Exchange rate and risk premium conversion on interest rate markets.
Sahut, Jean-Michel ; Mili, Medhi
ABSTRACT
This paper investigates common factors that jointly determine bond
returns across-countries. We study how risk factors deriving bond prices
influences exchange rates and we test if parameters of bond price
process are fundamental in specifying exchange rate process. We use an
arbitrage free international stochastic discount factor (SDF) framework
in order to analyse interaction between bond prices and exchange rate
process. We show that risk premia are different through countries and
exchange rate serve to convert currency-specific risk premia across
countries.
JEL Classification: C33, F31, G12, G15.
Keywords: Term structure; Common factors; Exchange rate; Bond
returns
I. INTRODUCTION
Bond portfolios investors diversify, generally, their portfolio by
investing in foreign bonds. The management of an international bond
portfolio requires a model that evaluates bond prices of different
maturities in diverse countries. Several studies (1) report that
premiums of different countries have, generally, similar evolution,
which imply the existence of a limited number of common factors that
derive the joint yield curve across countries. In order to optimally
diversify their assets, portfolio managers are primarily interested in
mechanisms that influence premiums and the degree of heterogeneity of
premium variations. This involves determination of the number and the
nature of common sources of variation for each bond. Despite their
crucial role in international portfolio management, the covariance between premiums across countries and the number of underlining common
factors are rarely investigated in the theory.
The asset pricing model of Ross (1976) shows that common variation
of asset returns can be expressed as linear function of a number of
factors. But this model doesn't specify the number and the
characteristics of these factors. Despite the ultimate success of this
theory, it appears unable to explain high correlations between bond
yields across the maturity spectrum and across countries and to identify
their common sources of variation.
Solnik (1983) extended the arbitrage pricing theory to an
international framework. He shows that if asset returns, expressed on an
enumerative money, follow a linear factor model, then the expected
return vector are perfectly identified by the principal factor vector.
Ikeda (1991) suggests that direct extension of the asset pricing theory
to an international context is counter intuitive since exchange risk
might induce an additional factor in the arbitrage process on financial
markets. The key element of these advancements is to suppose that the
generation process of returns is specified on an enumerative currency.
Under this precision, exchange risk of assets returns is automatically
diversified when constructing a risk free portfolio.
Our study is related to Knez, Litterman and Scheinkman (1994) and
Litterman and Scheinkman (1991) who estimate a model for short-term US
monetary market returns and long-term USA government bond returns,
respectively. Knez et al. (1994) propose a four-factor model. The first
two factors correspond to movement in the level and the slope of the
term structure, while the other two factors describe credit risk
difference of the different money market instruments. Litterman and
Scheinkman (1991) use the principal compound analysis and show that US
bond returns are mainly determined by three factors, which correspond to
level movement, slope and curvature movement in the term structure.
This paper extends these two studies by jointly analysing bond
returns in four countries, namely the USA, Germany, UK and Japan. The
joint analysis of interest rate term structures is particularly useful
in studying potential international diversification and international
bond portfolios management. In this spirit we model a cross-country
covariance matrix including (1) bond return variance of each country,
(2) covariance of domestic bond returns across maturities, and (3)
covariance of bond return across-countries.
The basic idea we explore here is that there is an important
systemic factor that cuts across a wide spectrum of markets. We apply
the principal compound analysis to determine the number of common
factors that influence risk premiums on international bond markets. This
empirical method also permits us to deduce in which measure
idiosyncratic loading factors affect premiums variations. In this
perspective we test two fundamental hypotheses of the international
asset pricing theory. First, we test if the expected hedged return of an
investor's international portfolio is determined by the factor
prices of risk of the investor's home country or by those of the
country in which he invests. Second, test if exchange rates serve to
convert prices of risk across-countries.
The research methodology we employ is based on the principal
compound analysis and entails two-stage procedure. First, we apply the
principal compound analysis separately to the term structure in the
following countries; the US, Germany, Japan and the UK, in order to
filter principal factors of prices of risk and risk premium relative to
each country. In a second stage, we use principal component analysis on
the unconditional covariance matrix of bond returns of the different
maturities in all countries to estimate the factors that determine these
bond returns.
The rest of the paper is organized as follow. Section II develops
theoretical framework used to model hedged bond returns and describes
the empirical methodology. Section III describes database. In the next
section we estimate principal factors of prices of risk specific to each
country. Section V estimates and interprets a cross-countries bond
return model. We test if exchange rate serves to convert risk premium
between countries. Section VI concludes.
II. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK
Asset Returns provide information about systematic and
idiosyncratic risks. In this section, we extend the international asset
pricing model of Ikeda (1991) into a continuous-time framework. We show
the importance of the arbitrage free hypothesis in pricing international
bond portfolio and we show in what sense the exchange rate can be
considered to convert prices of risks across countries.
A. A linear Factor Model with Exchange Rate Risk
We consider an economy with two countries, a domestic and foreign
country. Each country is characterised by domestic currency and an
exchange rate [E.sub.xg] expressing one unit of foreign currency in
terms of domestic currency. We suppose N risky asset and one riskless
asset traded for each country. We assume that these assets are freely
traded in perfect international financial markets. Denote as
[P.sub.d.sup.i], i={1,..., n}, the price of risky asset i of the
domestic country denominated in domestic currency. Let [P.sub.f.sup.i],
i={1,..., n}, be the price of risky asset i of the foreign country
denominated in foreign currency.
Similarly, we define [P.sub.d.sup.0] and [P.sub.f.sup.0] as the
local currency price of the riskless asset of the domestic and foreign
country, respectively. Local currency is defined as the currency of the
geographical place where the asset is quoted.
Assume that each risky asset i is driven by K international risk
factors (undiversifiable) and one specific risk factor (diversifiable).
The K international factors are generated by K Wiener process [Z.sub.k],
k = {1,...,K} which are independent. The local currency dynamics of the
prices [P.sub.d.sup.i] and [P.sub.f.sup.i] is supposed to be given by
the following equation:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
where d[P.sub.d.sup.i]]/[P.sub.d] is the random local currency
return of asset i and [[mu].sub.d.sup.i] is its instantaneous expected
value. d[Z.sub.k] represents the instantaneous increment of the kth
international risk factor. [b.sub.dk.sup.i] and [b.sub.fk.sup.i] denotes
sensitivity of local and foreign assets to fluctuations of the [Z.sub.k]
factor. [epsilon]d and [epsilon]f are the non-systematic risk component.
