Flaws in banking governance.
Sahut, Jean-Michel ; Boulerne, Sandrine
I. INTRODUCTION
Separation between ownership and control in business organisations
by way of shares underlies the emergence of the concept of governance.
According to agency theory, as defined by Jensen and Meckling (1976),
this separation creates a potential problem of conflict of interest,
notably between the shareholders and executives. The more ownership is
divided between a large numbers of shareholders, the more the executives
risk running the firm in their own interests. In effect, executives have
different temporal objectives and horizons to those of the shareholders,
and have privileged access to information that they can benefit from by
steering the organisation's management in line with their own
personal goals. Furthermore, executives may choose certain investments
over others, depending on their preferences and the level of risk.
(Charreaux, 1991). Thus, implementing effective governance mechanisms
should lead to reduced agency conflict costs, and ensure the alignment
of interests between shareholders and executives, consequently
maximising shareholder wealth. (1) From this perspective, business
organisation governance may be considered as "all the
organisational and institutional mechanisms (including laws) that define
the executives' room for manoeuvre and influence their
decision-making" (Charreaux, 1997).
The global financial scandals ha came o ligh in he firs decade of
he 21s century (Enron, Worldcom, Parmalat) and the resulting loss of
investor confidence in corporate management led to the tightening of
internal and external governance mechanisms, particularly in terms of
legislation (Sarbanes-Oxley law in the USA and TEPA law in France) and
"good governance" rules set out by various regulatory and
professional organisations (OCDE principles, Dey report in Canada,
Cadbury report in the UK, Treadway report in the US, etc.), linked to
greater pressure from institutional investors. In addition to their
deontological value, the central idea behind these measures is that good
governance creates value. According to McKinsey (2002), institutional
investors are ready to pay a 12 to 14% premium for firms that adopt best
governance practices. This link has been identified in a number of
studies, whether they focused on governance in general or specific
mechanisms like ownership structure, the institutional role of
investors, the proportion of external directors on the Board of
Directors, the existence of a dual Board structure, or executive
compensation.
Despite the stepping up of governance mechanisms, particularly in
terms of legislation, flaws in the financial regulation system and
business organisation governance were widely blamed in the press as the
main cause of the subprime crisis, highlighted in articles on
traders' bonuses, fiscal paradises, redundancies and the closing of
factories, etc.
However, to really understand the underlying causes of the
downturn, we need to separate the case of banks from that of other
industrial and commercial companies. The governance of the latter worked
relatively well, apart from some dysfunctions, like the monitoring of
ousted executives' compensation that included a "golden
handshake" or supplementary pension. In effect, the downturn forced
companies to cut back given the resulting drop in profits. Cost
reductions inevitably involved reviewing production methods (including
work organisation), logistics and stock management. The closure of
production plants was thus inevitable and in most cases cannot be blamed
on the poor governance of the firms in question.
The situation is completely different for financial institutions.
Their governance system really was to blame. In effect, good governance
would have enabled banks that granted subprime loans to better manage
the risks by limiting this type of credit and the sale of securitized
toxic products, and for other financial institutions to limit their
exposure to this type of products.
With this in mind, our paper sets out to explore the sources of
inefficient governance mechanisms in industrial and commercial firms and
the serious flaws in banks' governance practices revealed by the
subprime crisis.
II. SOURCES OF INEFFICIENT GOVERNANCE MECHANISMS
A. Governance and Value Creation
The link between good corporate governance and value creation has
been the subject of widespread debate and discussion. Different studies
on corporate governance have highlighted the relationship between
governance and performance either from a global perspective, or in terms
of a specific governance mechanism.
