International e-banking: ICT investments and the Basel Accord.
Lin, Hong-Jen ; Lin, Winston T.
This study investigates how the Basel Accord and Information and
Telecommunications Technologies (ICT) investments affect the commercial
banking industries across countries. We employ the stochastic frontier
approach to explore a data set composed of commercial banks, from 51
countries. We find that telecommunications investment reduces, and the
Basel Accord proxy enhances, the cost efficiency of commercial banks
under study. Moreover, it is found that ICT investments improve cost
efficiencies of commercial banks for countries in which the regulations
are consistent with the international supervision.
1. Introduction
During the past decade, commercial banks have witnessed dramatic
change in information and telecommunications technologies (called ICT
hereinafter). For instance, the use of electronic communication, such as
electronic bill paying, home banking, and internet transaction, has been
altering the relationship of business-to-business (B2B) and
business-to-customer (B2C). The marketing accessibility of financial
institutions is extended and increased to remote areas or countries via
the new telecommunications technology. Hence, the role of ICT
investments becomes more important in the banking industry. This trend
is also called e-banking.
The impacts of ICT in banking are categorized into three
categories: 1) globalization, 2) deregulation, and 3) consolidation
(Nieto, 2001). First, commercial banks can outreach remote clients via
electronic communications devices to the extent that foreign customers
are able to process transactions across national borders. Thus, the
banking markets are marching toward globalization. Second, accompanying
globalization, deregulation in the banking industry prevails in many
countries in order to improve the competitive strength of the financial
industry of a nation. Third, new technologies also enlarge the
capacities of financial institutions and thus improve their cost
efficiency. Therefore, more and more commercial banks have merged
together to attain a higher level of efficiency than before.
These issues on e-banking are international. Since the
consolidation of financial institutions may take place across countries
with different regulatory rules, the international supervision on the
banking regulation is urgent. In other words, we must set up proper
international banking regulations in order to satisfy the needs of the
international e-banking. Via the efforts of international regulations
such as the Basel Accord, (1) customers can be securely protected,
transactions can be smoothly processed, and operations are tightly
monitored by the supervisory bodies who join this Accord. The Basel
Accord requires commercial banks in member countries to maintain
adequate capitals and disclose related information to the public.
Consequently, commercial banks become more transparent across countries
and thus, more efficient than ever before.
This paper differentiates itself from previous studies in several
aspects. First, this research is devoted to the impact of ICT
investments in commercial banking. Many previous studies (e.g., Hunter
and Timme, 1991, among others) have explored the 'technological
change', instead of the ICT investments, of commercial banks, while
the concept of technological change is too broad. Second, not many
efforts have been made on the international comparison in commercial
banking. One of the few exceptions is Allen and Rai (1996).
Nevertheless, their efforts do not involve commercial banks in emerging
economies. Third, previous IT research focuses on the effect of IT
investments on the productivity of non-financial industries (or across
industries) rather than the effect of ICT investments on the banking
industry. Fourth, this is a pioneering attempt to link the impact of ICT
investments to that of international banking regulations.
The objective of this study is twofold: first, to address the
question-'do ICT investments contribute to commercial banks?'
and, second, to investigate the question- 'does the countries
joined the Basel Accord outperform those non-Basel Accord countries in
terms of cost efficiencies?' In essence, we would like to explore
the sources of the cost efficiency of international commercial banking:
is it from regulations or from ICT investments? or from both? In the
methodological issues, it is worth noting that the efficiency analysis
has become dominant in the research of financial institutions. We follow
this convention but adopt a more generalized stochastic frontier
approach to estimate cost efficiency (Wang and Schmidt, 2002). Our
approach is shown empirically and theoretically superior to previous
ones. The remainder of this research is structured as follows. Section 2
discusses the methodologies used and Section 3 provides the data sources
and statistical hypotheses. Section 4 presents and analyzes empirical
results. Finally, Section 5 concludes.
2. Methodologies
This section is designed to specify the estimation models on which
the analysis is based. We explain the measure of cost efficiency, often
used in the literature of financial institutions.
The present section consists of three subsections. Subsection 2.1
introduces notations of the variables used and details the choices of
ICT proxies. Subsection 2.2 discusses methodological issues regarding
cost efficiency. Finally, Subsection 2.3 specifies the estimation
models.
2.1 Notations and ICT Proxies
The variables used in this study are classified into five
categories: dependent variables, output variables, input prices, control
variables, and ICT proxies, where output variables and input prices are
key variables in the traditional stochastic frontier analysis. The
notations used are described as follows:
The dependent variable of the cost frontier is [LNTC.sub.it] where
[LNTC.sub.it] = ln([TC.sub.it/TA.sub.it])
[TC.sub.it] = the sum of a bank' s operating and interest
costs
[TA.sub.it] = total assets
and the subscripts i and t denote bank i at time t. The output
variables are represented by a vector of output [Y.sub.it] that
includes:
[LNLN.sub.it] = ln([LN.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it])
[LNTD.sub.it] = ln([TD.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it])
[LNFI.sub.it] = ln([FI.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it])
where
[LN.sub.it] = the sum of personal loans, commercial loans, property
and real estate loans, and industrial loans
[TD.sub.it] = the sum of demand and term deposits
[FI.sub.it] = the sum of long - term and short - term investments
[TD.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it] = the ratio of total loans to total assets
[TD.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it] = the ratio of total deposits to to total
assets
and
[FI.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it] = the ratio of financial investments over
total assets
The vector of input prices is denoted by [p.sub.it]: (e.g., the
wage of labor and price of capital), which is listed as follows:
[LNW.sub.it] = ln([W.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it])
where [w.sub.it] is the wage rate,
[LNC.sub.it] = In [r.sub.it]
and [r.sub.it] is the real deposit rate,
[r.sub.it] = price of capital in real term (2)
Note that the scales of different banks in different countries vary
widely, so do the variance of the firm-specific variables for different
banks in different countries. In order to account for such
heteroscedastic nature of commercial banks, [TC.sub.it], [TD.sub.it],
[FI.sub.it], [LN.sub.it], and [w.sub.it] are measured in the comparative
ratios to total assets. That is, the outputs, total costs, and wage
rates are divided by the amount of the total assets ([TA.sub.it]) of the
bank i at time t.
