The performance of initial public offerings in an emerging market: the case of the Istanbul stock exchange.
Ewing, Bradley T. ; Ozfidan, Ozkan
ABSTRACT
This study uses the Markov chain model to examine the behavior of
189 initial public offerings on the Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE) over
the 1990-1999 periods. The non-linear estimation results suggest that
Turkish IPOs do not follow a random walk but may instead follow a
first-order Markov chain process. It may be possible to predict excess
returns conditioned on the observation of the returns in the previous
period. Furthermore, the findings are particularly interesting because,
unlike what is found for most other markets; IPOs on the ISE over
perform the market several years beyond when firms go public. The
results add to our understanding of the behavior of equities in emerging
markets.
JEL: G1, C5
Keywords: Markov chain; Initial public offerings
I. INTRODUCTION
A now well-known finding in finance is that initial public
offerings in the U.S. tend to exhibit positive excess returns in the
short term but then underperforms the market over a longer period, often
for three to six years [Aggarwal and Rivoli (1990); Ritter (1991); Kang
(1995)]. (1) This phenomenon is not unique to the U.S. market as similar
results have been found in the United Kingdom [Levis (1993)] and in
several Latin American countries [Aggarwal, Leal, and Hernandez (1993)].
In fact, according to Kunz and Aggarwal (1994), the underperformance of
IPOs is common to almost every equity market that has been examined.
Surprisingly, while Aggarwal, Leal, and Hernandez (1993) examined the
aftermarket performance of IPOs in the emerging markets of Brazil,
Chile, and Mexico, the study of many other emerging markets, especially
those in Europe and the Middle East has been neglected. The Istanbul
Stock Exchange is a particularly interesting case to examine given
its' relatively small capitalization, unique set of economic
conditions, including extremely high rates of inflation, and that it is
relatively new, having been created in early 1986. The purpose of this
paper is to determine whether or not the excess returns of IPOs on the
Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE) are predictable. Provided that these
excess returns form predictable patterns, an additional goal of the
paper is to ascertain if it is possible for investors to reap financial
gains based on this information.
The results of the paper will provide information as to whether or
not the aftermarket performance of initial public offerings on the ISE
is similar to that of other, more developed equity markets as well as
the emerging markets of Latin America. The standard arguments given for
why IPOs may perform differently than the rest of the market have been
succinctly summarized in Ritter (1991). The first of these reasons is
the "risk mis-measurement" explanation. The measurement of
excess returns may be sensitive to the particular market index used. The
second explanation, albeit the least scientific, is that investors in
IPOs may simply have runs of "bad luck." Of course, since
Ritter's (1991) study, this explanation can essentially be ruled
out as the long-run underperformance of IPOs, especially in developed
markets, is now well-documented. The third explanation suggests that the
behavior of IPO returns is due to "fads." That is to say
(naive) investors may be overly optimistic about IPO behavior and
therefore bid up prices early on only to have them fall later. This last
reason is particularly interesting to consider when examining IPOs in an
emerging market such as that of Turkey. Since the ISE is relatively new,
having begun in 1986, financial market participants may be especially
eager to participate in IPO investments. It is possible that excess or
pent-up demand by Turkish investors might be such that the performance
of IPOs does not resemble that of the overall market.
The present paper differs from most other studies of IPO
performance in that, following Hensler (1998), we use the Markov chain
model to determine if IPO excess returns exhibit random walk behavior.
The use of this nonlinear method has the distinct advantage of allowing
the transition probabilities of the model to vary depending on the prior
state (i.e., whether last period's excess returns were negative or
positive). Mills (1999) describes the two-state Markov model as a type
of "switching- regime" model based on an autoregressive-moving
average process, capable of handling asymmetry and conditional
heteroskedasticity. Thus, the assumption of normally distributed returns
is not required and the Markov model does not require the linearity
assumption of standard regression tests as it allows the transition
probabilities to vary at each stage in a series, or chain, of states.
For this reason, it is often referred to as the Markov chain model. A
fording indicative of a Markov chain provides evidence against the
random walk hypothesis and suggests that Turkish IPO performance may be
predictable. Khan and Kiymaz (1998) and Zychowicz, Binbasioglu, and
Kazancioglu (1995) suggest that the returns of many stocks listed on the
ISE may not follow a random walk and that these returns are not normally
distributed. We test the IPO return series used in this paper for
normality and linearity before proceeding to the Markov chain
examination. In order to conduct these tests we focused on a randomly
selected group of 30 individual IPOs for which we had a full six years
worth of data (i.e., the full sample period). Twenty-three of the thirty
series exhibited non-normal returns based on the Jarque-Bera test statistic. Furthermore, we examined the issue of linearity using the
method outlined in Ozun (1999) and found that over one quarter of the
series exhibited some form of non-linearity. Given these preliminary
findings, it is appropriate to examine the random walk hypothesis using
the Markov chain model.
Finally, Hensler (1998, p. 44) points out reasons for why
researchers should consider the Markov chain analysis used in this paper
when normality and linearity assumptions may not hold for return series
under investigation. (1) The analysis provides a way to ascertain
whether or not a Markovian process exists since previous states are
directly incorporated into the analysis. (2) The previous states
analysis may document predictability, which would contradict the random
walk hypothesis, as the random walk requires that the transition
probabilities do not differ across the states of the model. And, (3) the
analysis can provide information regarding the stabilization or
disappearance of prediction patterns by examining excess returns across
time subsamples.
II. A BRIEF REVIEW OF THE RELATED LITERATURE (2)
Ritter (1991) finds that U.S. IPOs underperformed the market in the
three years after going public. He argues that the results are most
consistent with the "fads" explanation of IPO performance as
firms may go public when their industry is doing exceptionally well.