The price of risk of theses idiosyncratic risk is zero, and [dZk
[epsilon]d]=0 et E[dZk [epsilon]f]=0. The number of assets is much
larger than the number of international risk factor, i.e. 2N>>K.
Local returns of riskless asset are given by:
d[P.sub.d.sup.0]/[P.sub.d] = [r.sup.d]dt d[P.sub.f.sup.0]/[P.sub.f]
= [r.sup.f]dt (2)
Exchange rate process is given by the following differential
stochastic equation:
dS/S = [[mu].sub.s]dt + [K.summation over
(k=1)][b.sub.Sk]d[Z.sub.k] + d[Z.sub.S] (3)
where [[mu].sub.s]dt is the instantaneous variation of exchange
rate, [b.sub.sk] are the principal factors of exchange rate of the K
international factors and d[Z.sub.s] represents the orthogonal
idiosyncratic factor of risk that derives the K asset prices.
Investor that invests in an international portfolio doesn't
risk only depreciation of the local value of his investment, but he
risks also unfavourable exchange rate evolution when converting the
proceeds of his international investment into domestic currency. To
convert the value of his foreign portfolio into domestic currency he
must multiply it by the spot exchange rate, [[??].sup.i.sub.f] =
S[P.sup.i.sub.f], where [[??].sup.i.sub.f] is the price of risky asset i
of the foreign country measured by domestic investor (in domestic
currency).
From this hypothesis, we deduce the return process of the foreign
asset in domestic currency.
d[[??].sup.i.sub.f]/[[??].sup.i.sub.f] =
d(S[P.sup.i.sub.f])/S[P.sup.i.sub.f] = d[P.sup.i.sub.f]/[P.sup.i.sub.f]
+ dS/S + cov (d[P.sup.i.sub.f]/[P.sup.i.sub.f], dS/S) (4)
where cov(d[P.sup.i.sub.f]/[P.sup.i.sub.f], dS/S) is the
instantaneous covariance between foreign asset return and exchange rate
variation. From this equation we deduce that foreign asset return
measured in domestic currency equal the sum of asset return expressed in
domestic currency, variation of exchange rate and the covariance between
them. The presence of covariance element imply that domestic investor
doesn't convert only the initial amount invested in foreign
currency but also return realised in foreign currency. Through equations
(1), (3) and (4) we show that foreign asset return evaluated in domestic
return depends on the specific factor of risk dZs :
d[[??.sup.i.sub.f]/[P.sub.f] = [[??].sup.i.sub.f]dt + [K.summation
over (k=1)] ([b.sub.fk] + [b.sub.Sk])d[Z.sub.k] + [[epsilon].sub.f] +
d[Z.sub.S] (5)
where [[??].sup.i.sub.f] = [[mu].sup.i.sub.f] + [K.summation over
(k=1)] [b.sup.i.sub.fk] [b.sub.Sk] + [[mu].sub.s]; [[??].sup.i.sub.f] is
the expected value of the foreign asset return expressed in terms of
local currency. Similarly, the foreign riskless asset return measured in
domestic currency is given by:
d[[??].sub.f.sup.0]/[[??].sub.f.sup.0] = [[??].sub.f]dt +
[K.summation over (k=1)][b.sub.Sk]d[Z.sub.k] + d[Z.sub.S]
where [[??].sub.f] = [r.sub.f] + [[mu].sub.s].
In our framework, its impossible to construct a riskless portfolio
through the standard Asset Pricing Theory since shocks of exchange rate
d[Z.sub.s] are systematic, contrary to residual risk [[??].sub.i]. To
study this aspect in methodical ways, we construct a portfolio of 2N
risky assets (2) denoted by [omega]=([[omega].sub.1] ,... ,
[[omega].sub.2N])' where [omega]i are proportion invested in each
asset i.
The portfolio return, [omega], is given by:
[omega]'(d[??]/p) = [omega]'[[??].sup.i.sub.f]dt +
[K.summation over (k=1)] [omega]'([b.sub.k] + [b.sub.Sl])d[Z.sub.k]
+ [omega]'[epsilon] + [omega]'d[Z.sub.S] (6)
[??] = ([[mu].sup.1.sub.d],...,[[mu].sup.N.sub.d],
[[mu].sup.1.sub.f],...,[[mu].sup.N.sub.f])', d[Z.sub.S] =
(0,...,0,d[Z.sub.S],...,d[Z.sub.S])',
where
[b.sub.k] = ([b.sup.1.sub.d],...,[b.sup.N.sub.d],[b.sup.1.sub.f],...,[b.sup.N.sub.f])]', [epsilon] =
([[epsilon].sup.1.sub.d],...,[[epsilon].sup.N.sub.d],
[[epsilon].sup.1.sub.f],..., [[epsilon].sup.N.sub.f]
Exchange risk is eliminated by having short position on riskless
bonds in foreign currency. Weights [[omega].sub.i] are constrained by:
[omega]'[b.sub.k] = 0 k = {1,...,K} [omega]'[epsilon] = 0
(7)
Applying (7) to equation (6) reveals that:
[omega]'(d[??]/[??]) [??] [omega]'[??]dt +
[omega]'d[[??].sub.S] (8)
where d[[??].sub.s] = [K.summation over (k=1)][b.sub.sk]d[Z.sub.k]
+ d[Z.sub.s]
We remark from this equation that international risk and residual
risk (dZk) are diversified. However, constraints of equation (7) do not
lead necessarily to an international risk free portfolio since exchange
rate risk [omega]'dZs is left undiversified. The next subsection involves this problem by considering an arbitrage portfolio hedged
against exchange risk.
B. Arbitrage Pricing of Hedged Portfolio
Portfolio [omega] isn't hedging against exchange risk. This
portfolio hedged against exchange risk by holding short position
[[omega].sub.d] on riskless domestic bonds for each [[omega].sub.d]
invested in domestic asset and [[omega].sub.f] proportion invested in
riskless foreign bond for each [[omega].sub.f] invested in foreign
asset.