The control variables represented by country risk variables are:
[FIN.sub.it] = country financial risk
[POL.sub.it] = country political risk
[ECO.sub.it] = country economic risk
The three control variables are country-specific. Thus, they stay
the same for different banks within a country and differ for banks for
different countries. Although the dependent variable, the output
variables, and the wage of labor are firm-specific, it is insightful to
use country-specific control variables since the Basel proxy B and the
ICT investments proxies are also country-specific variables (detailed in
the following paragraphs).
This study uses three country risk indicators, financial risk,
political risk, and economic risk as control variables, which are used
in Chen and Lin (1994) and compiled by the PRS (Political Risk Services)
Group Inc. (2001). Their country risk rating systems are detailed in
Appendix. Since these three types of country risk indices reflect the
time-varying and comparative risks of a country, it is necessary to
incorporate them into the model as control variables while evaluating
the impact of ICT.
ICT-related variables for a financial institution are not readily
available, so the country-level proxies are used. The e-banking
variables are not available, either, so we are forced to use ICT proxies
as the substitutes of e-banking variables.
In previous studies, either the country level IT capital stock
(Dewan and Kraemer, 2000, and Daveri, 2001) or firm-level IT stock (Hitt
and Brynjolfsson, 1996; Lin and Shao, 2000; and Shao and Lin, 2000,
2001, 2002) is used to describe the contribution of IT to productivity
or productive efficiency. We follow Dewan and Kraemer (2000) for two
reasons. First, our focal point for an international comparison is
similar to theirs. Second, the firm-level data of IT capital stock is
not available for many other countries. Thus, the country-level
variables are used as proxies. In other words, the same ICT proxies
apply for banks within a country.
Here, the growth rate of the IT capital stock (ITCS) is adopted and
calculated as follows:
[IT.sub.it] = [ITCS.sub.it] - [ITCS.sub.it-1]/[ITCS.sub.it-1] x
100%
Telecommunications investments have increased rapidly in order to
foster progress in IT, caused by the rapid development of the internet
and telecommunications. Thus, the growth rate of telecommunications
capital investments (COMCI) is used and calculated as follows:
[COM.sub.it] = [COMCI.sub.it] - [COMCI.sub.it-1]/[COMCI.sub.it-1] x
100%
Based on the specification of IT and COM, we can examine how new
technologies (ICT) influence the performance of financial institutions
across nations.
The data of both ITCS and COMCI are defined as total revenue paid
to vendors (including channel markups) for hardware, data
communications, software, and services. Hence, these two variables are
not seriously impacted by the various accounting methods of capital
investments in different countries. Moreover, IT and COM are growth
rates of ITCS and COMCI, which reduces the problems of measuring errors
caused by different currencies in different countries. And the results
based on this data set are comparable across countries. Given that other
official data sources are not available, this is the only source of
information technology investments data for a large cross-section of
countries in the 1990's.
Since it is difficult to quantify what extent to which a country
complies its regulations with the Basel Accord, we rely on dummy
variable to deal with this problem. The Basel Accord variable B is
defined as one if a country joins the Basel Accord, while B is equal to
zero if a country does not.
2.2 Cost Efficiency
The stochastic frontier analysis is the one-step approach by Wang
and Schmidt (2002). The one-step cost efficiency frontier model is
applied to pool the cross-section of time-series (i.e., panel) data
culled from commercial banks throughout the world to explore the
dynamically and stochastically shifting patterns of the cost
(in)efficiencies of banks over time. (3)
The one-step model consisting of Equations (1) and (2) to examine
the cost efficiency of commercial banks is illustrated as follows:
ln[TC.sub.it] = f([y.sub.it], [p.sub.it]; [beta]) + [z.sub.it]
[gamma] + [u.sub.it] + [v.sub.ti] [1]
and
[u.sub.it] = g([IT.sub.it], [COM.sub.it], [B.sub.it]; [alpha]) +
[[epsilon].sub.it] [2]
where [beta]: the traditional vector of unknown parameters to be
estimated,
[gamma]: the vector of unknown parameter to be estimated,
[u.sub.it]: a random variable to account for the truncated-normally
distributed cost inefficiency at the mean of the g-function,
[V.sub.it]: a random variable to describe the normally distributed
disturbance, and
f(x): the optimized cost function of a given output vector and
input prices.
[IT.sub.it] and [COM.sub.it] in the g-function are the ICT
variable. (4) [z.sub.it] is a set of country-specific control variables.
B is the Basel Accord dummy. B=1, when a country joins the Basel Accord,
Otherwise, B=0. [alpha] is the vector of unknown parameters to be
estimated in the inefficiency [u.sub.it]. [[epsilon].sub.it] is a
truncated random variable (half-normally distributed) to account for the
error term of the cost inefficiency. That is,
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
2.3 Specifications of the Models
In Equations (1) and (2) the output vector [Y.sub.it] (cf. Lin and
Lin, 2005) consists of three output, [LN.sub.it], [TD.sub.it], and
[FI.sub.it]. Due to the limitation of the availability of data, we are
forced to use total deposits rather than demand deposits that have often
been used in the related studies.
