forces from the seminal
works of Hymer (1976), which challenged the weaknesses in the
assumptions inherent in the above trade theories, and established the
fact that firm-specific advantages (strengths) generate
"intangible" corporate wealth, and create leeway of
competition. FDI, in his opinion, takes place within a state of
imperfect market environment, and the "firm" or multinational
corporations (MNCs) other than the country is the "real actor"
(Ozawa, 1992) in transferring assets outside the national boundary.
Krugmen (1983 and 1990) has intertwined "firm-specific
variables" and "country-specific variables" (factor
endowments), which generate transaction cost incentives through
integration of up-stream and down-stream activities (inside a firm and
within the country), and movement of MNCs across national boundaries
arise from unequal factor endowments to reap the benefit of unequal
factor prices. This theory of Krugman is thus a refinement of his other
propositions and theories, namely the theory of intra-industry and the
theory of technological competition, and incorporates elements from all
of them.
Dunning's (1979 and 1988) "eclectic theory of
international production" has further enlarged the framework of FDI
by MNCs by incorporating the comparative factors in both home-and
host-countries in that three sets of advantages, namely ownership (O)
specific advantages, location (L) specific advantages in the home or
host countries, and advantages for internalization (I) from ownership,
determine the level, form, and extent of international investment and
distribution, and is called OLI in short. Dunning has classified FDIs
into four categories--market seeking, resource seeking, asset seeking,
and efficiency seeking--according to their objectives.
Vernon's "product-life cycle theory" or P-L-C
(Vernon 1966, pp. 191-207) explains both international trade and
investment in sequential stages or hierarchies that goes along with the
life cycle of a product. The product-life, as he postulates, consists of
three stages--new product, maturing product, and standardized product.
At the early stage, since inputs and processing specifications remain
unstandardized, the product is manufactured in the country of its origin
considering national and other locational factors, and is introduced to
foreign markets through exports. With the expansion of demand in the
market, standardization drives the product to the maturity stage (the
second stage), and price competition among manufacturers flares up.
Manufacturing facilities are established, in other words, investments
are done in other high-income countries like the USA. In the third or
more advanced stages of standardization, production units shift to
less-developed countries to take competitive advantage of low cost and
other locational factors, and goods manufactured there are exported back
to the home country or to other markets.
On the assumption of market imperfection, Peter Buckley and Mark
Casson have pioneered the development of the "internalization
theory" of FDI, which Rugman (1985) completed, and it explains the
process of expansion of multi-plant firms, both domestically and
internationally. For expanding domestically, a firm needs to explore
advantages (vertical integration, quality control, patents, R&D,
human force, and so forth) inherent in them (internal factors). But in
case of international expansion, exploration of such advantages takes
place across the national boundaries. As Rugman (1985) states, this
theory possesses intimate relationship with Dunning's
"eclectic theory", which combines ownership, internalization,
and location-specific advantages into a comprehensive model. The
internalization theory combines the first two elements into one set of
firm-specific advantage, since ownership advantages are internalized to
make them more effective. The country or location-specific advantages
(transaction cost and environmental factor) as such remain the second
important determinant of FDI decision. Both theories are thus reconciled
in essence and with assumptions (Rugman, 1985).
By critically observing and analyzing the most successful ten
nations that have achieved and sustained economic development in recent
years, Porter (1990, p. 545) has extended the "stages theory of
competitive development". The countries have achieved development
in four distinct stages: factor driven, investment driven, innovation
driven, and wealth driven. The first three of which involve successive
upgrading of their competitive advantages, but the fourth stage is one
of drift and ultimately decline. From this theory, it can be derived
that at the microlevel, a business firm capitalizes on the competitive
advantages at macro-levels, i.e. the nation, and uses those for
international expansion and competition. The government plays a crucial
role in creating competitive advantages of its nation (Porter, Ibid.,
pp. 126-128). Porter has stylized the determinants of national
advantage, namely factor conditions, demand conditions, related and
supporting industries, firm strategy, structure, and rivalry are
stylized into a diamond shape, and it is popularly called Porter
Diamond. Individually and collectively, these determinants create the
context in which a nation's MNCs come into being, compete in the
home market, and accumulate strengths to penetrate the foreign markets
(Porter, Ibid., pp. 71-130).