Given this hedging strategy, domestic currency return of an
investment in foreign hedged portfolio will be:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (9)
The hedged portfolio return, measured in domestic currency, is
deterministic and hedged against any type of risk. Since investment in
risky assets are totally financed by detention of an opposite position
on domestic bonds, the risk generated by international factors (dZk) and
residual factors ([epsilon]d, [epsilon]f) are diversified and the
investor is hedged against specific exchange risk. However, the value of
hedged portfolio depends on covariance between exchange rate and risky
asset. This is because foreign asset return is not pre-known and in
consequence can't be hedged against unfavourable fluctuations of
exchange rates.
The portfolio return (dP/P) is constituted by domestic and foreign
asset through constrains (7) and after be hedged by short positions on
riskless bonds is given by:
[[d[P.sub.f]/[P.sub.f]].sub.p] = [omega]'([[mu].sup.1]dt +
cov(dP/P,dS/S) + [SIGMA][b.sub.fk]d[Z.sub.k] - rdt) (10)
where [[mu].sup.1] is a 2N-dimensional vector of local expected
rates of return containing N[[mu].sub.d]
and N[[mu].sub.f.sup.*] of domestic and foreign asset; and
cov(dP/P, dS/S) is a 2N-dimension vector:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Since the portfolio does not require any initial investment due to
short position taken on riskless local bonds, its return must be zero to
avoid any arbitrage opportunity.
[omega]'([[mu].sup.1]dt + cov(dP/P, dS/S) = rdt) = 0 (12)
This equation shows that the vector e is also orthogonal to
expected hedged returns vector. Hence, Asset Pricing Theory implies that
the expected hedged return must be a linear combination of factor
loadings [b.sub.k], k = {1,...,K}:
[[mu].sup.1]dt + cov(dP/P, dS/S) = rdt =
[[lambda].sup.d.sub.1][b.sub.d2] + ... +
[[lambda].sup.d.sub.k][b.sub.dk] (13)
We deduce that expected returns in domestic currency, hedged
against exchange risk, are a linear combination of local factor loadings
with weights [[lambda].sup.d.sub.k]. According to the standard asset
pricing theory, weights [[lambda].sup.d.sub.k] are the domestic factor
risk prices.
In other words, there are K risk prices that determine expected
excess return on hedged assets. Each international factor represents
another dimension of systematic risk that cannot be diversified. In
consequence, each risk factor must be remunerated. We note that expected
hedged excess return of domestic and foreign investment will be
determined by the prices of risk of original country of the investor,
[[lambda].sub.k.sup.d], k={1,...,k}. Investor in domestic currency
can't apply foreign prices of risk to determine expected return
from investing on foreign market, if these conditions are not verified.
C. Covariance between Asset Returns and Exchange Return
In this subsection we show if exchange rate permit conversion of
risk prices across countries. To examine relationship between domestic
and foreign factors risk prices as well as asset-exchange rate
covariance, we compare expected hedged excess return of foreign asset f
in domestic currency to its expected excess return in foreign currency.
Through equations (9) and (13), expected hedged excess return
E[(d[P.sub.f]/[P.sub.f])], of foreign asset f in domestic currency is
given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (14)
An arbitrage portfolio constructed through formula (7) can be
formed also in foreign currency. The last section shows that prices of
factor of risk [[lambda].sub.fk] that evaluate hedged assets in foreign
currency can be determined. The equation measurement of foreign asset
excess return can be obtained:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (15)
Comparing equations (14) and (15) shows that presence of term
cov(d[P.sub.f]/[P.sub.f], dS/S) convert prices of risks of
[[lambda].sub.fk] to [[lambda].sub.dk], k={1...k}. This conversion
propriety of exchange rate is the result of exclusion of arbitrage
opportunities.
In this context, comparing these two equations shows that
covariance between foreign asset return and exchange return will be
given by:
cov(d[P.sub.f]/[P.sub.f], dS/S) = [K.summation over
(k=1)][b.sub.fk]([[lambda].sub.dk] - [[lambda].sub.fk])dt
This equation shows that covariance between asset return and
exchange return depends on factor loadings [b.sub.fk]. This result shows
also that exchange rate serves also to convert the prices of risk of
foreign investments prices into domestic ones. However, investor
can't convert prices of risk of his original country.
Two major implications are to be noted from these results. First,
portfolios returns hedged against exchange risk depend only on factors
of risk of domestic country. In other words, domestic and foreign
portfolio having the same profile of risk must allow identical expected
returns when they are converted into national currency. Second, this
result cannot be maintained in case of unhedged portfolio. In fact,
exchange rate dynamics and exchange factors intervene entirely. In this
case, excess returns will be determined in part by the forward premium,
meaning the price of holding additional and orthogonal exchange rate
risk.
III. EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION OF HEDGED BOND RETURNS
A. Databases and Estimation of Unhedged Returns
Our study focuses on the following four bond markets: USA, Germany,
Japan and the UK. For each market, we collect daily observations of
governmental bond prices for the following maturities: 3 years, 5 years,
7 years, 10 years and 30 years. We cover the time period from 09/10/2000
until 14/10/2005, and have 20 time series of 270 observations. From
theses series we construct four bond portfolios containing two bonds
with different maturities. For each country, we obtain the following
portfolio: PF3 to 5 years, PF5 to 7 years, P[F.sub.7 to 10 years], et
P[F.sub.10 to 30 years].
Summary statistics for local portfolio returns investment are
reported in Table 1. Means and standard deviations of returns appear
very weak since returns are measured on the basis of one week horizon.
Negative means of returns reported on the Japanese market are explained
by the slight rise of interest rate in Japan over the period of study
but continue to be close to zero. In all countries, average returns and
their standard deviations generally increase with maturity.
Expected returns in Table 1 cannot be used to evaluate
international investment strategy. Since at the maturity of his
investment, the investor not only risks
unfavourable evolution of local interest rates but also risks the
exchange when converting his investment into domestic currency. In this
context, we need to convert local returns into domestic currency returns
of the investor. In this paper, we consider the US as the domestic
country and the other ones as foreign country.