The elements of the input price vector ([P.sub.it]) include wit and
[r.sub.it]. Following Allen and Rai (1996), Rai (1996), and Lin and Lin
(2005), the wage of labor is obtained by dividing the total staff
expenses by the total number of reported employees of a bank. The total
staff expenses and total number of reported employees for a given bank
are collected from its financial statements. The price of capital is
measured by the loan interest rate of the country. In Equation (2), both
[IT.sub.it] and [COM.sub.it] are utilized to describe the ICT proxy over
time, as mentioned earlier. The cost function in Equation (1) takes a
translog form, the most frequently used form of the cost frontier in the
banking literature, while the g-function in Equation (2) is assumed to
be linear. (cf., e.g., Lin and Lin, 2005).
The translog functional Equation (1) can be re-written as follows:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] [3]
where
[y.sub.1it] = [LN.sub.it] /[TA.sub.it]
[y.sub.2it] = [TD.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it]
[y.sub.3it] = [FI.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it]
[p.sub.1it] = [w.sub.it]/[TA.sub.it]
[p.sub.2it] = [r.sub.it]
Based on the model specifications above, we are able to employ the
performance measure of cost efficiency to assess the ICT effect and the
international supervision across countries.
3. Data Sources and Statistical Hypothesis
This section summarizes data sources, and statistics of variables.
We also display the statistical hypothesis to be tested.
3.1 Data Sources
Our analysis is based on the variables from the financial
statements (firm specific and microeconomic variables). Nevertheless,
the country-level attributes are introduced to control the overall
economic climates for different countries. The observation period ranges
from 1993 to 2000. Due to the problem of missing values, unbalanced
panel data are used. All data are dated at the end of the year.
We categorize variables into two levels: firm-level and
country-level. The firm-level variables are based on the financial
statements gathered from the World Scope CD. (5) A problem arising from
the use of international accounting data is that accounting principles
used in different countries differ, and there are diverse
transformations of different foreign exchange rates. Nevertheless, the
World Scope has made efforts to standardize the data. Moreover, by using
a broader category of a variable, we alleviate the problems of varying
definitions and measurement errors of accounting practices among
different countries. Even though our firm-level data do not exhaust all
banks in a country, they nonetheless represent a majority of the players
of the industries in a country.
The country-level data are collected from the International
Financial Statistics (IFS) published by the IMF and the World
Development Indicator Database compiled by the World Bank. The base year
of both data sets for all countries and all variables has been adjusted
to the end of 1995. The two data sets that follow a universal format of
variables serve as the comparable foundation across countries. In order
to conduct cross-national comparisons, all monetary items have been
denominated into US dollars.
Following Dewan and Kraemer (1998, 2000) and Daveri (2001), the ICT
variables (including ITCS and COMCI) are obtained from the International
Data Corporation (IDC), a private consulting firm specializing in
high-tech industry research. The ITCS variable is defined as the total
revenue paid to vendors (including channel markups) for hardware, data
communications, software, and services. Since other official data
sources are not available, this is the only source of ICT investments
data for a large cross-section of countries in the 1990's.
3.2 Summary of Variables
The countries under study are listed in Table 1, where Belgium,
Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, the Netherlands,
Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, UK and US participate in the Basel Accord,
while the other countries are classified as non-Basel countries. The
countries joining the Basel Accord are supervised by their domestic
regulatory bodies in terms of the required capitals (called Basel I).
Here, for the purpose of comparison, we further split the whole
sample into two sub-samples: Basel countries and non-Basel countries.
The Basel group consists of thirteen countries and the sub-sample of the
non-Basel group is constituted by thirty-eight countries. Table 2 shows
statistic summary of the variables in the whole sample and sub-samples.
The whole sample contains 3494 observations from 51 countries under
study; the sub-sample of Basel countries is composed of 1858
observations; and the sub-sample of non-Basel countries consists of 1636
observations.
It is insightful to compare the means of variables in different
sub-samples. The comparative total costs of commercial banks (LNTC) in
the Basel countries are lower than those in the non-Basel countries
(-2.4435 vs. -1.8771). Very obviously, the total costs of the Basel
countries must be larger than those of the non-Basel countries in terms
of absolute value. Hence, we can conclude that the Basel countries are
more cost-saving than the non-Basel countries in the comparative
measure. Similarly, LNW of the Basel countries is smaller than that of
the non-Basel countries (-5.8226 vs. -5.3248). Moreover, the cost of
capital of Basel countries (0.5673) is again smaller than that of the
non-Basel countries (1.8994). All these shows that the comparative input
prices and total costs of the non-Basel countries are higher than those
of the Basel countries.
Regarding the means of the three output variables LNLN, LNTD, and
LNFI, we find that the Basel countries produce more LNLN and LNFI
(-0.3474 vs. -0.4166 and -1.8535 vs. -1.9993, respectively) but less
LNTD (-0.7137 vs. -0.5467) than the non-Basel countries in the sample.
This outcome shows that commercial banks in the Basel countries are
bigger in terms of scale, amounts of loans, and the balances of
financial investments (including long-term and short-term) than their
counterparts in the non-Basel countries. The Basel countries benefit
from sound regulations in banking and freedoms of international capital
flows, so their banks are able to make more loans to companies in both
Basel and non-Basel countries, which results in the higher LNLN in the
Basel countries. They also enjoy a variety of financial instruments that
allow their commercial banks to diversify their risks. Thus, the
commercial banks in the Basel countries invest more heavily than those
in the non-Basel countries. In contrast, people in some developing
countries (all of them are non-Basel countries) tend to deposit a
majority of their disposable incomes. Thus, the LNTD in the non-Basel
countries is larger than that in the Basel countries.