Loughran (1993) suggests that the underpricing of U.S. IPOs is not
limited to only three years after going public. Examining 3,656 IPOs
over the period from 1967 to 1987, Loughran finds that IPOs have
underperformed in the 72 months after going public. Following in the
footsteps of Ritter's (1991) study, Levis (1993) analyzes short-run
and long-run returns of IPOs issued in the United Kingdom. The results
on long-run performance are similar to those previously documented for
the U.S. market.
The performance of IPOs in emerging markets is not well documented.
However, Aggarwal, Leal, and Hernandez (1993) analyzed IPO returns in
three Latin American countries--Brazil, Mexico, and Chile. They find
that IPOs in these markets experienced significantly negative mean
market-adjusted returns after one to three years. Recently, Hensler,
Herrera, and Lockwood (2000) investigated differences in the performance
of bank and non-bank IPOs in the Mexican market. Their results on
long-run performance (defined as 300 days after issuance) of 68
individual IPOs indicates that 54 non-bank IPOs underperformed the
Mexican market by 21%, while 14 bank IPOs overperformed the market by
56%.
The results of the previous studies suggest that IPOs typically
behave differently than the rest of the market. It also appears that
IPOs typically underperform the market over periods of one to several
years. These findings motivate the study of other emerging markets and,
in particular, our examination of IPOs on the Istanbul Stock Exchange
where, as in many Eastern European and Middle-Eastern countries,
financial markets and investing are just now starting to gain
prominence.
III. THE MARKOV CHAIN PROCESS, DATA, AND METHODOLOGY
Variants of the Markov model have been used to study a number of
financial time series. Engle and Hamilton (1990) examined the
relationship between the British sterling and the U.S. dollar by fitting
a two-state Markov process to the data. They determined that movements
in the exchange rate could be characterized by long swings. Thus, once
an exchange rate is in a particular regime it is likely to remain there
often for more than a year. McQueen and Thorley (1991) used a Markov
chain model to test the random walk hypothesis in U.S. stock returns as
an alternative to standard, linear regression-based tests. They found
non-random walk behavior in the post-war period and random walk behavior
in the pre-war period. Recently, Hensler (1998) employed the Markov
chain model to test for random walk behavior of 1,932 U.S. initial
public offerings. Hensler's results indicated that U.S. IPO excess
returns do not follow a random walk process and he provides evidence on
the existence of a second-order Markov chain. Our analysis closely
resembles that of Hensler (1998) except that we examine IPOs on the
Istanbul Stock Exchange (ISE).
The data used in this study are monthly excess returns of companies
offered to the public for the first time on the ISE and cover the period
from January 1990 to August 1999. The underlying stock prices are
obtained from Analiz.com. (3) Over the 1990-1999 periods, 209 IPOs are
identified based on information made available from the ISE. For twenty
of the IPOs, complete price series were not available, thus, the number
of IPOs included in the analysis is 189. Table 1 reports the
distribution of IPOs and the number of observations per year. The fewest
number of IPOs is 9 and occurred in 1992, while 1991 saw the most IPOs
at 35. (4)
Daily return series ([R.sub.d]) are computed for the IPOs as well
as for the National 100 index, our measure of the Turkish market, in the
following way:
[R.sub.d] = [P.sub.d]/[P.sub.d-1] - 1 (1)
[P.sub.d] denotes the closing price on day d. (5) Compounded
monthly returns ([R.sub.t]) are given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
where n is the number of days the return is compounded in month t.
Monthly excess returns ([ER.sub.t]) are the arithmetic difference
between monthly returns and the market return ([R.sup.m]), thus: (6)
[ER.sub.t] = [R.sub.t] - [R.sup.m.sub.t] (3)
Figure 1 plots monthly cumulative excess returns for the 189 IPOs
over the six-year period. (7) First, note that short-run cumulative
excess returns are negative. After 10 months, however, there is a period
in which cumulative excess returns fluctuate from positive to negative,
until about month 30. At that time, cumulative excess returns trend
upward in positive territory well out into the 6th year and beyond.
Figure 1 indicates that IPOs on the Istanbul Stock Exchange generate
positive market-adjusted returns over a long-run horizon. This
observation of long-run overperformance is contrary to the
well-documented phenomenon of long-term IPO underperformance found in
many other equity markets. The use of market returns to calibrate nominal returns could result in more positive excess return counts than
what might occur from using a more risky benchmark, assuming the stocks
in the National 100 index are relatively more established and less risky
than a portfolio comprised of IPO stocks. Thus, the number of positive
counts may be biased upward and this should be taken into account when
interpreting Figure 1 and our results. However, a relatively small
number of stocks on the ISE does not allow us to develop a benchmark
that would appropriately control other factors such as industry, capital
structure, size, etc. We choose to focus on the National 100 index as
the benchmark, in part, because of these difficulties and also because,
for an emerging market such as the ISE, it is not clear exactly what
constitutes an appropriate benchmark for IPOs. However, for comparison
purposes, we examine the behavior of excess returns using various
benchmarks and report those findings in the conclusions.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Of interest is the determination of whether or not this longer-term
overperformance of initial public offerings on the Istanbul Stock
Exchange is predictable. Moreover, if the excess returns form a
predictable pattern, then we are also interested in whether or not it is
possible for a market participant to establish a trading strategy that
will provide meaningful financial gains based on this information.
As explained by Hensler (1998), the Markov chain model has two
distinct advantages over standard regression models. First,
non-linearity can be handled since the transition probabilities can take
different values in a stage or from one stage to another, depending on
the previous stages. Second, normally distributed return behavior is not
a requirement. Moreover, since non-linearity is allowed, the Markov
chain model is capable of dealing with mean reverting behavior that is
due to fads and/or rational speculative bubbles [McQueen and Thorley
(1991)]. The ensuing discussion is based in large part on that of
Hensler (1998).