Aharoni (1966) observed that an individual firm's geographical
horizon (a locality, a sub-national region, or a home country) changes
in the course of its growth due to changes in its internal and external
environmental forces, and stimulates it to "go international".
Aharoni's proposition resembles Weber's industrial
localization theory, which is one of the earliest researches that
examined the concentration of factories in industrial enclaves to reduce
the burden of population migration to large urban cities. Weber
emphasized the need to minimize the total cost of transporting raw
materials to the factory and of final manufactures to the market by
locating industries in the close proximity of markets. Originally if the
cost of production, including transportation cost of final products, is
higher than the cost of final product, including the transportation cost
of raw materials, the factory should be established in the proximity of
its market, and vice versa. Cost of production, in addition to raw
material cost, includes labor cost, can be minimized by locating
industries to low labor-cost regions in other countries (Suzuki, 2001,
pp. 134-145). These geo-business models give a comprehensive framework
of explaining and pinpointing all international business actions of any
firm, and not only of MNCs. Three set of variables, namely conditioning
variables, motivation variables, and control variables greatly influence
the locational aspect of a firm, and interactions among these variables
entice or discourage firms to take businesses across national
boundaries. National policies of economic development, through
import-substitution or export-oriented industrialization, historically
created a wide array of physical and fiscal facilities (factors) through
the establishment of developmental enclaves with diversified incentive
offer to MNCs, non-MNCs, and domestic enterprise.
Political approaches of FDI include political and power aspects
underlying FDI, and most importantly, they emphasize how changes of
world political blocs pose impact on FDI flows. Gilpin (1975, p.19)
argues that international political orders created by dominant nations
(core country) for security interests provide a favorable environment of
economic interdependence and corporate expansion in other countries
(periphery). Known as "core-periphery model", it is a dominant
power that assumes the "core" position and sends goods and
investments to countries dependent on it or adjacent to its power of
business and economic activities, "the periphery". Pax
Britannica and Pax Americana are two most important structures, the
former explains UK's position in the pre-war period, and the
latter, the US position in the post-WW II period (Gilpin, Ibid.).
Marxist, and even many non-Marxists, economist view the
relationship between partners in P-L-C as "hierarchical and
exploitative". In other words, they view that growth and
development outcomes instead of flowing to the lesser developed
periphery move in reverse direction, that is, from the "global,
underdeveloped periphery to the centers of industrial financial power
and decision" (Gilpin, Ibid.), which as such makes the periphery
more dependent on the core.
In order to describe the movement of goods and investments among
markets during the situation of unbalanced growth, Akamatsu (1961) has
extended the "geese-flying pattern (G-F-P)". According to the
G-F-P, products, firms, technologies, investments, and ultimately
countries move among locations in search for market opportunities,
forming a pattern of wild-geese that migrate to comfortable locations in
different seasons of the year. Products, firms, and so forth are
analogous to the geese seeking safe nests. This model is vividly
referred to while explaining economic growth in Japan and Asian fast
growth economies.
On the theoretical and practical premises of this G-F-P, Kojima
(1975) has extended "macro-economic theory" of FDI with two
propositions--one based on the classical Richardian doctrine of
comparative advantages, and the other on his own classification of
"mutually beneficial type of FDI". The core concept of this
model is that countries in trade gain more from a situation of
immobility of factors through FDI, provided that such FDI goes from the
"disadvantaged sectors" of the home country to the"
advantaged sectors" of the host country (Kojima and Ozawa, 1984,
pp. 1-20).
Fayerweather (1969) argues that a firm can transfer its management
resources, superior skills of product, process, information, technology,
and management, in package with FDI, and using that can create
competitive advantages for it in other countries, and is called
"management technology transfer theory" of FDI (Yamamura,
2001, pp. 39-40).
Theses, anti-theses, and syntheses prevail in plenty, some come and
some go with or without notice, and it can be concluded in line with
Koontz (1961) that FDI theories can perfectly be interwoven into
"FDI Theory Jungle" comprising of innumerable full-or sub-
approaches or models. All have uniqueness and originality in some forms
or others, and apply validly to explain the nature and causes of FDI and
operations of MNCs.
Theoretical Outlook Of Japanese FDI To China
Increasing Japanese FDI to China is indeed a functional outcome of
two divergent sets of factors, push and pull, in that the former
composed of historical and neo-factors in Japan pushes MNCs to extend
networks to China, and the latter composed of country and market
specific advantages in China pulls MNCs investments into it. This
situation can be explained with references to existing researches and
from logical inductions from facts to frame a hybrid theory of Japanese
FDI in China.