The means of the three z control variables POL, ECO, and FIN for
the Basel countries are unanimously bigger than those for the non-Basel
countries (POL: 81.3119 vs. 74.5446; ECO: 40.7832 vs. 37.9245; and FIN:
44.5151 vs. 40.3386). This comparison signals that the Basel countries
bear lower political, economic, and financial risks than the non-Basel
countries.
The IT and COM variables for the Basel countries are on average
smaller than those for the non-Basel countries (IT: 5.9071 vs. 11.2578
and COM: 8.6934 vs. 13.4227, respectively). Since many non-Basel
countries are emerging economies that have enjoyed rapid technological
changes in recent years, their ICT investments are larger in terms of
growth rates. In addition, the standard deviations of all variables are
listed for references.
3.3 Statistical Hypotheses
In this study, we are interested in the impact of the international
supervision in accordance with the Basel Accord and that of the affect
of the ICT investments. Therefore, two hypotheses H1 and H2 are
proposed. These two hypotheses are tested on the basis of the
two-equation model. These three hypotheses are:
H1: B (the proxy for the Basel countries) has a positive impact on
cost efficiency. (i.e., B is statistically negative in Equation (2).)
H2: IT investments exert a positive effect on cost efficiency.
(i.e., the coefficient of IT is statistically negative in Equation (2).)
H3: COM investments have a positive impact on cost efficiency.
(i.e., the coefficient of COM is statistically negative in Equation
(2).)
If H1 is not rejected, it is efficient for a country to join the
Basel Accord to improve the operations of commercial banking. If H2 is
not rejected, the IT investments would lead to the increase in the cost
efficiency of the banks in the Basel countries and the non-Basel
countries as well. If H3 is not rejected, it is efficient to invest in
COM to improve the operation of commercial banks. Moreover, if neither
H1, nor H2, nor H3 is rejected for the whole sample, then ICT
investments and the international regulations are the essential factors
(sources) that improve the cost efficiency.
4. Analysis of Empirical Results
This subsection discusses the empirical results of Equations (l)
and (2). Table 3 shows estimates of the cost frontiers of the whole
sample and two sub-samples and Table 4 demonstrates results of the sub-
time periods of years 1997, 1998, and 1999.
4.1 Analysis of the Whole Time Periods
According to Table 3, in the whole sample, our empirical result of
Equation (1) shows that the input prices LNW and LNC are positively
related with the total cost (LNTC) and two outputs (LNLN and LNTD) are
negatively linked to LNTC, while the other output variable LNFI is
insignificant. The three control variables POL, ECO, and FIN are
significantly and negatively associated with LNTC. Since high control
variables represent a low risk, our result reveals that the lower risk a
country bears, the lower the total cost of banks in that country is.
In Equation (2), IT reduces the cost inefficiency [u.sub.it] but
the impact is insignificant. Nevertheless, COM strongly contributes to
the cost inefficiency significantly at the 1% level. Moreover, the Basel
Accord proxy B is significantly and negatively related to the cost
inefficiency, implying that the international regulations improve on the
cost efficiency of the banks in the sample countries. The absolute value
of the coefficient of B is larger than that of COM (-1.3847 vs. 0.0234)
and its absolute t-value is also larger (-6.55 vs. 3.17). This outcome
signals that the telecommunications investments seriously deteriorate the cost efficiency of the banks in the countries under study, and the
both the IT and the Basel Accord proxy B are more important factors in
improving the cost efficiency of commercial banks than COM. That is, H1
is not rejected in the whole sample.
We further divide the whole sample into two sub-samples: Basel
countries and non-Basel countries and concentrate on the results of
Equation (2). Interestingly, it is observed that IT mitigates the cost
inefficiency of commercial banks in the sub-sample of the Basel
countries, while the impact of COM on the cost inefficiency stays
insignificant. That is, H2 of IT is not rejected but H3 of COM is
rejected for the sub-sample of the Basel countries. In the sub-sample of
the non-Basel countries, IT does not exert a significant impact on the
cost inefficiency and the effect caused by COM is significant only at
the 10% level. In other words, H2 of IT and H3 of COM are rejected for
the non-Basel countries.
This outcome signals that 1) commercial banks in the non-Basel
countries cannot align the ICT investments with their operations; 2) IT
investments alone, but COM investments alone do not, enhance the cost
efficiency of commercial banks; and 3) the COM investments are
capital-using for the whole sample and the sub-sample of the non-Basel
countries, and they seem indifferent toward the cost efficiency for the
sub-sample of the Basel countries. Without good supervisory regulations,
the commercial banks in a country cannot outperform their counterparts
by using the COM investments. In other words, IT investments help banks
save cost only when appropriate regulations and standards are
well-established.
In addition, we have investigated the lag effect of ICT investments
on the cost efficiency but the impact stays insignificant. Therefore,
the results are not shown here. The empirical results related to the lag
effects of IT and COM are available upon request.
4.2 Analysis of Years 1997, 1998 and 1999
It is insightful to analyze the empirical results of sub-periods.
By doing so, we can depict the time-varying patterns of the cost
efficiency for different years. Unfortunately, the empirical results of
the stochastic frontiers for 1993, 1994, 1995, 1996, and 2000 are not
obtainable due to the wrong skewness of the dependent variable.
Therefore, the results for these years are not shown here.