The transition probabilities across the stages of the Markov chain
provide information as to the predictability of the series under the
assumption that the series are Markov chain stationary, which is, they
have constant transition probabilities over time. Equal transition
probabilities are indicative of a random walk process while transition
probabilities that are not equal suggest a violation of the random walk
hypothesis. To conduct the test, [X.sub.t] is defined as:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
Excess returns are classified as either negative (N) or positive
(P) and there are T excess returns. The probability of obtaining a
negative return in the period after a positive return is defined as
[[lambda].sub.p], and the probability of obtaining a negative return in
the period after a negative return is defined as [[lambda].sub.N]. (8)
Formally, we have:
[[lambda].sub.P] = Pr[[X.sub.t] = N|[X.sub.t-1] = P]
[[lambda].sub.N] = Pr[[X.sub.t] = N|[X.sub.t-1] = N] (5)
The number of negative observations after a negative (positive)
return is denoted by [N.sub.N] ([N.sub.p]). The log likelihood function
employed to estimate the parameters of the model, [[LAMBDA].sub.1], =
[[[lambda].sub.p] [[lambda].sub.N]], is given by: (9)
[L.sub.1]([S.sub.t1], [[LAMBDA]'.sub.1], [[PI].sub.1]) = log
[[PI].sub.1] + [P.summation over (i=N)] [N.sub.i] log [[lambda].sub.i] +
[P.sub.i] log(1-[[lambda].sub.i]) (6)
[S.sub.t1] are the observed excess returns defined in [X.sub.t].
The subscript 1 indicates the first order Markov chain. Thus, the
maximum likelihood estimates are:
[[lambda].sub.i] = [N.sub.i]/([N.sub.i] + [P.sub.i]) (7)
S[E.sub.i] =([[lambda].sub.i](1 - [[lambda].sub.i])[([N.sub.i] +
[P.sub.i])).sup.0.5] (8)
where S[E.sub.i] is the standard error of [[lambda].sub.i]. The
test for equality of the probabilities is equivalent to testing for
random walk behavior in the excess returns. If the transition
probabilities are equal, then a random walk process exists and the
series does not follow a first-order Markov process.
The procedure for determining whether or not IPO excess returns are
predictable proceeds by examining several key hypotheses designed to
detect random walk behavior. (10) The first hypothesis tests to see if
the transition probabilities are equal and is given by:
H1: [[lambda].sub.p] = [[lambda].sub.N]
According to Hensler (1998), failure to reject H1 is consistent
with there being no Markov chain, while rejection of H1 implies that a
Markov chain may exist. In our analysis, if H1 is rejected then we will
proceed to the next step (i.e., stage 2) which can help to shed light as
to the existence of a Markov chain. The following probabilities are
defined:
[[lambda].sub.PP] = Pr[[X.sub.t] = N|[X.sub.t-2] = P, [X.sub.t-1] =
P]
[[lambda].sub.PN] = Pr[[X.sub.t] = N|[X.sub.t-2] = P, [X.sub.t-1] =
N]
[[lambda].sub.NP] = Pr[[X.sub.t] = N|[X.sub.t-2] = N, [X.sub.t-1] =
P]
[[lambda].sub.NN] = Pr[[X.sub.t] = N|[X.sub.t-2] = N, [X.sub.t-1] =
P] (9)
The associated log likelihood function, ML estimates for
[[lambda].sub.ij], and S[E.sub.ij] are:
[L.sub.2]([S.sub.t2], [[LAMBDA]'.sub.2], [[PI].sub.2]) = log
[[PI].sub.2] + [PP.summation over (ij=NN)] [N.sub.ij] log
[[lambda].sub.ij] + [P.sub.ij] log(1 - [[lambda].sub.ij]) (10)
where [S.sub.t2] are the realized positive and negative excess
returns. The subscript 2 indicates the second order Markov chain.
[[lambda].sub.ij] = [N.sub.ij]/([N.sub.ij] + [P.sub.ij]) (11)
[[SE].sub.ij] = ([[lambda].sub.ij] (1-
[[lambda].sub.ij])/[([N.sub.ij] + [P.sub.ij])).sup.0.5] (12)
The hypothesis used to test for the presence of a second-order
Markov chain is:
H2 : [[lambda].sub.PP] = [[lambda].sub.NP] and [[lambda].sub.PN] =
[[lambda].sub.NN]
If H2 is not rejected (and H1 is rejected), the presence of a
first-order Markov chain will be concluded. In addition, a third
hypothesis can be employed to analyze the probabilities of all four
different states.
H3: [[lambda].sub.PP] = [[lambda].sub.NP] = [[lambda].sub.PN] =
[[lambda].sub.NN]
Failure to reject H3 indicates that the probability of a negative
return does not depend on the past two months' excess return
sequence. Hypotheses H1 through H3 are tested via the following
likelihood ratio test (LR):
LR = 2[[L.sub.U] - [L.sub.R] ~ [[chi].sup.2.sub.q] (13)
where [L.sub.U] is the log likelihood function for the unrestricted
model and [L.sub.R] is the log likelihood function for the restricted
model. (11)
In order to compare the results of HI-H3 and to analyze the
economic significance of returns, conditional on there being a
predictable pattern, four additional hypothesis tests are employed. The
first of these (H4) looks to see if the average excess return following
a positive return is similar to the average excess return following a
negative return.
H4: [R.sub.P] = [R.sub.N]
where [R.sub.i] (i=P, N) denotes the mean excess return conditional
on observing a positive/negative excess return in the previous month.
The following hypotheses investigate the average returns conditioned on
the previous two excess returns:
H5: [R.sub.PP] = [R.sub.NN] = [R.sub.PN] = [R.sub.NP]
H6: [R.sub.PP] = [R.sub.NP] and
H7: [R.sub.PN] = [R.sub.NN]
where [R.sub.PN] is the average of the excess returns following a
positive return in a month and then a negative return in the next month.