Country-Specific Competitive Advantages Available, Created, and
Promoted in China
Japanese FDI surged to China, as was seen, at first in the
aftermath of yen appreciation in the second half of the 1980s, and
secondly since 1993. High growth of the Chinese economy as the result of
economic reform and market liberalization and recognition of the same by
other nations induced Japanese MNCs to incorporate China into their
regional production and market networks to reap the benefit of its
national endowments in labour, consumer market, and its nurtured
competitive advantages toward catching-up with the developed countries.
Japanese FDI was not absolutely resource-or-asset seeking, rather
market-and-efficiency seeking to serve the Chinese domestic market in
the first instance and then home market, and to maximize overall
corporate efficiency and performance thereby.
Asian currency crisis and increase of labour costs in Singapore,
Malaysia, and Thailand induced most MNCs to relocate plants, and divert
new investments to China. Sikorski and Mennkhoff (2000) regarded this
trend as revolving of FDI within the region in response to its
transforming comparative advantages. Zhou and Lall (2005) found that
China does not crowd out FDI to other countries; rather its industrial
capabilities in skills, technology levels, supplier bases,
infrastructure, and its large market size allow MNCs to reap scale and
scope of economies more competitively than in other countries in the
region.
External orientation of development strategies that emerged from
its market reforms and growth of efficient human capital and social
concessions in the economically advanced provinces added new forces to
attracting FDI. The Government of China explicitly directed its
liberalization and marketization policy to promote the development of
the southeastern coastal provinces, and to divert that toward the
northwestern provinces. As is evident in the Western Region Development
Program of the Government, this spatial dimension of development has put
emphasis on infrastructure development, such as the upgrading of human
capital through education, and inward migration of needful human force,
which was very similar in the development policy of the coastal
provinces.
International pressure, from the US in particular, to revise the
existing monetary and banking systems to strengthen the undervalued, and
thus highly competitive renminbi, and to reform the operation of the
commercial banks (Daily Yomiuri, 2005, p. 4) will strengthen
China's advantage. China's national industry localization
policy to pool industries in different regions based on different
natural endowments and development levels, is quite akin to the
historical strategy of polarizing growth activities in designated
centers in market economies.
From 1999, the Chinese government has removed restrictions,
liberalized regimes and administrative mechanisms, and above all
abolished restrictions to foreign entry (FDI) in some industries and
sectors. It also initiated new bilateral investment treaties (BITs) and
double taxation treaties (DTTs) with many countries and to specifically
earmarked industries. Other measures included enhancing guarantees on
the protection of intellectual property right and against expropriation,
changes in legislation, environment aspects, and accounting and audit.
As China's bid to access into the World Trade Organization (WTO)
was at the final phase, it removed most tariff and non-tariff barriers
and embargo on local contents in the final manufactures, technology
transfer, and local R&D (UNCTAD, 2002, pp. 54-5). Further
liberalization was introduced to the services sector, especially
financial services, distribution (wholesale, retail, franchising),
media, education, with more incentives and opportunities to establish
R&D centers, regional HQs, and reform SOEs. It signed agreement with
ASEAN to establish free-trade area by 2010. As the consequences of
embracing market mechanisms and adding new and liberal elements in its
National Economic and Social Development Plan of 2005, China's
market imperfections in the yardstick of market economies in the West
took a new shift to more perfection.
Domestic Forces Inducing Japanese MNCs to Invest in China
Japan lost its colonies in China and other Asian countries in WW
II, entered into peace treaty with the USA, was looked after by the GHQ,
and virtually entered under the umbrella of Pax Americana. Although not
recognized in the political development history, it was indeed demise of
the Pax Japonica. However, Japan gained free access to the US product
and investment markets under a fixed exchange rate agreement of US$1 to
360 yen. From the 1970s onwards, Japan constantly maintained a positive
trade balances with the USA and most of the developed nations. Negative
trade balances of trade with the USA gave rise to severe trade
frictions, and the Plaza Agreement of 1985 resulted in the appreciation
of Yen against US dollar and other major currencies. Japan firms had to
look for new manufacturing bases in countries possessing relatively cozy
business and diplomatic relationship with the West, and especially the
USA. These coincided with the import substitution-cum-export oriented
trade policies adopted by the NIEs and ASEAN countries since the 1970s,
all of which are endowed with surplus labours and huge untapped primary
resources and offered infrastructure facilities by establishing
industrial enclaves, namely IEs, FTZs, LMWs, IPs, and with lucrative
financial and fiscal incentives. Japan entered into bilateral and
regional trade and investment agreements with these countries, which
further enhanced factors mobility from Japan, and its cultural
similarity with ethnic Chinese population segments in those countries
eased MNCs movement within this region, and ultimately has paved the way
to penetrate the Chinese market.