The one-month money market rate is applied as the risk-free
interest rate in order to calculate excess returns on each market. Spot
exchange rates between these countries are also sampled for the same
period of study. Exchange rates are quoted as the price of foreign
currency in units of domestic currency.
Table 2 reports summary statistics of interest rates and
first-variations of exchange rates for each country. This table shows
that Euro and Pound sterling are appreciated, in means, face to USD over
the period of study by 0.082% and 0.124%, respectively. While, the USD
is globally appreciated by 0.027% face to the Nippon.
Figure 1, we plot the correlations between bond returns of
different maturities and different countries. Since portfolios are
regrouped by country in the correlation matrix, high correlations near
the diagonal of the matrix indicate high correlations between countries.
The majority of correlations are positives.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Returns of unhedged international investment portfolio in domestic
currency can be calculated by equation (4). Table 3 reports means and
standard deviations of returns of the unhedged portfolio when
considering USA as domestic country. This table shows that standard
deviations of international investment portfolio are higher than
domestic portfolio returns.
We note that when investment occurs in US, expected returns will be
the same as those of Table 1, since in this case American investor is
not expected to exchange risk. Returns in Table 3 can be compared to
those of Table 1.
Comparison of Tables 1 and 3 shows that investment in foreign
markets increases standard deviation of returns in all considered
markets. In fact, standard deviation of unhedged returns in the European
and Japanese market lies between 1.037% and 1.138%, at a time when it
was less than 0.03% when returns are measured in domestic currency
(table 1). Equally, standard deviations of unhedged returns in the UK
market exceed 0.95% when it was less than 0.029% in the first table. The
impact of exchange rate on international investment return is clearly
expressed in this table, since the depreciation of the Yen has
contributed to the deterioration of returns realized on the Japanese
market, when the depreciation of the EUR and GBP contributes to
ameliorate returns realised on the European and English markets.
B. Estimation of Hedged Bond Returns
Expected returns of hedged portfolios can be measured by the
following equation:
[[d[P.sub.f]/[P.sub.f]].sub.couvert] = [[mu].sub.f] +
cov(d[P.sup.*.sub.f]/[P.sup.*.sub.f], dS/S) - [r.sup.f] + [r.sub.d] (16)
Table 4 reports descriptive statistics of hedged portfolios. When
considering the case of an American investor in an England portfolio
formed of 3 and 5 year bonds, he realises an average return of 0.0374%
from his investment in London and realises a negative return from his
hedging position on the exchange market. Measured by the spread;
rusd-rgbp, (-1.948%). Its net return in USD is about (-1.9106%). In this
case also, the difference between this return and the return indicated
in table 4 (-1.958) is always due to the covariance term between asset
return and exchange rate returns.
Comparison of unhedged returns and hedged returns of local
portfolios in Tables 3 and 4 shows that the hedging strategy leads to a
significant reduction of the hedged portfolio variances compared to
those of unhedged portfolios. This reduction is about 70% and 80% in
mean for all the portfolios. We remark that risk reduction is not
necessary coupled with an equivalent reduction in mean returns. Indeed,
some means of return of hedged portfolios exceed those of unhedged
portfolios. This can be due to the impact of the depreciation of
exchange rate.
IV. ESTIMATION RESULTS OF FACTORS LOADING PER COUNTRY
We estimate the first four principal factors and the explained
cumulative variance (4) for each country by applying principal component
analysis to the covariance matrix of local currency excess returns.
Since the principal compound analysis doesn't determine the
exact number of factor loadings, we proceed in our methodology by
estimating prices of risk factors separately in each country and then we
compare results to those estimated through a cross-sectional analysis.
Table 5 presents the first four principal factors obtained from the
principal component analysis method applied to bond returns in each
country.
The factor loadings values appear very small. This is due to the
adjustment of the principal compound analysis. The first factor affects
bonds in all countries and can be regarded as a global factor, whereas
the other factors seem to be more country-specifics. For example, the
second risk factor strongly affects bond in Japan, the third affects
British bond and the fourth one affects bond returns in Germany.
Estimations of the first four factors are presented in Figure 2. We
note that variation of term structure level influence considerably long
term bond returns. We interpret the first factor as a world level
factor. This factor shifts the entire term structure in all countries in
the same direction. The second factor can be interpreted as a slope
factor, since movement of this factors exhibit the slope of the curve.
when the third factor describe the curvature of yields curve, since it
affect middle term bond returns in different sense of the short and long
bond maturities.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Though risk factors express almost the same form across countries,
the explained variances for each country differ for one country to
another. Our results differ from those of Litterman and Scheikman (1991)
who show that explained variance is lower for the first factor, and
higher for the second and the third factors. This imply that for the
last five years more movement of slope and curvature has occurred on the
yield curve of Germany, Japan and UK than in the US market.
From Table 6 we deduce that the three first factors explain 99.99%
of the variation of bond returns in the USA, 98.65% in Japan, 97.67% in
the UK and 98.65% in Germany. The first factor appears very important
for the four bond markets considered and explains 88% of variation in
the USA, 76% in Japan, 67% in the UK and 79% in Germany.
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS FOR A MULTI-COUNTRIES MODEL
A. Risk Premium Estimation
The factor loadings estimated for each country will be used as
inputs for the cross sectional estimation of currency-specific factors
risk premium for each. From equation (14), the international asset
pricing theory supports that hedged returns in a common currency can be
expressed in terms of linear combination of principal compound and risk
premium. In this section, we estimate risk premium of factors by
regressing hedged returns on the principal factors estimated. In order
to estimate specific prices of risk for each currency, expected returns
of all bonds NM(=16) in the four currencies are measured, which give us
N[M.sup.2] (64) expected returns in our cross-sectional study. In a
multi-country context equation (14) can be expressed in the following
form:
[R.sub.e] = [I [cross product] B][lambda] (17)
Where Re is an N[M.sup.2]-dimensional vector of expected hedged
returns for all bonds in all countries. I is an identity matrix and
[cross product] is the Kronecker product. [lambda] is an NK-dimensional
vector containing specific risks premia for all factors and all
currencies. Equation (20) can be reformulated in our case into:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (18)
The parameters of this system can be estimated by the Generalised Moments Method developed by Hyearsen (1982) (5). We estimate risk
premium from one to seven risk factors. Table 7 presents specific risk
premia for each currency. We remark that only six prices of risk are
significant for all the countries.