[R.sub.PP], [R.sub.NN], and [R.sub.NP] are similarly defined. Thus,
H5-H7 provide insight as to the significance of the information
contained about the returns in the Markov chain process and allow us to
make inference about possible trading strategies.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The first step of the analysis tests to see if the first stage
transition probabilities ([[lambda].sub.N], [[lambda].sub.P]) are equal.
(12) Maximum likelihood (ML) estimates for [[lambda].sub.N] and
[[lambda].sub.P] are presented in the first two columns of Panel A in
Table 2 and are found to be 56% and 58%, respectively. The result of
testing HI (i.e., [[lambda].sub.N] = [[lambda].sub.P]) is shown in the
first column of Panel B in Table 2. The likelihood ratio statistic
indicates that the probability of encountering a negative excess return
after a negative excess return ([[lambda].sub.N]) and the probability of
encountering a negative excess return after a positive excess return
([[lambda].sub.P]) are not the same (LR = 4.04, probability level =
0.05). Thus, we reject HI and conclude that the excess return series do
not follow a random walk. This result suggests that a predictable
pattern of excess returns may exist.
Table 2 also summarizes information regarding the second stage
transition probabilities. Columns 3-6 of Panel A present the maximum
likelihood estimates for [[lambda].sub.NN], [[lambda].sub.PP],
[[lambda].sub.PN] and [[lambda].sub.NP]. These probabilities are found
to be 55%, 58%, 56%, and 58%, respectively. (13) The two likelihood
ratio statistics for testing the second hypothesis (H2),
[[lambda].sub.PP] = [[lambda].sub.NP] and also that [[lambda].sub.PN] =
[[lambda].sub.NN], are insignificant (see columns 2 and 3 of Panel B
where LR = 0.123 and LR = 0.187 with actual probability values of 0.726
and 0.665, respectively). These findings imply that excess returns are
not predictable conditioned on the previous two excess returns. We
therefore conclude that a second-order Markov chain does not exist. This
finding provides information as to how returns behave over the six-year
time horizon.
The last column of Panel B in Table 2 presents the result from
testing the third hypothesis that the four second stage probabilities
are equal, H3: [[lambda].sub.PP] = [[lambda].sub.NP] = [[lambda].sub.PN]
= [[lambda].sub.NN]. The likelihood ratio statistic is insignificant (LR
= 5.512 with a probability value of 0.138). Thus, the previous two
excess returns provide no statistically useful information as to the
predictability of the next excess return. Therefore, we conclude that
the probability of a negative excess return is independent of the
sequence of the excess returns in the previous two months.
We now turn our attention to the examination of transition
probabilities over time. Table 3 reports the transition probabilities on
a year-by-year basis for the first and second stages. Panel A of Table 3
presents the transition probability estimates by year. Hypothesis tests
based on these estimates are shown in Panel B. Based on results from
likelihood ratio tests, we find that the transition probabilities for
the first stage ([[lambda].sub.N], [[lambda].sub.P]) are statistically
different only in the fourth year (LR = 5.36, probability value = 0.02).
The results for examining the second stage probabilities over time are
also reported in Panel B. We find that the second stage transition
probabilities are not statistically different in any of the six years
with only one exception, that is, [[lambda].sub.PN] and
[[lambda].sub.NN] appear to statistically differ in the sixth year (LR =
5.46, probability value = 0.02). The joint hypothesis of the equality of
the four second-stage probabilities is not rejected for each of the six
years (see the row marked H3). Overall, we find no clear indication of a
predictable pattern over time for IPO excess returns conditioned on one
previous excess return, nor is there a pattern for excess returns
conditioned on two previous excess returns.
The above findings regarding transition probabilities over time
suggest that it may be difficult for financial market participants to
reap financial gains based on trading strategies that attempt to exploit
the predictable nature of IPOs. Of course, the success of such a trading
strategy will depend on the size of the excess returns themselves,
provided these excess returns are predictable. Here we make the
distinction between statistical significance and economic significance.
The latter term is meant to convey the idea that even (nearly perfect)
predictable patterns in equity returns must be associated with excess
returns that are large enough to be economically meaningful since,
ultimately, the investor faces some transactions costs, fees, etc. In
order to explore the possibility that an investor may successfully
implement a trading strategy based on information extracted from the
transition probabilities, we conclude our study of IPO excess returns by
focusing on the average excess return (i.e., size) conditional on the
type of excess return (positive/negative) observed in the previous
month(s). For this purpose we conduct analysis of variance (ANOVA) tests
of excess returns, the results of which are presented in Table 4. (14)
The result reported in the first row of Panel A, Table 4 shows that
excess returns conditioned on one period of previous excess return do
not differ statistically (t = -0.611, probability value = 0.541). Thus,
there appears to be no difference in the size of these excess returns.
The findings in Panel A also indicate that we cannot reject H5 nor H7.
Thus, [R.sub.ij] do not differ for any of the ij combinations (F = 1.44,
probability value = 0.229). Furthermore, the means of [R.sub.NN] and
[R[R.sub.PN] are not found to be statistically different (F = 0.57,
probability value = 0.449). However, we reject the null hypothesis that
[R.sub.NP] and [R.sub.PP] are equal only at the 10% level (F = 3.22,
probability value = 0.07). The latter finding provides weak evidence
that the size of excess returns conditional on two previous returns may
differ, provided a particular pattern has been observed.
Panel B of Table 4 shows the ANOVA results for looking at average
returns on a year-by-year basis, both for the first stage and the second
stage. Generally speaking, these results are consistent with those
presented in the first row of Panel B in Table 3 for the first stage
transition probabilities, and show that excess returns conditioned on
one previous return do not statistically differ in any of the six years.