In effect, investors insist on companies applying rigorous
corporate governance principles in order to maximise their investment
profitability. Gugler, Mueller and Yurtoglu (2003) define "a strong
corporate governance system as one that aligns managerial and
shareholder interests and thus leads managers to maximise shareholder
wealth" Campos, Newell and Wilson (2002) studied the link between
governance and a firm's value and concluded that good governance
practices are associated with higher market valuation. Thus, a firm that
invests in shareholders' rights, providing transparent information
and developing the independence of the Board of Directors generates more
shareholder confidence. In similar vein, a study by Gompers, Ishii and
Metrick (2003) identified a positive relationship between good
governance and a firm's performance. By adopting investment
strategies based on best governance practices, investors made an
abnormal return of 8.5%. They concluded that good corporate governance
practice had a considerable impact on the organisation's reputation
in terms of value creation. Black, Jang and Kim, (2003) developed a
corporate governance index with 526 Korean firms, based on six
subindices, namely, shareholder rights, Board of Directors, the audit
process, independent directors, information transparency and ownership
structure. After analysing this index, they found a positive correlation between the corporate governance index and a firm's value. Bai,
Liu, Song and Zhang (2003) compared the performance of firms with good
governance practices and those without, and concluded that investors are
ready to pay a higher premium for firms which adopt best governance
practices. In similar vein, Drobetz, Schillhofer and Zimmermann (2003)
developed a corporate governance index for German companies, including a
number of variables such as minority shareholder rights, audit
committee, transparency and Board of Directors. They identified a
positive link between the governance score and the value of these firms.
Again, in a sample of 55 French SBF120 companies, Amir (2007) confirmed
the crucial role played by governance mechanisms in value creation. The
results of his study suggest that a well-un Board of Directors, related
to its structure and independence and the existence of an audit
committee on the Board, plays a key role in determining the performance
of French companies. On the other hand, he found that compensation
policies, ownership structure and shareholder rights did not appear to
impact significantly on the firms' performance. This finding does
not square with recommendations regarding governance and value creation
in most codes of good conduct.
Still within the context of the correlation between value creation
and corporate governance, four specific governance mechanisms are
frequently mentioned in the literature: independence of the Board of
Directors, size of the Board, separation of the chairman and the CEO,
and incentive pay packages.
Board member independence is a decisive factor in corporate
governance and its effectiveness. Nonetheless, conflicting findings
emerge from studies regarding the impact of independent members on
performance, mainly due to the fact that a non independent (internal)
board member does not necessarily support the same value creation
strategy as an independent (external) board member. In the context of
dispersed shareholder structures, Gagnon and St-Pierre (1995) found a
positive correlation between the presence of independent board members
and the rate of return on capital in Canadian firms. Agrawal and Knoeber
(1996), however, noted a negative link between the presence of
independent members on the Board and an organisation's performance.
Hermalin and Weisbach (2003) (2) concluded that there was little proof
of a correlation between performance and board members, at least in the
United States. Other studies, like those of Lawrence and Stapledon
(1999) or Alexander and Paquerot (2000), appear to confirm the absence
of independent board members' influence on performance. After
measuring performance using Tobin's Q, Andre and Schiehll (2004)
nonetheless argued there was a positive link between the performance of
Canadian firms and the proportion of independent board members. Their
findings suggest that an average increase of 10% in the percentage of
independent board members leads to a 9% increase in a firm's
performance.
Another frequently studied feature of the Board of Directors is its
size. Several authors claim that the Board loses its effectiveness when
it is too big. Bhagat and Black (2002) confirmed this assertion. (3)
Smaller Boards tend to have greater control over the executives.
However, Daily et al. (1999) argued that a Board which is too small
reduces the possibility of having a wide spread of expertise.
Another variable studied is the sharing of responsibility by the
Chairman of the Board and the CEO. Study conclusions diverge regarding
the relationship between duality (when the positions of CEO and Chairman
of the Board are held by one individual) and performance. Dalton et al.
(1998) suggested that markets are relatively indifferent to this concept
of duality, while Worell, Nemec and Daidson (1997) found that duality
had a negative impact.
When executive compensation is closely linked to the firm's
performance, it is widely acknowledged in the literature that costs
associated with conflicts of interest are reduced. (4) Andre and
Schiehll (2004) found a positive correlation between the performance of
Canadian firms and the size of the business leader's incentive pay.
A 10% increase in the relative size of the CEO's incentive pay
results in a similar increase in the organisation's performance.
CEOs with larger compensation levels tend to align their interests far
more with those of their shareholders.