This table shows that on the American market, prices of risk of the
first factor and the third factor are significant. The second and the
fifth factor prices of risk are significant only on the UK market.
Whereas risk prices of the fourth and the fifth factors are significant
for Germany and Japan, respectively.
Table 8 indicates that daily premium variations in international
bond markets are explained by a common world factor. This result seems
surprising when taking into account the complication process underlining
the governmental bon market. This factor explains about 64.82% of the
commune variation.
B. Economic Interpretation
While the principal component analysis shows that variation of
premium results namely of a common factor, it appears insufficient to
give any indication about underlying economic forces. This section
examines this aspect in order to find a significant economic
interpretation of the common factor. A factor is an abstract series that
explains the common part variation of risk premium. In this sense it can
be the world economic development, change in investors attitude face to
risk.
Our methodology consists of analysing simple correlations between
common factor series and variables reflecting world economic tendency.
If it's impossible to precisely identify the significance of the
common factor, this empirical investigation allows determination of the
most important world tendency affecting bon risk premia. In particular,
we propose examination of the explanatory power of the following
variables: stock index return (S&P 500, FTSE and Nasdaq); long-term
interest rates in the US and the slope of the yield curve in the US. We
consider weekly data selected for the same period of study. Results are
presented in Table 9.
The common factor is significantly correlated with many variables,
which is explained by the high correlation existent between the world
tendency variables, and the fact that common factor, in nature,
associates all common determinants of risk premia in international bond
markets. Globally, our study indicates positive correlation with
American interest rate.
This positive relationship can be explained by the informative
contain of the slope of the US yield curve, which is usually used as a
common indicator to anticipate economic growth.
This is also corroborated by relatively narrow correlations with
stock index (6). For example, an increase of the return of S&P 500,
is accompanied by an increase of the common factor, and in consequence
an increase in bond returns.
C. Prices of Risk Divergence across Country
Before testing price of risk conversion across-countries, we must,
first of all, verify that price of risks is different across-countries.
We apply the Wald to test the null hypothesis that risk premium are
equivalent across-countries ([lambda]usd = [lambda]yen = [lambda]gbp =
[lambda]eur). Table 10 reports results of the Wald test. It's shown
that price of risk of the first and the second factor are significantly
different across-countries.
The first and the second factors show different price of risk
across-countries. On one hand this difference must be reflected in the
expected exchange rate, and on the other hand on the covariance between
exchange rate and bond return in conformity to equations (14) and (15).
As a first step, in order to test the effect of price of risk
differential on expected exchange rate, we regress the exchange return
on risk prices spread and the interest rate differential
across-countries. That is:
[R.sub.Tchg] = [alpha] + [beta]([r.sub.d] - [r.sub.f]) +
[K.summation over (k=1)] [[delta]i]([[lambda].sub.dk] -
[[lambda].sub.fk])dt (19)
Table 11 reports results estimation of coefficients [[delta].sub.i]
for the first four factors. Though this table shows weak values of
[[delta].sub.i] coefficients in all countries, these coefficients appear
significant for the case of two factors in EUR/USD and GBP/USD
regression. However, the null hypothesis which support that exchange
rate dynamic depends on risk prices differentials is rejected in the
case of Japan.
The major remark to report from this table is that coefficients
[[delta].sub.i] is not significant for specifications with more than two
factors for all countries. This is due to the fact that the first two
factors are evaluated differently across-countries and must influence
the expected exchange rate. We conclude that prices differentials affect
the expected exchange rate.
D. Role of Exchange Rate in Converting Price of Risks across
Countries
With the aim of test if exchange rate has serve to convert prices
of risk across countries, we test the null hypothesis which support that
cross risk premium, estimated from a multi-countries model, equals the
specific prices of risk spread to every currency.
Formally we test if [[lambda].sub.k.sup.cross] = [[lambda].sub.dk]
- [[lambda].sub.fk], where [[lambda].sub.k.sub.cross] is estimated from
the following equation:
E[[DELTA][P.sub.f]/[P.sub.f] [DELTA]S/S] = [K.summation over
(k=1)][b.sub.fk][[lambda].sup.cross.sub.k] (20)
We apply the Wald test to the product of expected bond returns and
exchange return. Results of the test are presented in Table 12. Our
results support the hypothesis that bond return covariance and exchange
rate are identified by the spread of risk premium across-countries. At
10% level of significance, the null hypothesis is rejected only in the
case of Yen/USD exchange rate.
Our cross-sectional analysis of bond returns supports the
hypothesis that exchange rate serves to convert prices of risk as
suggested by the International Asset Pricing Theory presented in section
2. Hence, expected variances of exchange rate can't be entirely
explained by interest rates and risk price differentials in a
cross-country model.
In this spirit, the rejection of equation (13) can be explained by
incomplete market. In the case of incomplete market, exchange rate can
be deduced from risk factors that are orthogonal to asset returns and
can't be directly estimated through only market data.
Restriction of covariance must be maintained in the case of
incomplete market. Its reject in the case of USD/Yen exchange rate
indicates that Japanese market is not fully integrated with
international markets. In the case of complete markets, assets with the
same profile of risk must have the same expected returns after
conversion to the commune currency.
Specific prices of risk are compatible with integrated markets as
long as exchange risk recompenses spreads of these prices of risk. This
is not the case of the Yen where differences in the first and the second
factors are not adjusted by exchange rate. Limited integration of the
Japanese market has been reported in many studies, i.e. Frenck and
Poterba (1991), Harvey (1991) and Campbell and Hamao (1992).
Two possible explanations can be advanced for this phenomenon.
First, Japanese market was slightly liberalized. Hence, Japanese
investors were faced with capital control that limited their investment
opportunities in foreign markets. Second, the Japanese Yen was
considered as a semi-floating currency, since the bank of Japan
intervenes some times on the exchange market in order to imitate the
appreciation of the Yen (7). In this context, the bank of Japan has
intervened in many reprises in 2001 to attenuate the appreciation of the
Yen. These repeated interventions had maintained the Yen in an interval
of 124 and 126 JPY per dollar at the middle of 2001.