In Table 4, we find that the input price variables LNC and LNW are
positively related to the LNTC for 1997, 1998 and 1999. Therefore, the
input prices contribute positively to the total costs. Two output
variables LNTD and LNFI are negatively related to the total costs for
1997, 1998 and 1999 while LNLN is negatively related to LNTC for 1997
and 1998 but positively related to LNTC in 1999. In addition, the
results of the z variables of country risks vary from year to year.
The results of ICT (IT and COM) investments and the Basel proxy
from Equation (2) are our focal point. We find that IT is positively
linked to the cost inefficiency for 1997 but negatively and
significantly associated with the cost inefficiency for 1998 (at the 10%
significance level) and 1999 (at the 1% significance level). These
estimates over time suggest that the 1T investments tend to contribute
to the cost efficiency of commercial banks more and more deeply as time
goes by. The COM variable remains insignificant for 1997 and positively
related to the cost inefficiency for 1998. However, it mitigates the
cost inefficiency (i.e., enhances the cost efficiency) for 1999.
Consequently, COM tends to reduce the cost efficiency for 1998 hut
improve it for 1999. In other words, the changing pattern of the effect
of COM on the cost efficiency is shifting favorably through time.
Moreover, the estimated coefficients of the Basel proxy B indicate
that the international supervision on commercial banks unanimously
increases the cost inefficiency significantly at the 1% level for all
the three sub-periods, 1997, 1998, and 1999. This evidence reveals the
fact that it is capital-using for a bank to align its operations with
the international Basel Accord for each year, though it is beneficial to
banks in the long run (i.e., the observation periods are longer than one
year) as shown in Table 3.
5. Conclusions
This article has explored the impacts of the ICT (IT and COM)
investments on the cost efficiency of commercial banks for 51 nations
including both countries joining the Basel Accord and the other
economies. In the analysis via the stochastic frontier approach, we have
found that IT investments are significant in improving the cost
efficiency of the banks in the countries in the Basel Accord. COM
investments tend to affect the cost efficiency negatively, particularly
for the whole sample combining the Basel and the non-Basel countries.
Furthermore, the analysis for the three sub-periods has indicated that
participating in the Basel Accord is capital-using in the short run
(i.e., in the cross-sectional analysis) but cost-saving in the long run
(i.e., in the whole panel data set). In addition, the impacts of the ICT
investments on the cost efficiency become stronger and stronger from
1997 to 1999. In other words, the time-varying patterns of the effects
of IT and COM upon the cost efficiency are favourable.
Obviously, our analysis contributes to technology policy and
management, international e-banking, and international supervisions in
banking. We have found that IT investments, instead of the
telecommunications investments, of a country are important source of the
cost efficiency of commercial banks. Moreover, this study provides a
strategic implication for the international banking market. Once the
deregulation across countries takes place, financial institutions
facilitated with IT investments in highly efficient countries would
invade the banking markets in the countries with low IT investments and
cost efficiencies. On the other hand, the banks in the non-Basel
countries can adopt successful e-banking models and international
supervisions to leapfrog over their counterparts in the Basel countries.
Given this research project, there are some possible extensions.
First, the new Basel Accord (usually called Basel II), which will be
implemented, calls for the three-pillar regulations. Therefore, an
extended new analysis is needed in exploring the impact of the new Basel
Accord. Second, different ownership structures of financial institutions
such as public-owned and private-owned may be considered in the field of
international e-banking. Third, commercial banks in several countries
(e.g., U.S.) have started to sell life insurance policies to clients.
Consequently, the boundary between the banking and insurance industries
is becoming blurred. New research on this new wave of conglomerates of
financial institutions is necessary. And fourth, an in-depth discussion
on how ICT investments under the new Basel Accord improve the cost
efficiency of banks is imperative. It is not satisfactory to find out
that the countries in the Basel Accord outperform others in the cost
efficiency of commercial banking. We want to know the details of the
procedure of adopting new technologies and supervisions to improve cost
efficiency.
All in all, the ultimate goal of the ICT investments is to maximize
a firm's market value of stocks through the improvement of cost
efficiency. Consequently, it is important to investigate how ICT
investments are linked to the profit and stock prices of a firm at the
microeconomic level and to the GDP of a country at the macroeconomic level in future research. These interesting empirical problems await
future efforts to solve them. The solution to these problems will
further enrich and benefit the practice of international banking.
In closing, the present study has made multifold contributions to
the literature of finance and banking: theoretically sound,
methodologically correct, and empirically rich.
Appendix: Definitions of Three Country Risk Indicators
The political risk rating (POL) measures the political stability of
a country. It is composed of 12 components: government stability,
socioeconomic conditions, investment profile, internal conflict,
external conflict, corruption, military in politics, religion in
politics, law and order, ethnic tensions, democratic accountability, and
bureaucracy quality. The economic risk (ECO) components include GDP per
Head, Real GDP Growth, Annual Inflation Rate, Budget Balance as a
Percentage of GDP. and Current Account as a percentage of GDP. The
financial risk index (FIN) is rated by the Percentage of Foreign Debt to
GDP, Foreign Debt Service as a Percentage of Exports of Goods and
Services, Current Account as a Percentage of Exports of Goods and
Services, Net International Liquidity as Months of Import Cover, and
Exchange Rate Stability. For these three indicators, the higher rating
means lower risk.
References
Allen, L. and Rai, A. (1996). Operational Efficiency in Banking: An
international Comparison. Journal of Banking and Finance 20:655-672.
Berger, A. N. and Mester, L. J., (1999). What Explain the Dramatic
Changes in Cost and Profit Performance of the U.S. Banking Industry?
Working Paper 1999-13, Federal Reserved Bank.
Chen, Y. H., and Lin, W. T. (1994). Political Risk and Adjusted
Present Value. International Journal of Systems Science 25:2207-2220.