B. Weaknesses in Governance Mechanisms in France
The present economic and financial crisis has laid bare the
weaknesses of certain governance mechanisms utilised in France. In
particular, the recent scandals surrounding the ousting or negotiated
departure of listed organisation executives revealed that part of their
compensation package was unrelated to their performance. It should be
noted that executive compensation is decided by the Board of Directors,
which may include a compensation committee. However, neither
legislation, nor the AMF (French financial markets authority) requires
the Board to consult a compensation committee, which is limited to a
purely preliminary stage in the Board of Directors' decision-making
process. Under the TEPA bill of 21 August 2007, executives' pay
packages in publicly listed companies are subject to shareholder
approval and determined by performance criteria. These criteria are
extremely vague, given the absence of any legal definition or
explanation, and in practice are considered according to individual
criteria related to the financial or strategic objectives of the company
in question. (5) Only the Board of Directors may define performance
indicators that must be approved during a general meeting of
shareholders, but the nature of the adoption mechanism, subject to
public release, may be totally arbitrary and discretionary. Executives
may thus benefit from excessive pay packages that are entirely unrelated
to the firm's financial performance. Only deferred executive
compensation (severance pay) is forbidden under the TEPA law unless
justified by conditions linked to the recipient's performance. For
their part, the AMF and the AFEP/MEDEF have also asked for deferred
compensation to be dependent on the executive's performance,
without, however, going into detail regarding the notion of performance.
Yet, according to a study published by La Tribune, in 2007 French bosses
received the highest severance pay when compared to their European
counterparts. (6) A measure of proportionality between the compensation
awarded (such as golden handshakes) and the employer's actual
performance would more easily justify these compensatory measures. A
survey conducted by Hewitt Associates found that, in 2007, 45% of SBF
120-listed companies introduced a performance threshold beyond which the
payment of compensation based on tenure would become effective, a
measure designed to penalise poor executive performance. This introduces
the notion of level of threshold demanded. On the other hand, 55% of
SBF120 firms have introduced a system whereby severance pay increases in
line with performance. This measure is ambiguous insofar as other
compensation elements such as annual salary variables or stock options
are better at acknowledging performance than severance pay. It even
seems that in France, organisations where executive compensation is
separate from the company's financial performance are the very ones
who tend to give in to the temptation or the pressure to set up
compensation committees. This is true of France Telecom which set up
three new committees in 2005: the compensation, selection and
organisation committee, the strategic committee, and the policy
committee. These committees were set up in addition to the audit
committee already in place. Some companies, even with specialised
committees, have been unable to avert scandals, like Vivendi Universal
under Jean-Marie Messier. (7)
Creating supervisory committees on Boards of Directors is one way
organisations have been improved, especially in terms of corporate
governance, as recommended by codes of good conduct, notably the first
Vienot report (1995). Nonetheless, in French law, these committees
(audit committee, compensation committee and selection committee) are
not answerable to the shareholders and therefore do not meet the
independence criteria required by the Anglo-Saxon concept. Setting up
committees not only remains at the discretion of the organisations in
question but, in addition, the committees have little more than an
advisory role. After noting the weaknesses in such governance
mechanisms, some authors (including Pochet and Yeo, 2004) have argued
that the creation of a supervisory committee has a purely formal
character in France, intended to satisfy the demands of Anglo-Saxon
investors, without really offering an operational reality that meets
market expectations, especially regarding the CEO's independence.
This raises the question as to why an ever-growing number of listed
companies adopt such measures.
As well as the independence of supervisory committees, board
members' independence is also compromised for two main reasons: the
small financial reward they receive (8) and the appointment itself,
which is often initiated by the CEO. In France, in particular,
executives have always considered the appointment of board members as a
personal prerogative. This is why, even when a selection committee has
been set up, management, and particularly the CEO, continue to have a
strong influence over the selection process. In addition, the way the
Board of Directors is run may be influenced by personal intermeshed relationships with other boards. Several studies have highlighted the
existence of board member networks and bilateral relations between board
members in CAC 40 companies. (9) As networks of independent Board member
'friends' sit on various boards and specialised committees, it
makes them more difficult to remove. Their recruitment and appointment
is not related to their competencies, thereby reducing the interest of
subjecting them to any form of evaluation. Several authors (10) note
that a board member who belongs to the same social circle (the old boy
network) as the CEO is more likely to be given a mandate. Such board
member networks call into question the members' independence and
result in a certain degree of ineffective internal control. Public
opinion consequently has a negative view of board member networks in
France as they are considered to damage corporate performance. The same
trends have been observed with regard to executives in leading listed
organisations. The main business leaders seem to find it more difficult
to leave their job when they are from the same social circle or old boy
network as at least one other board member: they are less likely to be
fired in the event of poor performance and, if they are dismissed, they
tend to find another job that is at least as lucrative as the previous
one. Another observation which is just as disturbing, the French
'old boys' network from the elite political science school,
ENA, has appropriated the power in all the main financial institutions,
generating a clear competitive edge for executives from the same school
in terms of political indebtedness with regard to their peers. (11)
A further governance mechanism weakness observed by the IFA
(Institut Frangais des Administrateurs) arises from the board
member-shareholder relationship which is often limited to discussions
during the general assembly, and only then when board members are
present. In an attempt to remedy this weakness, the IFA put forward
proposals for a better relationship between board members and
shareholders in May 2007. These proposals not only reflect shareholder
interests in the way the Board is run, but also take into consideration
board members' involvement in communication between the listed
company and its shareholders outside of the general assembly.