Finally, Panel B, Table 4 also provides the associated F-statistics
for testing H5, H6, and H7. These (second stage) hypotheses are not
rejected for each of the six years, with the exceptions of H5 and H7
where [R.sub.NN] and [R.sub.PN] are found to statistically differ in the
sixth year (F = 3.06 with p-value = 0.028 and F = 7.71 with p-value =
0.006, respectively). Thus, even if a predictable pattern can be
detected, the differences in excess returns are probably not large
enough for an investor to successfully profit on.
V. CONCLUSION
The results reported in this paper provide some evidence that
excess returns of initial public offerings on the Istanbul Stock
Exchange may be predictable conditioned on one previous return, although
this is not generally supported by the analysis of transition
probabilities over time. Specifically, we use a non-linear estimation
technique and find weak evidence to suggest that these excess returns
follow a first-order Markov chain. However, there is no strong
indication that a second-order Markov chain exists, although the
analyses suggested the presence of predictable patterns in excess
returns for some specific years following issuance.
In all but one of the cases examined we are unable to detect both a
predictable pattern and statistically different excess returns. For
instance, the likelihood ratio test of the first hypothesis (H1:
[[lambda].sub.N] = [[lambda].sub.P]) for the fourth year after issuance
indicates a predictable pattern based on transition probabilities;
however, the associated excess returns, [R.sub.N] and [R.sub.P], are not
statistically different in that same year. Thus, while initial public
offerings on the Istanbul Stock Exchange overperformed the market during
the six years after the issuance date, an investor may not realize
financial gains from the predictable nature of IPO excess returns since
any differences in excess returns appear to be minor.
For comparison purposes, we repeated the tests presented in this
paper using two different benchmarks. First, we employed a narrowly
defined portfolio that is likely to exhibit the general return
characteristics of IPOs in our sample. Second, we employed a broadly
defined benchmark to overcome the (possible) independence issues that
may be present since the National 100 index may include a number of IPO
firms in the sample over time. The narrowly defined benchmark was
constructed using the average returns of nineteen IPOs that had been
traded before 1991. With regards to both the first-order and
second-order Markov chain, no predictable pattern emerged. To construct
the broadly defined benchmark, we used the Morgan Stanley MSCI Europe
and Middle East Emerging Market Index, the use of which should remove
any independencies that may be present when the National 100 index is
used as a benchmark. In testing for the first-order Markov chain, the
returns were not predictable at the 5% level of significance; however,
consistent with the results presented in the paper there is predictable
return behavior in the overall sample at the 10% level of significance.
Furthermore, the results suggested the possible presence of a
second-order Markov chain.
As a further test of the predictability hypotheses, we also
investigated privatization IPOs. In particular, we re-ran the analyses
for 19 privatization IPOs on the ISE. The results provided no evidence
of a first-order Markov chain and there was no indication of the
presence of a second-order Markov chain. We then conducted the analyses
on the entire sample excluding the 19 privatization IPOs. The results of
the tests were the same as the results presented in the paper. (15)
Thus, this provides evidence that our previously reported conclusions
regarding the first-order Markov chain are robust and are not affected
by privatization IPOs.
One interpretation of the lack of any overriding indication that
monthly excess returns are predictable is that the ISE is a small market
in which a few large investors may be able to significantly influence
return behavior. In fact, according to the Capital Market Board of
Turkey, the average daily traded value did not exceed $100 million (U.S.
dollars) until 1995. It is possible that private information on the part
of large investors may be responsible for unpredictable return behavior.
It is interesting to note; however, that Ozun (1999) suggests that the
ISE has experienced significant improvements in very recent years
towards efficiency. Finally, it may be the case that market deepening has affected the market. For example, the daily average traded value in
US dollars on the ISE more than doubled between 1994 and 1995 going from
$92 million to $209 million. The effect of market deepening can be
analyzed by examining plots of the probabilities corresponding to H1 and
H2 over (calendar) time. Doing so for the first-order Markov chain, we
found that there are only three years in which IPO returns were
predictable at the 5% probability value (1990, 1998, and 1999). No
predictable behavior is present in the other years. This fording does
not suggest that market deepening was a major factor for IPO returns.
With regards to the second-order Markov chain, the results were
consistent with the results already presented. Thus, further research on
the Turkish IPO market may be directed at determining if the return
behavior detected in this paper holds into the future.
APPENDIX 1
Transition count matrix
A negative monthly excess return is denoted by N and a positive
monthly excess return is denoted by P. Stage 1 transition counts in
first two rows for negative (positive) excess returns after observing
i in the previous stage are [N.sub.i] ([P.sub.i]). Stage 2 transition
counts in last four rows for negative (positive) excess returns after
observing i in two previous stages then observing j in one previous
stage are [N.sub.ij] ([P.sub.ij]).
Next State
Previous State N P
P 2313 1680
N 2950 2333
PP 968 691
PN 1280 1007
NP 1302 951
NN 1599 1289
APPENDIX 2
Average excess returns
A negative excess return is denoted by N and a positive excess return
is denoted by P. For Stage 1, estimated mean excess return conditional
on observing i in the previous month is [R.sub.i]. For Stage 2,
estimated mean excess return conditional on observing i in two
previous stage then observing j in one previous stage is [R.sub.ij].