Daveri, Francesco. (2001). Information Technology and Growth in
Europe. Working Paper, University of Parma, and Innocenzo Gasparini
Institute for Economic Research IGIER).
Dewan, S. and Kraemer, K. L. (1998). International Dimension of the
Productivity Paradox. Communications of the ACM, 41:56-62.
Dewan, S. and Kraemer, K. L. (2000). Information Technology and
Productivity: Evidence from Country-Level Data. Management Science,
46:548-562.
Hitt, L.M. and Brynjolfsson, E. (1996). Productivity, Business
Profitability, and Consumer Surplus: Three Different Measures of
Information Technology Value. M1S Quarterly, 20:121-142.
Hunter, W. C. and Timme, S. G. (1991). Technological Change in
Large U S. Commercial Banks. Journal of Business, 64:339-362.
Lin, W. T. and Shao, B. B. M. (2000). Relative Sizes of Information
Technology Investments and Productive Efficiency: Their Linkage and
Empirical Evidence. Journal of the Association for Information Systems,
1, Article 7, pp. 1-35.
Lin, W.T. and Lin, H. J. (2005). The Cost and Profit Efficiencies
and Scope Economies of Commercial Banks with Evidence from Taiwan and
China. under the 3rd review by the International Review of Finance.
Nieto, M. (2001). Reflections on the Regulatory Approach to
E-finance. BIS Papers, No 7, part 10.
PRS Group Inc. (2001). International Country Risk Guide, East
Syracuse, New York.
Rai, A. (1996). Cost Efficiency of International Insurance Firms.
Journal of Financial Services Research, 10:213-233.
Shao, B. B. M., and Lin, W. T. (2000). Examining the Determinants
of Productive Efficiency with IT as a Production Factor. Journal of
Computer Information Systems, 41: 25-30.
Shao, B. B. M., and Lin, W. T. (2001). Measuring the Value of
Information Technology in Technical Efficiency with Stochastic
Production Frontiers. Information and Software Technology, 43: 447-456.
Shao, B.B.M. and Lin, W. T. (2002). Technical Efficiency Analysis
of Information Technology Investments: A Two-Stage Empirical
Investigation. Information & Management, 39:391-401.
Wang, H. J. and Schmidt, P. (2002). One-Step and Two-Step
Estimation of the Effects of Exogenous Variables on Technical Efficiency
Levels. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 18:129-144.
by
Hong-Jen Lin
City University of New York, U.S.A.
Winston T. Lin
State University of New York at Buffalo, U.S.A.
Endnotes
(1) The Basel Accord is an agreement defined by the Bank for
International Settlements (BIS) that is an international organization
which fosters international monetary and financial cooperation for
central banks that regulate commercial banks.
(2) The interaction terms in the translog function are products of
the input prices and outputs (for simplicity, the subscripts i and t are
omitted if the omission causes no confusion).
W*C=LNW*LNC, WSQ=LNW*LNW, CSQ=LNC*LNC, LN*TD=LNLN*LNTD, LN*FI=
LNLN*LNFI, TD*FI= LNTD*LNFL LNSQ= LNLN*LNLN, FISQ= LNFI*LNFI, TDSQ=
LNTD*LNTD, LN*W- LNLN*LNW, LN*C= LNLN*LNC, TD*W= LNTD*LNW,
TD*C-LNTD*LNC, FI*W= LNFI*LNW, and FI*C= LNFI*LNC.
(3) The stochastic frontier approach includes both cross-sectional
and panel data analyses. Here, we adopt the panel-data form of it.
(4) IT and COM should be considered in the g-function as exogenous
factors because the collected data of the ICT variables are
country-specific, not firm-specific.
(5) The author is indebted to the Management Library at the
University of Rochester.
Table 1: The List of Countries Under Study
Country Join Basel
Accord or not
Argentina No
Australia No
Austria No
Belgium Yes
Brazil No
Canada Yes
Chile No
Colombia No
Czech Republic No
Denmark No
Egypt No
Finland No
France Yes
Germany Yes
Greece No
Hong Kong No
Hungary No
India No
Indonesia No
Ireland No
Israel No
Italy Yes
Japan Yes
Jordan No
Korea (South) No
Luxembourg Yes
Malaysia No
Mexico No
Morocco No
Netherlands Yes
Norway No
Pakistan No
Peru No
Philippines No
Poland No
Portugal No
Russia No
Singapore No
Slovakia No
South Africa No
Spain Yes
Sri Lanka No
Sweden Yes
Switzerland Yes
Taiwan No
Thailand No
Turkey No
United Kingdom Yes
United States Yes
Venezuela No
Zimbabwe No
Table 2: Summary of Statistics
The Whole Sample
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Obs
LNTC -2.1783 0.5709 3494
LNW -5.5895 1.3776 3494
LNC 1.1910 1.2555 3494
LNLN -0.3798 0.2835 3494
LNTD -0.6355 0.8054 3494
LNFI -1.9317 0.7625 3194
POL 78.1412 9.2946 3494
ECO 39.4446 4.3959 3494
FIN 42.5595 5.1885 3494
IT 8.4125 14.8792 3494
COM 10.9078 19.9142 3494
Basel Countries
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Obs
LNTC -2.4435 0.4922 1858
LNW -5.8226 1.3730 1858
LNC 0.5673 1.2054 1858
LNLN -0.3474 0.2786 1858
LNTD -0.7137 0.9029 1858
LNFI -1.8535 0.7718 1858
POL 81.3119 4.8653 1858
ECO 40.7832 2.8840 1858
FIN 44.5151 3.8313 1858
IT 5.9071 9.7321 1858
COM 8.6934 9.0942 1858
Non-Basel Countries
Variable Mean Std. Dev. Obs
LNTC -1.8771 0.5005 1636
LNW -5.3248 1.3348 1636
LNC 1.8994 0.8793 1636
LNLN -0.4166 0.2846 1636
LNTD -0.5467 0.6672 1636
LNFI -1.9993 0.7445 1636
POL 74.5446 11.5459 1636
ECO 37.9245 5.2429 1636
FIN 40.3386 5.6178 1636
IT 11.2578 18.7129 1636
COM 13.4227 27.2287 1636
Notes:
The dependent variable of the cost frontier is [LNTC.sub.it], where
LNTC=ln(TC/TA). LNLN=ln(LN/TA), [LNTD.sub.it]=ln(TD/TA),
LNFI=ln(FI/TA), LNW=ln(w/TA), and LNC=ln(r) with r being the real
price of capital. The control variables represented by country risk
variables are FIN=country financial risk, POL=country political
risk, and ECO=country economic risk.