Regional Competitiveness of China
UNCTAD's 2005 Survey of FDI Prospects for 2005-2008 revealed
that international FDI experts and TNCs rank China (85 percent) as the
best global business location among such top ten countries, including
the USA (55 percent), India (42 percent), Brazil, Russian Federation,
the UK, Germany, Poland, and Ukraine. TNCs (87 percent) in this survey
ranked it as the best location over India, the USA, Russian Federation,
Brazil, Mexico, Germany, the UK, and Canada (UNCTAD, 2005, pp. 33-5).
China is found to adopt greater investment targets, strengthen
investment policies, offer additional incentive packages, introduce
further liberalization, and adopt promotional measures. Among its Asian
counterparts, albeit with much lower points, India, Singapore, and
Thailand were on the list. China's national advantages are more
promising than those available at other Southeast Asian countries, and
it is adding more forces to those by introducing pro-investment legal
and market measures. Liberalization of FDI in banking and financial
sectors has improved its competitive edge (UNCTAD, 2005).
Surveys on overseas business operations of Japanese manufacturing
companies by the defunct Japan Bank for International Cooperation (JBIC)
showed China as the most promising location for investment and business
operation for five consecutive years from 2001-2005. The Survey in 2005
found that 71.2 percent of the respondents favor China as the most
promising location for business promotion over Russia and other CIS,
Central and Eastern Europe, other Asian Countries/ Oceania, and North
America. With China at the top, other Asian favorites are India,
Thailand, and Vietnam. Although the stance toward China has declined
compared with the previous year, FDI in China is aimed to increase sales
in the domestic market and in ASEAN and to reduce sales in Japan.
Respondents view only limited impact of anti-Japanese demonstration on
their operations in China. Production bases in China manufacture
general-purpose products and will shift to high-value-added products
(JBIC, 2005).
Responding companies attached high priority to China and India as
more potential markets over the EU-member countries due to geographical
proximity, which facilitate easy access to both production bases and
final markets. In terms of industrial category, electrical equipment and
electronics or E&E (41.0 percent) and general machinery (23.3
percent) show relatively higher tendency to produce and sale in the same
bases. The automobile makers are more prone to produce near the market,
but E&E companies are keen to move production to low-cost overseas
sites to meet the need of short product cycle and pressure of cost
reduction (JBIC, Ibid, p. 8).
Within China, all MNCs irrespective of industrial categories intend
to strengthen and expand their operations in Eastern and Southern
regions, E&E manufacturers also in the same regions, but automobile
makers favor Southern regions (59.7 percent) over Eastern regions (44.1
percent), which might be due again to affluent regional markets, easy
access to affluent Hong Kong and Macao, and facility of exporting to
other countries. Since industrial accumulations in China takes place
corresponding to expansion of operations by Japanese automakers, more
companies prefer Southern regions to other regions (JBIC, Ibid.).
Functional clustering shows a strong tendency to locate production
functions in Southern regions, distribution functions in Northeastern
regions, and regional control functions in Northern and Southern
regions. This corresponds with the status of development at sub-national
levels in this country. Japanese manufacturers are more interested in
increasing revenues and earnings through reinforcing business operations
in the emerging sub-national markets.