Panel A: Summary statistics for excess returns
Stage 1 Stage 2 [R.sub.N] [R.sub.P]
unconditional unconditional
Mean 0.004 0.004 0.005 0.002
Standard 0.238 0.238 0.226 0.254
deviation
# of obs. 9276 9087 5283 3993
[R.sub.NN] [R.sub.NP] [R.sub.PP] [R.sub.PN]
Mean 0.008 0.008 -0.006 0.003
Standard 0.220 0.247 0.263 0.230
deviation
# of obs. 2888 2253 1659 2287
Panel B: Average excess returns on a year-by-year basis
Year
1 2 3
[R.sub.N] 0.009 -0.007 0.009
(0.250) (0.217) (0.230)
[R.sub.P] 0.002 -0.006 0.011
(0.234) (0.254) (0.290)
[R.sub.NN] 0.013 -0.009 0.008
(0.219) (0.215) (0.231)
[R.sub.PP] -0.004 -0.013 0.015
(0.256) (0.261) (0.322)
[R.sub.PN] 0.009 -0.006 0.010
(0.273) (0.228) (0.230)
[R.sub.NP] 0.012 -0.009 0.007
(0.231) (0.230) (0.266)
Year
4 5 6
[R.sub.N] 0.009 0.009 0.006
(0.222) (0.214) (0.196)
[R.sub.P] 0.001 0.008 0.002
(0.252) (0.251) (0.238)
[R.sub.NN] 0.009 0.010 0.029
(0.227) (0.228) (0.220)
[R.sub.PP] -0.014 -0.01 -0.013
(0.242) (0.235) (0.234)
[R.sub.PN] 0.010 0.008 -0.023
(0.217) (0.195) (0.196)
[R.sub.NP] 0.011 0.021 0.013
(0.259) (0.262) (0.241)
Notes: The first column in Panel A presents information regarding the
unconditional mean and standard deviation, the remaining columns are
conditional means and standard deviations. Standard deviations of the
year-by-year returns are in parentheses.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
We would like to thank an anonymous reviewer and Celali Yihnaz of
the Enforcement Department, Capital Market Board of Turkey for valuable
assistance, as well as participants in the Department of Finance
workshop at Texas Tech University. We especially appreciate comments
from Ramesh Rao and Steve Sears. The usual disclaimer applies.
REFERENCES
Aggarwal, R, R. Leal and L. Hernandez, 1993, The Aftermarket
Performance of Initial Public Offerings in Latin America, Financial
Management, 22 (1), 42-53.
Aggarwal, R. and Rivoli, P., 1990, Fads in the Initial Public
Offering Market, Financial Management, 19 (4),45-57.
Brav, A. and P. A. Gompers, 1997, Myth or Reality? The Long-Run
Underperformance of Initial Public Offerings: Evidence from Venture and
Nonventure Capital Backed Companies, Journal of Finance, 52, 1791-1821.
Carter, R. B., F. H. Dark, and A. K. Singh, 1998, Underwriter Reputation, Initial Returns, and the Long-Run Performance of IPO Stocks,
Journal of Finance, 53(1), 285-311.
Engle, R F. and J. D. Hamilton, 1990, Long Swings in the Dollar:
Are They in the Data and Do Markets Know It? American Economic Review,
80, 689-713.
Hensler, D. A., 1998, The Nature and Persistence of Initial Public
Offering Aftermarket Returns Predictability, Review of Quantitative
Finance and Accounting, 10, 39-58.
Hensler, D. A., M. J. Herrera, and L. J. Lockwood, 2000, The
Performance of Initial Public Offerings in the Mexican Stock Market,
1987-1993, Journal of International Money and Finance, 19, 93-116.
Houge, T. and T. Loughran, 1999, Growth Fixation and the
Performance of Bank Initial Public Offerings, 1983-1991, Journal of
Banking and Finance, 23 (8), 1277-1301.
Kandel, S., O. Sarig, and A. Wohl, 1999 The Demand for Stocks: An
Analysis of IPO Auctions, Review of Financial Studies, 12 (2), 227-247.
Kang, J. C., 1995, Fixed-Price Offering, Discriminatory Allocation,
and IPO Underpricing, Research in Finance, 10, 161-183.
Khan, W. A. and H. Kiymaz, 1998, The Istanbul Stock Exchange: An
Examination of Stock Price Behavior, Journal of Emerging Markets, 3 (3),
115-131.
Krigman, L., W. H. Shaw, and K. L. Womack, 1999, The Persistence of
IPO Mispricing and the Predictive Power of Flipping, Journal of Finance,
54 (3), 1015-1044.
Kunz, R. M. and R Aggarwal, 1994, Why Initial Public Offerings are
Underpriced: Evidence from Switzerland, Journal of Banking and Finance,
18 (4), 705-723.
Lee, P. J., S. L. Taylor, and T. S. Walter, 1999) IPO Underpricing
Explanations: Implications from Investor Application and Allocation
Schedules, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 34 (4),
425-444.
Levis, M., 1993, The Long-Run Performance of Initial Public
Offerings: The UK Experience, Financial Management, 22 (1), 28-41.
Loughran, T., 1993, NYSE vs. NASDAQ Returns: Market Microstructure or the Poor Performance of Initial Public Offerings? Journal of
Financial Economics; 33, 241-260.
McQueen, G. and S. Thorley, 1991, Are Stock Returns Predictable? A
Test Using Markov Chains, Journal of Finance, 46 (1), 239-263.
Mills, T. C., 1999, The Econometric Modeling of Financial Time
Series, 2nd edition, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, United
Kingdom.
Ozun, A., 1999, Chaos Theory, Non-linear Behavior in Stock Returns,
Thin Trading and Market Efficiency in Emerging Markets: The Case of the
Istanbul Stock Exchange, ISE Review, 3 (9).
Rajan, R. and H. Servaes, 1997, Analyst Following of Initial Public
Offerings, Journal Of Finance, 52 (2), 507-529.
Ritter, J. R., 1991, The Long-Run Performance of Initial Public
Offerings, Journal of Finance, 46 (1), 3-48.
Zychowicz, E. J., M. Binbasioglu, and N. Kazancioglu, Nebil, 1995,
The Behavior of Prices on the Istanbul Stock Exchange, Journal
ofInternational Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 5 (4), 61-71.