III. A GOVERNANCE CRISIS IN FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS
The subprime crisis bore out Levine's argument (2004) that
bank-related crises are largely an outcome of poor bank governance. He
added that well-managed banks run their operations more efficiently.
Governance problems in financial institutions mainly concern four areas:
risk management and the internal control system, definition of strategy,
the independence and competence of board members, and executive and
trader compensation. In this section, we look in turn at these four
governance issues, although it is often quite difficult to separate
them. We begin with the central point, namely risk management, followed
by the makeup of the Board of Directors, as this influences the
compensation system, as well as the design and monitoring process of the
organisation's strategy.
A. Risk Control
One of the conclusions drawn by the BIS regarding the financial
crisis was that internal and external banking controls failed during the
period in question. Indeed, even the stress scenarios traditionally used
in banking risk management, particularly for asset and liability
management, apparently failed to indicate the extent of the risks being
run. Banks therefore need to review their risk management model in order
to integrate extreme risks arising from crisis events. Economists from
international regulatory bodies consider internal bank control
procedures as structural obstacles that are far more significant in
developing countries than in the industrialised countries. And yet it
was in the latter, particularly those subjected to Basel II regulations,
that the downturn hit hardest. There are five main reasons for this:
1. Excessive risk-taking intensified by leveraging. Leveraging both
for loans and investments (particularly via derivatives) enabled the
leading banks to considerably increase their profits, which more than
doubled between 2001 and 2006, but which led to risk-taking that was
unsustainable in a crisis, as it required a constant influx of capital
(margin call) or else winding up their positions during a period of
considerable financial market illiquidity.
2. The use of poorly-adapted risk measurement tools like VaR (value
at risk). Risk measurement operations recommended by Basel II to
evaluate market operators' equity capital requirements are based on
the concept of VaR. As modelling for most future events, like security
price evolutions, volatility, etc., are made from relatively stable
records (with normal probability distribution models, for example), this
fails to take sufficient account of extreme risks.
3. A rise in the number of complex products and below line
operations. The development of products like ABS, CDO and CDS that are
more difficult to assess, as well as the creation of Special Investment
Vehicles mean that all internal controls are ineffective.
4. Less power in the back office than in the front office, even
though former is supposed to check its operations and monitor the risks
being taken. A new balance of power between these two entities appears
vital if crises are to be better dealt with, and any potential fraud
uncovered in time (see the Kerviel affair at Societe Generale (12)).
Back office jobs in banks should also be reviewed so as to attract staff
as highly qualified as those in the front office.
5. A redefinition of the role of internal and external auditors.
External auditors are especially important in the control chain because
they complement internal control mechanisms. During the present crisis,
they did not keep as close an eye on the banks' practices as they
should have done, no doubt because their interests were too close. In
this context, the European Economic and Social Committee (EESC)
recommend examining the possibility of paying them differently.
B. Independence and Competence of Board Members
One of the key areas of debate on governance concerns the
composition (size and relationship between internal and external board
members) and the competence of the Board of Directors. Agency theory
minimised the role of internal board members, considering that they do
not have enough power to go against decisions made by the CEO, given
their hierarchical dependence on the latter.