VI. CONCLUSION
The paper deduces conclusions about governmental bond returns
through the exchange rate process. We have investigated loading factors
that might account for the simultaneous increase in risk premia in many
bond markets. Than we have tested two fundamental hypotheses of the
international asset pricing theory. First, we test if hedged returns of
international investment portfolio depend on the prices of risk of the
domestic country of the investor or the price of risk where investment
is realised. Second, we test the property of exchange rate to convert
risk premium across-countries.
To test if factors of price of risk observed on bond market affect
exchange process, we use a two-step approach. Firstly, we use the
principal component analysis to estimate separately the principal
factors in each bond market. Secondly, we estimated risk prices factors
for all the countries considered. Specific factors of prices of risk to
each currency are used to test if exchange rate convert expected
exchange rate for all the currencies considered, only in the case of the
Japanese market that is less integrated with international markets than
American and European markets.
This paper involves three principal results. First, we show that
international governmental bonds variation is due to a common loading
factor. This one is, in mean, at the origin of the third of the whole
daily variation. Idiosyncratic factors are in consequence dominating.
Second, we confirm that prices of risk are different across countries.
Finally, we have shown that exchange rates serve to convert prices of
risk between countries and returns of hedged portfolios are determined
by risk premium of the domestic country of the investor and not by the
prices of risk where investment has happened, i.e., an American investor
can't apply German prices of risk to evaluate the performance of
his investment in the German market.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Basilevsky, A., 1995, Statistical Factor Analysis and Related
Methods, John Wiley & Sons.
Buhler, W., M. Uhrig, U. Walter, and T. Weber, 1999, "An
Empirical Comparison of Forward- and Spot-Rate Models for Valuing
Interest-Rate Options ", Journal of Finance, 54, 269-305.
Brown, S., 1989, "The Number of Factors in Security Returns
", Journal of Finance, 44, no 5, December, pp. 1247-1262.
Frachot, A., 1995, "Factor Models of Domestic and Foreign
Interest Rates with Stochastic Volatilities", Mathematical Finance,
5, 167-185.
Golub, B.W., and L.M. Tilman, 1997, "Measuring Yield Curve
Risk using Principal Components Analysis, Value at Risk, and Key Rate
Durations", Journal of Portfolio Management, Summer 1997, 72-84.
Cochrane, J., 2001, Asset Pricing, Princeton University Press,
Princeton.
Connor, G., and R. Korajczyk, 1993, "A Test for the Number of
Factors in an Approximate Factor Model", Journal of Finance, 48, no
4, September, pp. 1263-1291.
Fama, E., and K. French, 1992, "The Cross-section of Expected
Stock Returns", Journal of Finance, 47, no 2, June, pp. 427-465.
Fama, E., and K. French, 1993, "Common Risk Factors in the
Returns on Stocks and Bonds", Journal of Financial Economics, 33,
no 1, February, pp. 3-56.
Fama, E., and K. French, 1996, "The CAPM is Wanted, Dead or
Alive", Journal of Finance, 49, no 5, December, pp. 1579-1593.
Farrell, J., 1974, "Analyzing Covariation of Returns to
Determine Homogenous Stock Groupings", Journal of Business, 47, no
2, April, pp. 186-207.
Hyearsen, L., 1982, "Large Sample Properties of Generalized
Methods of Moments Estimators", Econometrica, 50, 1029-1054.
Harvey, C.R., 1995, "Predictable Risk and Return in Emerging
Markets", Review of Financial Studies, 8, no 3, pp. 773-816.
Ilmanen, A., 1995, "Time-Varying Expected Returns in
International Bond Markets", Journal of Finance, 50, 481-506.
Knez, P.J., R. Litterman, and J. Scheinkman, 1994,
"Explorations into Factors Explaining Money Market Returns",
Journal of Finance, 49, 1861-1882.
Litterman, R., and J. Scheinkman, 1991, "Common Factors
Affecting Bond Returns", Journal of Fixed Income, 1, 62-74.
Macaulay, F.R., 1938, "Some Theoretical Problems Suggested by
the Movements of Interest Rates, Bond Yields, and Stock Prices in the
United States since 1856", Columbia University Press New York.
Mei, J., 1993, "A Semiautoregression Approach to the Arbitrage
Pricing Theory", Journal of Finance, 48, no 2, June, pp. 599-620.
Newey, W.K., and K.D. West, 1987, "A Simple, Positive
Semi-Definite, Heteroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent
Covariance Matrix", Econometrica, 55, 703-708.
Rebonato, R., 1996, Interest-Rate Option Models, John Wiley &
Sons.
Rebonato, R., and I. Cooper, 1996, "The Limitations of
Two-Factor Interest Rate Models", Journal of Financial Engineering,
5, 1-16.
Ross, S.A., 1976, "The Arbitrage Theory of Capital",
Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 341-360.
Shao, J., and D. Tu, 1995, The Jackknife and the Bootstrap,
Springer-Verlag New York.
Singh, M., 1997, "Value at Risk Using Principal Components
Analysis", Journal of Portfolio Management, Fall 1997, 101-110.
Trzcinka, C. 1986, "On the Number of Factors in the Arbitrage
Pricing Model", Journal of Finance, 41, no 2, June, pp. 347-368.
Thomas, L., and R. Willner, 1997, "Measuring the Duration of
an Internationally Diversified Bond Portfolio", Journal of
Portfolio Management, Fall 1997, 93-99.
Willner, R., 1996, "A New Tool for Portfolio Managers: Level,
Slope and Curvature Durations", Journal of Fixed Income, June 1996,
48-59.
ENDNOTES
(1.) Brown (1989), Litterman and Scheinkman (1991), Connor and
Korajczyk (1993), etc.
(2.) This portfolio is formed by domestic and foreign assets.
(3.) German portfolio will be indicated by EUR since the exchange
rate considered in the case of Germany is the Euro.