Std. Dev. represents the standard deviation and Obs means the
number of observations.
Table 3: The Empirical Results of the Cost Frontiers
All Countries
Equation (1)
Variable Coefficient t-value
Constant -0.4647 -3.79 ***
LNW 0.3063 11.86 ***
LNC 0.4496 17.20 ***
LNLN -0.1960 -2.30 **
LNTD -0.2728 -7.26 ***
LNFi 0.0208 0.60
W*C 0.0218 3.23 ***
WSQ 0.0482 15.36 ***
CSQ -0.0132 -4.08 ***
LN*TD -0.0993 -5.31 ***
LN*FI -0.1866 -8.23 ***
TD*FI -0.0267 -4.37 ***
LNSQ 0.1771 4.26 ***
FISQ 0.0171 2.20 **
TDSQ -0.0134 -2.77 ***
LN*W -0.0229 -1.81 *
LN*C 0.1079 7.21 ***
TD*W -0.0164 -3.05 ***
TD*C 0.0014 0.20
Fi*W 0.0115 2.41 **
FI*C 0.0428 6.54 ***
POL -0.0032 -5.68 ***
ECO -0.0241 -21.43 ***
FIN -0.0053 -4.78 **
Equation (2)
IT -0.0016 -0.32
COM 0.0234 3.17 ***
B -1.3847 -6.55 ***
Lambda 1.8189 16.83 ***
Sigma 0.3580 23.29 ***
Basel Countries
Equation (1)
Variable Coefficient t-value
Constant -2.6475 -14.47 ***
LNW 0.2624 8.57 ***
LNC 0.4981 9.31 ***
LNLN -0.5735 -3.19 ***
LNTD -0.3270 -8.50 ***
LNFi -0.1446 -2.36 **
W*C 0.0451 5.60 ***
WSQ 0.0495 12.55 ***
CSQ 0.1066 10.86 ***
LN*TD -0.0439 -1.79 *
LN*FI 0.1115 1.98 **
TD*FI 0.0017 0.21
LNSQ -0.0069 -0.08
FISQ -0.0074 -0.50
TDSQ -0.0557 -9.78 ***
LN*W -0.1012 -4.99 ***
LN*C -0.0592 -1.21
TD*W -0.0052 -1.15
TD*C 0.0108 1.06
Fi*W -0.0017 -0.24
FI*C 0.0585 3.25 ***
POL -0.0016 -1.66 *
ECO 0.0005 0.30
FIN 0.0024 1.54
Equation (2)
IT -0.0035 -5.87 ***
COM 0.0003 0.22
B -- --
Lambda 1.2100 14.73 ***
Sigma 0.2476 40.60 ***
Non-Basel Countries
Equation (1)
Variable Coefficient t-value
Constant -0.4556 -1.42
LNW 0.1035 1.66 *
LNC 0.3973 6.14 ***
LNLN 0.5448 2.00 **
LNTD -0.5097 -5.54 ***
LNFi 0.0195 0.16
W*C 0.0465 2.79 ***
WSQ 0.0194 2.90 ***
CSQ 0.0173 1.89 *
LN*TD 0.1144 2.28 **
LN*FI -0.1801 -3.22 ***
TD*FI -0.0425 -2.21 **
LNSQ 0.3305 2.74 ***
FISQ 0.0358 1.34
TDSQ 0.0130 1.47
LN*W 0.0529 1.57
LN*C 0.0313 0.90
TD*W -0.0576 -3.97 ***
TD*C 0.0809 6.04 ***
Fi*W -0.0042 -0.29
FI*C 0.0186 1.20
POL -0.0026 -2.31 **
ECO -0.0333 -11.76 ***
FIN -0.0051 -2.28 **
Equation (2)
IT 0.0089 1.58
COM 0.0111 1.65 *
B -- --
Lambda 0.9596 16.38 ***
Sigma 0.2283 18.07 ***
Notes:
*, **, and *** denotes significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,
respectively. The notations of variables are as described in
Sub-section 2.1. The dependent variable of the cost frontier is
LNTC, where LNTC=ln(TC/TA). LNLN=ln(LN/TA), LNTD=ln(TD/TA),
LNFI=ln(FI/TA), LNW=ln(w/TA), and LNC=ln(r), where r=the real price
of capital. The interaction terms are products of the input prices
and outputs. These are: W*C=LNW*LNC, WSQ=LNW*LNW, CSQ=LNC*LNC,
LN*TD=LNLN*LNTD, LN*FI=LNLN*LNFI, TD*FI=LNTD*LNFI, LNSQ=LNLN*LNLN,
FISQ=LNFI*LNFI, TDSQ= LNTD*LNTD, LN*W=LNLN*LNW, LN*C=LNLN*LNC,
TD*W=LNTD*LNW, TD*C=LNTD*LNC, FI*W=LNFI*LNW, and FI*C=LNFI*LNC The
control variables represented by country risk variables are
FIN=country financial risk, POL=country polital risk, and
ECO=country economic risk.