NOTES
(1.) Aggarwal and Rivoli (1990) attribute some of the initial
overpricing of initial public offerings to fads and the overly
optimistic behavior of investors.
(2.) The research on IPOs is immense and too many important papers
have been published to list them all here. Recent work on IPOs includes
papers by Brav and Gompers (1997), Rajan and Servaes (1997), Carter,
Dark, and Singh (1998), Houge and Loughran (1999), Kandel, Sarig, and
Wohl (1999), Krigman, Shaw, and Womack (1999), and Lee, Taylor, and
Walter (1999), to name just a few. However, in this section we report
only the papers that are most related to the present study.
(3.) The price series reported by Analiz.com are adjusted for past
stock splits and dividends so as to obtain consistent and comparable
price series.
(4.) Three IPOs were actually offered in 1998 but are listed on ISE
for the first time in 1999, and are thus counted as 1999 IPOs.
(5.) Since [P.sub.d] incorporates stock splits and dividends, no
additional adjustments are required.
(6.) The empirical analysis begins with the second full month of
trading as this helps to ensure more stable series and also avoids any
possible effects of underwriter efforts. See Hensler (1998) for a more
detailed explanation.
(7.) The definition of excess returns, as used here, may not fully
capture the measurement of risk given that IPOs lack a history. However,
the measure does show how IPO returns compare to the return on the
National 100 index and this is likely to be important to financial
market participants. The distribution of delistings by type, e.g.,
between firm failure or acquisition, may affect the (average cumulative)
excess returns and Figure 1 may suffer from survivorship bias. Given the
absence of information available on type and number of de-listings,
these effects are not addressed in this paper.
(8.) The focus on conditional probabilities of negative excess
returns follows that of Hensler (1998). One could choose to instead
focus on conditional probabilities of positive excess returns without
loss of generality; however, the interpretation would change
accordingly.
(9.) McQueen and Thorley (1991) note that, in practice, [PI]1 may
be ignored since its effect on the transition probabilities is
negligible.
(10.) For a detailed explanation of these hypotheses see Hensler
(1998).
(11.) The LR statistic is distributed asymptotically as
[[chi].sub.q.sup.2] with q degrees of freedom (i.e., there are q
restrictions).
(12.) The transition counts for both the first and second stages
are shown in the Appendix 1.
(13.) Given these probabilities, an explanation for positive
cumulative excess returns over time (see Figure 1) is that the relative
size of positive excess returns exceeds that of negative excess returns.
This conclusion is consistent with the evidence presented in Appendix 2
as most of the average excess returns appear to be positive regardless
of the previous state(s).
(14.) Summary statistics for excess returns, including on a
year-by-year basis, are presented in Appendix 2.
(15.) In the interest of brevity, we do not report tables of these
additional results. However, the results of the analyses are available
upon request.
Bradley T. Ewing (a)
Ozkan Ozfidan (b)
(a) Associate Professor of Economics, Texas Tech University
(b) Economist, Virginia Department of Planning and Budget
Table 1
Summary information for initial public offerings on the Istanbul Stock
Exchange
Stage 1 Data Stage 2 Data
One Previous Return Two Previous Returns
Year Firms Observations Firms Observations
1990 14 994 14 980
1991 35 2,485 35 2,450
1992 9 639 9 630
1993 11 775 11 764
1994 17 1,087 17 1,070
1995 34 1,717 34 1,683
1996 19 718 19 699
1997 21 498 21 477
1998 26 351 26 325
1999 3 12 2 9
Total 189 9,276 188 9,087
Notes: IPOs were issued between January 1990 and August 1999.
Observation counts do not necessarily reflect a full six years of
trading for all firms in the sample since more recently issued IPOs
do not have a full six years of trading on the ISE.
Table 2
Stage 1 and 2 transitions probabilities and tests of hypotheses
Log likelihood function for Stage 1 is [P.summation over (i=N)]
[N.sub.i] log [[lambda].sub.i] + [P.sub.i] log(1 - [[lambda].sub.i]).
A negative excess return is denoted by N and a positive excess return
is denoted by P. The number of counts for negative (positive) excess
returns after observing i in the previous stage is [N.sub.i]
([P.sub.i]). Estimated probability of obtaining a negative excess
return following i is [[lambda].sub.i]. Similarly, log likelihood
function for Stage 2 is [PP.summation over (ij=NN)] [N.sub.ij] log
[[lambda].sub.ij] + [P.sub.ij] log (1 - [[lambda].sub.ij]). The number
of counts for negative (positive) excess returns after observing i in
two previous stages then observing j in one previous stage is
[N.sub.ij] ([P.sub.ij]). Estimated probability of obtaining a negative
excess return following associated ij sequence is [[lambda].sub.ij].
Panel A: Maximum likelihood estimates and standard errors of
transition probabilities
[[lambda].sub.N] [[lambda].sub.P] [[lambda].sub.NN]
0.5584 0.5793 0.5537
(0.0068) (0.0078) (0.0093)
[[lambda].sub.PP] [[lambda].sub.PN] [[lambda].sub.NP]
0.5835 0.5597 0.5779
(0.0121) (0.0104) (0.0104)
Panel B: Hypothesis tests
H1: [[lambda].sub.N]= H2: [[lambda].sub.PP=
[[lambda].sub.p] [[lambda].sub.NP]
4.037 0.123
[0.045] [0.726]
H2: [[lambda].sub.PN]= H3: [[lambda].sub.PP]=
[[lambda].sub.NN] [[lambda].sub.NP]=
[[lambda].sub.PN]=
[[lambda].sub.NN]
0.187 5.512
[0.665] [0.138]
Notes: Standard error is given in parentheses in Panel A. Panel B
reports the likelihood ratio statistic (LR) for testing the null
hypothesis and actual significance level for the test is given in
square brackets. The LR statistic is distributed [chi square] with q
degree of freedom.