(4.) To estimate principal factors for each country, we precede
Eisenberg (2003) approach used to extract principal factors from the
share market of America, Japan, Germany and England.
(5.) This work is effectuated by Ogaki (1993).
(6.) A significant part of stock prices volatility is explained by
variation of discount factor-degree of risk aversion (Cochrane (2001)).
(7.) Hiyao (2000).
Jean-Michel Sahut (a) and Medhi Mili (b)
(a) Professor of Finance, Groupe Sup de Co Amiens &
CEREGE--University of Poitiers
[email protected]
(b) Ph.D. Student, MODESFI--University of Sfax & CEREGE -
University of Poitiers
Table 1
Descriptive statistics of local returns (3)
Returns are measured weekly over the period 9/10/2000 to 14/10/2005.
Every portfolio is formed of two bonds with different maturities for
each country.
Std.Dev
Means (%) (%) Skew. Kurtos. Auto-cor.
USA 3-5 years 0.02051 0.0194 7.9555 -1.1962 -0.312
USA 5-7 years 0.02307 0.0208 4.1009 0.4025 -0.109
USA 7-10 years 0.03614 0.0253 4.5097 0.2002 -0.205
USA 10-30 years 0.0451 0.0280 2.5186 -0.8057 -0.482
YEN 3-5 years -0.04584 0.0078 10.1722 0.4764 -0.320
YEN 5-7 years -0.03977 0.0113 10.2341 -0.9217 -0.187
YENP 7-10 years -0.02182 0.0121 5.6137 -1.2058 -0.622
YEN 10-30 years 0.06178 0.0287 12.1687 0.6341 -0.455
GBP 3-5 years 0.03746 0.0176 49.012 -2.6231 -0.780
GBP 5-7 years 0.03446 0.0211 31.7354 -2.3924 -0.792
GBP 7-10 years 0.03667 0.0315 35.4229 -0.1237 -0.806
GBP 10-30 years 0.05423 0.0354 24.415 -0.5532 -0.818
EUR 3-5 years 0.02300 0.0098 7.2371 -0.0446 -0.543
EUR 5-7 years 0.02609 0.0131 5.0173 -0.3781 -0.622
EUR 7-10 years 0.03174 0.0158 2.9443 -0.4494 -0.863
EUR 10-30 years 0.03633 0.0229 3.1777 -1.1124 -0.766
Table 2
Descriptive statistics of exchange returns and one month interest rates
Exchange rates are expressed one dollar in terms of foreign currencies.
Les taux de change sont exprimes en termes de dollar par rapport a une
unite de monnaie etrangere. Interest rates are one-month monetary
market interest rates in each country which will be considered as
approximation of spot rates.
Std.Dev
Means. (%) (%) Skew. Kurtos. Auto-cor.
Rendements des taux de change
YEN/USD -0.027 1.038 0.187 1.021 0.875
GBP/USD 0.082 0.951 0.162- 5.046 0,923
EUR/USD 0.124 1.134 -0.046 -0.007 0,967
Taux d'interet
[r.sup.usd] 2.425 1.528 1.411 1.117 0,938
[r.sup.yen] 0.078 0.126 4.940 30.791 0,840
[r.sup.gbp] 4.417 0.706 0.660 -0.354 0,974
[r.sup.eur] 2.978 1.006 0.726 -0.869 0,921
Table 3
Descriptive statistics of unhedged bond portfolios
Std.Dev
Means (%) (%) Skew. Kurtos. Auto-cor.
USA 3-5 years 0.02051 0.0194 7.9555 -1.1962 -0.312
USA 5-7 years 0.02307 0.0208 4.1009 0.4025 -0.109
USA 7-10 years 0.03614 0.0253 4.5097 0.2002 -0.205
USA 10-30 years 0.04510 0.0280 2.5186 -0.8057 -0.482
YEN 3-5 years -0.07863 1.0377 0.1891 0.2586 -0.792
YEN 5-7 years -0.07835 1.0380 0.1956 0.2673 -0.785
YENP 7-10 years -0.02601 1.0391 0.1936 0.2617 -0.784
YEN 10-30 years -0.02686 1.0488 0.1957 0.2892 -0.779
GBP 3-5 years 0.08148 0.9517 -0.1591 0.5139 -0.788
GBP 5-7 years 0.08097 0.9513 -0.1574 0.5115 -0.794
GBP 7-10 years 0.08405 0.9541 -0.1665 0.5145 -0.806
GBP 10-30 years 0.08582 0.9566 -0.1627 0.5183 -0.816
EUR 3-5 years 0.12675 1.1371 -0.0461 -0.3135 -0.884
EUR 5-7 years 0.12724 1.1376 -0.0445 -0.3118 -0.876
EUR 7-10 years 0.12771 1.1380 -0.0450 -0.3088 -0.884
EUR 10-30 years 0.13676 1.1376 -0.0449 -0.3022 0.793
Table 4
Hedged returns summary statistics
Std.Dev
Means (%) (%) Skew. Kurtos. Auto-cor.
USA 3-5 years 0.02051 0.0194 7.9555 -1.1962 -0.312
USA 5-7 years 0.02307 0.0208 4.1009 0.4025 -0.109
USA 7-10 years 0.03614 0.0253 4.5097 0.2002 -0.205
USA 10-30 years 0.04510 0.0280 2.5186 -0.8057 -0.482
YEN 3-5 years 2.38508 0.4134 1.1846 0.5551 -0.794
YEN 5-7 years 2.38535 0.4131 1.1842 0.5558 -0.378
YENP 7-10 years 2.38669 0.4130 1.1851 0.5604 -0.278
YEN 10-30 years 2.38684 0.4144 1.1879 0.5708 -0.377
GBP 3-5 years -1.95887 0.6551 1.1062 0.9423 -0.578
GBP 5-7 years -1.95938 0.6544 1.1122 0.9549 -0.379
GBP 7-10 years -1.95630 0.5562 1.1053 0.9371 -0.280
GBP 10-30 years -1.95453 0.5356 1.1025 0.9459 -0.481
EUR 3-5 years -0.46804 0.8701 0.7860 -0.7413 -0.388
EUR 5-7 years -0.46755 0.8701 0.7854 -0.7442 -0.487
EUR 7-10 years -0.45708 0.8703 0.7856 -0.7427 -0.380
EUR 10-30 years -0.40803 0.8706 0.7857 -0.7390 -0.798
Table 5
Estimated factor loadings
The four first factors loading are estimated by the principal
component analysis for each country.