The Perceived Theory Of Japanese FDI In China
Huge research literatures explain theoretically and empirically the
underlying reasons of success of the Asia's high growth economies,
and regard them as the world's growth pole that create and emit
forces to foster development supportive environment for the rest of the
global economy. China witnessed a dramatic growth at the average rate of
about 10 percent in the 1980s, more than 10.3 percent in 1990s, and more
than 9 percent in the year 2000. Max Weber's cultural
configurations of Confucianism that propels economic development has
been widely attributed to by many development economists and historians
while explaining development in Asian NIEs. Confucianism, which forms
the foundation of Chinese societal interactions and work ethics, has
historically modeled the economic developmental environment of this
nation (Chen, 1989, p. 63). China's state sponsored socialist
policies, moreover, was always development oriented and
"economic" development supportive, either with or without
courting capitalistic modus operandi, and welfare oriented. Its
government can be admired as pro-development or "conducive
autocratic" and has ensured a stable environment for investment,
modernization, and socio-economic transition. FDI is regarded as a solid
substitute for Confucian culture (Chen, Ibid, pp. 63-70). China's
Open Door Policy was, indeed, a rational and robust challenge towards
courting the western market-economy fundamentals, and a realistic
"demonstration" of the advanced Asian neighbors. Buckley,
Clegg, Wang, and Cross (2002, pp. 1-28) viewed FDI as one of the most
palpable outcomes of the same policy, which has also bolstered FDI and
foreign firms' activities in the economically strong provinces.
The G-F-P model of Akamatsu does not optimally explain China's
development or its FDI harvesting. Chen observes the matter as follows:
"China is not a goose but some other huge bird flying side by side
with the geese. China has the potential of complementing and competing
with the various layers (author adds, raw materials, product,
technology, industry, country) of the flying geese at various levels of
industrial production. In some areas, China is competing or potentially
could compete with Japan and the NICs.--China is also producing
downstream labour-intensive products in competition with ASEAN-4"
(1989, pp. 70-71).
This locational phenomenon of Japanese MNCs production bases in
NIEs/ ASEAN, and in the next phase, from NIEs to ASEAN seem somewhat
akin to the propositions in Vernon's P-L-C and Akamatsu's
G-F-P models of economic development. Japan, however, did more
investment in USA and Europe, and only recently invests in big amounts
to China. Most of the Japanese MNCs did not develop new products, nor
did introduce new products to the developed country markets other than
their own one. It can thus be argued that P-L-C and G-F-P models fail to
explain fully the movement Japanese FDI or MNCs to China.
The country-specific factors and conditions in China can be fairly
accommodated in Porter's diamond model and country-specific
advantages in Rugmen's theory, as was mentioned earlier. The
government maneuvers trickily and wittily to nurture, multiply, and
refurbish its country-specific advantages, which can be attributed to as
"pull factors". Traditional push factors in Japan, such as,
high labour costs, lose of viability by low-tech, light industries at
home are of paramount importance, but Japanese MNCs aim to reap
advantages inherent in China's market structure and also those
arising out of its rapidly transforming social-market environments,
which can be attributed to as "neo-push factors", propelling
their investment into the Chinese market.
The fact that, Japanese MNCs attach importance to China over other
distantly located countries and to the affluent sub-regions within
China, further leads to infer that P-L-C and geo-business models explain
some Japanese MNCs' FDI to China. While Toyota and other major
automobile makers have established their operations in China with
R&D facilities, Sanyo, Matsushita, Hitachi, Toshiba, and many other
small and non-reputed E&E makers have done the same, where the
demand for household appliances, electronics goods, and low price fuel
efficient private vehicles are increasing at galloping rates. This
implies that companies are more in search of lucrative markets in China,
the geographical factors and other factor endowments more important to
them, and the stages of products are illusory or less visible. Proximity
of China's Eastern and Southern regions to Japan further supports
this argument.
Japanese FDI flowed to China due to its MNCs effort to divert their
firm-specific competitive advantages (superior HRM techniques, TQM, JIT and kanban) to the culturally akin (cultural advantage) and
geographically close (market proximity) huge markets in China. As found,
local competitors are less equipped in terms of management, technology,
QC control, market promotion, and distribution than their Japanese
counterparts, but Japanese MNCs possess the same competitive relations
among them as it is in the home country. Thus, it is seen that
Fayerweather's proposition of "transfer of management
resources" better explains FDI by Japanese MNCs, in that, they
transfer their more advanced management resources to China to seek its
country-specific advantages (Yamamura, 2001, pp.36-40). China caught
those FDI with diligent and wit. China's reform policies and market
oriented development programs created and nurtured its country-specific
advantages. Japan, however, is a late entrant to automobile and other
star-product sectors in China, and is outdone by German, the USA,
France, and Asian rivals from South Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan in some
cases.