Table 3
Year-by-year analysis of transition probabilities
A negative excess return is denoted by N and a positive excess return
is denoted by P. For Stage 1, estimated probability of obtaining a
negative excess return following i is [[lambda].sub.i]. For Stage 2,
estimated probability of obtaining a negative excess return after
observing i in two previous stage then observing j in one previous
stage is [[lambda].sub.ij].
Panel A: Maximum likelihood estimates of transition probabilities
by year
Year
1 2 3
[[lambda].sub.N] 0.556 0.564 0.567
(0.0l5) (0.0l5) (0.0l6)
[[lambda].sub.P] 0.546 0.581 0.589
(0.0l7) (0.0l7) (0.0l8)
[[lambda].sub.NN] 0.561 0.560 0.565
(0.020) (0.02l) (0.02l)
[[lambda].sub.PP] 0.557 0.585 0.577
(0.024) (0.027) (0.029)
[[lambda].sub.PN] 0.526 0.572 0.569
(0.022) (0.023) (0.024)
[[[lambda].sub.NP] 0.534 0.590 0.597
(0.022) (0.023) (0.024)
Year
4 5 6
[[lambda].sub.N] 0.540 0.555 0.570
(0.0l7) (0.0l9) (0.022)
[[lambda].sub.P] 0.600 0.602 0.573
(0.0l9) (0.022) (0.025)
[[lambda].sub.NN] 0.539 0.555 0.527
(0.023) (0.026) (0.029)
[[lambda].sub.PP] 0.602 0.624 0.579
(0.03l) (0.033) (0.039)
[[lambda].sub.PN] 0.540 0.556 0.628
(0.025) (0.029) (0.032)
[[[lambda].sub.NP] 0.598 0.587 0.570
(0.025) (0.029) (0.033)
Panel B: Hypothesis tests
Year
1 2 3
Hl: [[lambda].sub.N]= 0.225 0.603 0.814
[[lambda].sub.P] [0.635] [0.437] [0.367]
# of stage 1 observations 2049 1980 1691
H2: [[lambda].sub.PP]= 0.472 0.021 0.294
[[lambda].sub.NP] [0.492] [0.884] [0.588]
H2: [[lambda].sub.PN]= 1.315 0.145 0.020
[[lambda].sub.NN] [0.252] [0.703] [0.887]
H3: [[lambda].sub.PP]= 1.788 1.074 1.128
[[lambda].sub.NP]= [0.618] [0.783] [0.770]
[[lambda].sub.PN]=
[[lambda].sub.NN]
# of stage 2 observations 2035 1805 1691
Year
4 5 6
Hl: [[lambda].sub.N]= 5.359 2.560 0.008
[[lambda].sub.P] [0.021] [0.110] [0.929]
# of stage 1 observations 1496 1152 908
H2: [[lambda].sub.PP]= 0.013 0.699 0.031
[[lambda].sub.NP] [0.911] [0.403] [0.859]
H2: [[lambda].sub.PN]= 0.001 0.002 5.461
[[lambda].sub.NN] [0.974] [0.966] [0.019]
H3: [[lambda].sub.PP]= 5.373 3.261 5.501
[[lambda].sub.NP]= [0.146] [0.353] [0.139]
[[lambda].sub.PN]=
[[lambda].sub.NN]
# of stage 2 observations 1496 1152 908
Notes: In Panel A the standard errors of ML estimates are in
parentheses. In Panel B the actual probability values associated with
the LR test statistics are in square brackets.
Table 4
ANOVA of average excess returns
A negative excess return is denoted by N and a positive excess return
is denoted by P. For Stage 1, estimated mean excess return conditional
on observing i in the previous month is [R.sub.i]. For Stage 2,
estimated mean excess return conditional on observing i in two
previous stage then observing j in one previous stage is [R.sub.ij].
Panel A: Average excess returns
Test
statistic
H4: [R.sub.N]=[R.sub.P] -0.611
[0.5411
H5: [R.sub.PP]=[R.sub.NN]=[R.sub.PN]=[R.sub.NP 1.440
[0.229]
H6: [R.sub.NP]=[R.sub.PP] 3.220
[0.073]
H7: [R.sub.NN]=[R.sub.PN] 0.573
[0.449]
Panel B: Average excess returns on a year-by-year basis
Year
1 2 3
H4: [R.sub.N]=[R.sub.P] -0.662 0.066 0.145
[0.508] [0.948] [0.885]
# of stage 1 observations 2049 1980 1691
H5: [R.sub.PP]=[R.sub.NN] 0.470 0.070 0.070
=[R.sub.PN]=[R.sub.NP] [0.701] [0.977] [0.974]
H6: [R.sub.NP]=[R.sub.PP] 0.973 0.078 0.180
[0.324] [0.779] [0.672]
H7: [R.sub.NN]=[R.sub.PN] 0.059 0.052 0.023
[0.808] [0.820] [0.879]
# of stage 2 observations 2035 1805 1691
Year
4 5 6
H4: [R.sub.N]=[R.sub.P] -0.666 -0.104 -0.28
[0.505] [0.918] [0.779]
# of stage 1 observations 1496 1152 908
H5: [R.sub.PP]=[R.sub.NN] 0.770 0.730 3.060
=[R.sub.PN]=[R.sub.NP] [0.511] [0.537] [0.028]
H6: [R.sub.NP]=[R.sub.PP] 1.863 2.154 1.382
[0.172] [0.142] [0.240]
H7: [R.sub.NN]=[R.sub.PN] 0.002 0.010 7.708
[0.963] [0.919] [0.006]
# of stage 2 observations 1496 1152 908
Notes: The test statistic for H4 is a t-statistic, all others are F
statistics. The test statistics for the hypothesis tests are based on
ANOVA. Actual probability value is given in square brackets.