1 2 3 4
USA 3-5 years 0.0549 -0.4569 -0.5576 -0.5953
USA 5-7 years 0.3608 0.3059 -0.1433 -0.5542
USA 7-10 years 0.3611 -0.1754 -0.7073 0.5818
USA 10-30 years 0.5046 0.8166 -0.4102 -0.0005
YEN 3-5 years 0,0574 0,1536 0,2528 0,9537
YEN 5-7 years 0,4320 -0,7606 -0,4109 0,2571
YENP 7-10 years 0,4527 0,2521 -0,8417 0,1550
YEN 10-30 years 0,7779 -0,5792 0,2431 -0,0177
GBP 3-5 years 0.0846 -0.1985 -0.6479 -0.7305
GBP 5-7 years 0.1417 -0.7386 -0.3907 -0.5308
GBP 7-10 years 0.4819 -0.3654 0.2923 -0.0578
GBP 10-30 years 0.9416 -0.5306 0.5849 -0.4258
EUR 3-5 years 0.2191 -0.3669 -0.5034 -0.7510
EUR 5-7 years 0.3736 -0.6049 -0.3261 0.6231
EUR 7-10 years 0.7728 -0.9276 -0.6107 0.1705
EUR 10-30 years 0.7840 -0.0706 -0.5169 0.1369
Table 6
Variance explained by principal components for each country
This Table reports explained variance in means for each
compared with the total variance of bond returns.
1 2 3 4
Usd 88.378 9.528 2.092 0.0007
Eur 79.161 14.201 5.129 1.507
Yen 76.829 14.486 7.337 1.347
Gbp 67.673 18.078 11.597 2.650
Table 7
Results of estimated prices of risk for the four-country model
This Table reports cross-section estimation of prices of risk of
factors following equation (21). We suppose that each country has
different prices of risk. Student-Statistics are indicated between
parentheses for each prices of risk. * indicates that prices of
risks are significant at 95% level.
[[lambda].sup.usd] [[lambda].sup.yen]
1 0.077 * -0.062
(5.245) (0.147)
2 0.08 -0.059
(0.146) (0.058)
3 0.024 * -0.025
(2.034) (0.543)
4 0.048 -0.052
(0.120) (0.456)
5 0.016 -0.043 *
(0.149) (2.876)
6 0.063 -0.083
(0.345) (0.855)
7 0.045 -0.027
(0.129) (0.243)
[[lambda].sup.gbp] [[lambda].sup.eur]
1 0.012 -0.067
(0.432) (1.325)
2 0.009* -0.043
(4.131) (0.980)
3 0.068 -0.029
(1.532) (0.654)
4 0.047 -0.056 *
(0.012) (2.654)
5 -0.036 * 0.027
(-1.944) (0.071)
6 -0.083 0.054
(0.009) (0.038)
7 -0.11 0.079
(1.032) (1.298)
Table 8
Explained variance for a multi-country model
This Table reports average explained variance for each
factor compared to the whole variance of bond returns.
Returns of multi-factor model
1 64.821 (%)
2 18.314 (%)
3 9.9640 (%)
4 0.4216 (%)
5 0.0125 (%)
6 0.0045 (%)
Total 93.536 (%)
Table 9
Correlation coefficients between common factor and economic variables
Returns are measured for 270 weekly observations over the period from
9/12/200 to 14/10/2005.
Correlation with economic variables
Stock Index
Nasdaq 0.214 (%)
FTSE 0.370 (%)
S&P 500 0.324 (%)
United State interest rates
3-month EUR treasury returns 0.268 (%)
10-month EUR treasury returns 0.356 (%)
Yield curve 0.174 (%)
Table 10
Wald hypothesis tests on currency-specific factor risk premia
This table reports p-value for Wald hypothesis tests. The null
hypothesis testes is that factor risk premia are equal across
countries: [[lambda].sup.usd] = [[lambda].sup.yen] =
[[lambda].sup.gbp] = [[lambda].sup.eur]. Low p-values reject
the null hypothesis.
P-Value
1 0.04358 *
2 0.00987 *
3 0.23956
4 0.35512
5 0.78231
6 0.35056
7 0.89721
Table 11
Estimation results of the regression of exchange rate returns on
interest rates differential and prices of risk differentials
This table reports results of the test of expected variations of
exchange rates that depends on interest rate differentials and
prices of risk factors differential. * indicates that
[[delta].sub.i] coefficient is significant at 10% level.
JPY/USD GBP/USD EUR/USD
One facteur [[delta].sub.1] 0,013 0,014 * 0,015
Two factors [[delta].sub.1] 0,051 0,052 * 0,056 *
[[delta].sub.2] 0,050 0,049 0,052 *
Three factors [[delta].sub.1] 0,019 0,024 0,010
[[delta].sub.2] 0,064 0,055 0,059
[[delta].sub.3] 0,056 0,056 0,056
Four factors [[delta].sub.1] 0,013 0,014 0,015
[[delta].sub.2] 0,051 0,052 0,056
[[delta].sub.3] 0,050 0,049 0,052
[[delta].sub.4] 0,019 0,024 0,010
Table 12
Wald hypothesis tests on expected cross products os asset returns
and exchange rates
This table reports P-Values of the null hypothesis that:
[[lambda].sub.k.sup.cross] = [[lambda].sub.dk] - [[lambda].sub.fk],
where [[lambda].sub.k.sup.cross] is the price of risk estimated
through equation (23). * indicates that the value is significant
at level of 10%. Low values of p-values indicate rejection of the
null hypothesis.
P-Value
Nbr of factors JPY/USD GBP/USD EUR/USD
1 0.013 * 0.314 0.515
2 0.051 * 0.452 0.556
3 0.050 * 0.249 0.352
4 0.219 0.924 0.210
5 0.025 * 0.452 0.849
6 0.015 * 0.547 0.955
7 0.000 * 0.621 * 0.125