Concluding Remark
Thus what emerges broadly from this study is that, a single
existing model is not sufficient to theorize Japanese FDI to China,
rather a host of theories or models explain the different aspects of
Japanese MNCs' practices/FDI in this country. While more empirical
research, using statistical and econometric models, is needed to
theorize and support findings of this research, in its status quo it can
be called a Japanese FDI a la China model. It incorporates elements from
many theories, as mentioned above, to explain the scenarios surrounding
Japanese FDI in China.
References
Aharoni, Yair (1966). The Foreign Investment Decision Process,
Boston: Harvard Business School.
Akamatsu, Kaname (1961). "A Theory of Unbalanced Growth in the
World Economy", Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 86 (I).
Buckley, Peter J., Clegg, Jeremy, Wang, Chengqi, and Cross, Adam R.
(2002). "FDI, regional differences and economic growth: panel data
evidence from China", Transnational Corporations, 11 (1).
Chen, K. Y. Edward (1989). "Economic Trends in Asia",
Naya, Seiji, et. al. (eds). Lessons in Development: a Comparative Study
of Asia and Latin America, California: ICS Press.
Daily Yomiuri, The (2006, May 1). "Weakest link of
China's economy", Tokyo.
Dunning, John H (1979, November). "Explaining Changing
Patterns of International Production: in Defense of the Eclectic
Theory", Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 41 (4).
-- (1988, Spring). "The Eclectic Paradigm of International
Production: A Restatement and Some Possible Extensions", Journal of
International Business Studies, 4(1).
Fayerweather, John (1969). International Business Management: A
Conceptual Framework, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Gilpin, Robert (1975). U.S. Power and the Multinational
Corporation--The Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment, New
York: Basic Books.
Hymer, Stephen (1976). The International Operations of National
Firms: A Study in Foreign Direct Investment, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Japan Bank for International Cooperation or JBIC (2005). Survey
Report on Overseas Business Operations by Japanese Manufacturing
Companies, Tokyo: JBIC Institute.
JETRO (several years). JETRO White Paper on Trade and Investment
(in Japanese), Tokyo: JETRO
Kojima, Kiyoshi (1975, June). "International trade and foreign
investment: substitutes or complements", Hitotsubashi Journal of
Economics, 16.
-- and Ozawa, Terutomo (1984, June). "Micro- and
macro-economic models of direct foreign investment: toward a
synthesis", Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, 25.
Koontz, Harold (1961, December). "The Management Theory
Jungle", Academy of Management Journal, 4(3).
Krugman Paul (1983): "New Theories of Trade Among Industrial
Countries", American Economic Review, 73 (2).
-- (1990): Rethinking International Trade, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT
Press.
-- and Obstefld, Maurice (2002). International Economics: Theory
and Policy, Readings, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.
Nakajima, Seiichi ed. (2005, August). Economic Statistics of
China--After Reform and Opening (in Japanese), Tokyo: JETRO.
Ozawa, Terutomo (1992, February). "Foreign direct investment
and economic development", Transnational Corporations, 1 (1).
Porter, Michael E. (1990). The Competitive Advantage of Nations,
New York: Free Press.
Rugman, Alan (1985, September). "Internalization Is Still a
General Theory of Foreign Direct Investment", Weltwirtschaftliches
Archiv, 121(3).
Sikorski, D., and Mennkhoff, T. (2000). "Internationalization of Asian Business", Singapore Management Review, 22(1).
Suzuki, Youtarou (2001). "Locating Industries in Foreign
Countries--From the Viewpoint of Evolution of Overseas Manufacturing
Bases (in Japanese)" in Osaka City University, Faculty of Commerce
(ed.). International Business, Tokyo: Yuhikaku. Suzuki cites from Alfred
Weber's research in 1922.
UN/UNCTAD (2002). World Investment Report 2002, New York: UN.
-- (2005). World Investment Report 2005, New York: UN.
Vernon, Raymond (1966, May): "International Investment and
International Trade in the Product Cycle", The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, LXXX.
Yamamura, Youichi (2001). "Theory of Multinational
Corporations", in Kinumaki, Yasushi ed., International
Management--Foreign Trade, Investment and Operation of Multinational
Corportions, Tokyo: Bunshindo.
Zhou, Yuping and Lall, Sanjaya (2005, April). "The impact of
China's FDI surge on FDI in South-East Asia: panel data analysis
for 986-2001", Transnational Corporations, 14 (1).
by Khondaker Mizanur Rahman
Nanzan University, Japan