Lambda=[[sigma].sub.u]/[[sigma].sub.v] and Sigma=[square root of
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.u] + [[sigma].sup.2.sub.v]], B is the Basel
Country Proxy.
Table 4: The Empirical Results of the Cost
Frontiers for Years 1997, 1998 and 1999
Year 1997
Variable Coefficient t-value
Equation 1
Constant -1.4365 -4.25 ***
LNW 0.1763 2.99 ***
LNC 0.2525 3.70 ***
LNLN -0.1958 -0.56
LNTD -0.5771 -6.76 ***
LNFI -0.0417 -0.37
W *C 0.0245 1.69
W SQ 0.0424 6.01 ***
CSQ 0.0434 2.46 **
LN*TD -0.0742 -1.21
LN*FI -0.1810 -1.82 *
TD*FI -0.0247 -2.12 **
LNSQ 0.0041 0.02
FISQ 0.0178 0.60
TDSQ -0.0457 -4.19 ***
LN*W -0.0867 -2.57 **
LN*C -0.2691 -4.44 ***
TD*W -0.0382 -4.00 ***
TD*C 0.0589 3.02 ***
FI*W -0.0114 -0.89
FI*C -0.0178 -0.79
POL 0.0018 1.10
ECO -0.0093 -2.68 ***
FIN -0.0175 -4.70 ***
Equation 2
IT 0.0215 5.18 ***
COM 0.0007 0.19
B 0.4945 3.82 ***
Lambda 1.9408 8.63 ***
Sigma 0.3274 17.78 ***
Year 1998
Variable Coefficient t-value
Equation 1
Constant -1.2126 -2.79 ***
LNW 0.2900 3.91 ***
LNC 0.6582 8.06 ***
LNLN -0.1497 -0.33
LNTD -0.7277 -7.34 ***
LNFI -0.0578 -0.36
W *C 0.0583 3.27 ***
W SQ 0.0546 6.05 ***
CSQ 0.1483 6.57 ***
LN*TD -0.1135 -2.58 ***
LN*FI -0.2819 -2.55 **
TD*FI -0.0370 -3.15 ***
LNSQ 0.0294 0.14
FISQ 0.0237 0.66
TDSQ -0.0453 -3.95 ***
LN*W -0.0115 -0.29
LN*C 0.0015 0.02
TD*W -0.0237 -2.18 **
TD*C 0.2538 8.19 ***
FI*W -0.0025 -0.17
FI*C 0.0606 2.48 **
POL -0.0002 -0.12
ECO -0.0329 -7.28 ***
FIN 0.0040 1.12
Equation 2
IT -0.0053 -1.94 *
COM 0.0163 3.45 ***
B 0.2883 2.81 ***
Lambda 1.9918 7.60 ***
Sigma 0.3602 17.68 ***
Year 1999
Variable Coefficient t-value
Equation 1
Constant -1.2003 -1.93 *
LNW 0.1471 1.59
LNC 0.4903 3.96 ***
LNLN 0.0299 0.07
LNTD -0.1227 -1.24
LNFI -0.0438 -0.20
W *C 0.0224 1.25
W SQ 0.0278 2.66 ***
CSQ 0.1058 5.05 ***
LN*TD -0.0402 -0.45
LN*FI 0.0383 0.26
TD*FI -0.0027 -0.13
LNSQ 0.3507 1.39
FISQ 0.0324 0.48
TDSQ -0.0259 -1.50
LN*W -0.0420 -0.86
LN*C 0.1455 1.55
TD*W 0.0130 1.20
TD*C 0.0523 2.31 **
FI*W -0.0091 -0.40
FI*C 0.0669 1.74
POL -0.0051 -2.45 **
ECO -0.0046 -0.73
FIN -0.0204 -3.39 ***
Equation 2
IT -0.0046 -3.77 ***
COM -0.0148 -3.78 ***
B 0.3709 3.42 ***
Lambda 1.8252 8.92 ***
Sigma 0.3742 20.71 ***
Notes:
*, **, and *** denotes significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels,
respectively. The notations of variables are as described in
Sub-section 2.1. The dependent variable of the cost frontier is
LNTC, where LNTC=ln(TC/TA). LNLN=ln(LN/TA), LNTD=ln(TD/TA),
LNFI=ln(FI/TA), LNW=ln(w/TA), and LNC=ln(r), where r=the real price
of capital. The interaction terms are products of the input prices
and outputs. These are: W*C=LNW*LNC, WSQ=LNW*LNW, CSQ=LNC*LNC,
LN*TD=LNLN*LNTD, LN*FI=LNLN*LNFI, TD*FI=LNTD*LNFI, LNSQ=LNLN*LNLN,
FISQ=LNFI*LNFI, TDSQ=LNTD*LNTD, LN*W=LNLN*LNW, LN*C=LNLN*LNC,
TD*W=LNTD*LNW, TD*C=LNTD*LNC, FI*W=LNFI*LNW, and FI*C=LNFI*LNC
The control variables represented by country risk variables
are FIN=country financial risk, POL=country polital risk, and
ECO=country economic risk.
Lambda=[[sigma].sub.u]/[[sigma].sub.v] and Sigma=[square root of
[[sigma].sup.2.sub.u] + [[sigma].sup.2.sub.v]], B is the Basel
Country Proxy.