Thus, a Board of Directors made up of a large number of external
members is considered to have greater clout and to be more objective
with regard to management. Board members are thus considered as
arbitrators who, among other things, are expected to resolve any
conflicts that may arise between different corporate partners. Board
member independence is crucial for effective control, and guarantees, on
the one hand, that there is no collusion between the CEO and the board
members, and on the other hand, the real capacity to oppose more
questionable decisions.
In similar vein, Kamran et al. (2006) explain the positive link
between the proportion of external board members and the firm's
value by the fact that a large number of independent members on the
Board of Directors increases the probability that financial information
will be monitored effectively, and enhances the quality of external
information. Resources theory reaches a similar conclusion. The Board of
Directors is considered to have a service provider role, particularly
external board members, thereby acknowledging its usefulness as a
strategic resource for the firm, with a positive impact on performance
(Mace, 1986). Thus, the capacity of the Board to formulate and implement
successful strategies by developing adequate internal supervision
mechanisms to monitor the work of its managers, and provide all the
stakeholders with accurate information, acts as a cornerstone to the
firm's global performance. However, the CEO is also able to
manipulate board member independence. In effect, in some banks, we see
that the same CEO has headed the organisation for several years, but
that every 2 years or so he or she changes the team, or influences the
composition of the Board by appointing former influential CEOs with no
financial experience.
The case of Lehman Brothers is a good illustration of this type of
governance problem. The firm was declared bankrupt on 15 September 2008.
Its Board of Directors was made up of ten independent members. (13)
However, we might well ask whether they could really be considered
independent and if they truly understood the business model. In effect,
six members had been on the Board for over twelve years. They were all
either retired or had been working for over forty years. Only one of
them was specialised in finance and he was relatively elderly (79).
Consequently, their ability to understand and manage the risks taken by
the institution, or complex products like CDS, is open to considerable
doubt.
C. Executives and Traders Compensation
Bank executive and traders' compensation has been widely
criticised during the economic crisis, for two reasons in particular,
namely, the amounts of money involved and the link with bank performance
and its monitoring by the governance bodies.
With regard to the first point, while it may be logical to pay CEOs
largely on the basis of their contribution to the firm's
performance, we need to examine their real contribution very carefully,
as well as the performance indicators used and the amount awarded. In
effect, executive pay is calculated as if the entire corporate
performance was due to their actions and decisions alone. In addition,
the executive performance indicator most frequently used is share-price
return, even though this may also be an outcome of macroeconomic factors. If this scenario is arguable for industrial firms, it is even
more so for banks. Magnan and St-Onge (2008), for example, observed that
between 1998 and 2008, 90% of the stock price trends for five of the
leading Canadian banks could be explained by banking sector factors.
Less than 10% of the differences in these banks' share performance
were due to factors specific to the individual banks, such as the
CEO's decisions and initiatives, and a wide range of other factors
like staff, client base, location and business mix.
Similarly, Proxinvest (14) showed that in real terms,
executives' pay is well over their basic salary. The latter depends
on a range of criteria specific to the firm like its size, workforce,
stock market capitalisation, value creation for its shareholders and
return on capital. In 2006, the disparity between basic salary and final
income for the CEO of Business Objects was 441.4%.
To put this into perspective, while the average US executive salary
was 40 times that of a worker in the 1970s, today it is over 400 times.
In 2006, a CAC 40 executive in France earned the equivalent of 298 times
the SMIC (minimum salary) on average.
Given that traders can put their institution at risk, and with the
present incentives culture, the issue of traders' compensation is
even more difficult to justify. 5% of the best paid traders earned
116,000 Euros in fixed salary and 1.32 million Euros in the form of an
annual bonus in 1998, in other words 1138% of their basic salary. In
fact, traders pay is linked to the convex incentives theory. It is
similar to a call option because if their performance is poor or
negative, they only receive their basic salary, but over a certain
threshold, their bonuses increase exponentially in relation to their
performance. Thus, by increasing the volatility of their performance,
the value of their option increases substantially. This goes a long way
to explaining the risks they are willing to take, and why they
don't hesitate to sidestep internal control procedures when
necessary, as illustrated by the "Kerviel affair" at Societe
Generale.
Moreover, it is sometimes possible for traders to manipulate the
calculation of bonuses based on potential earnings (i.e., by
manipulating the yield curve, which increases the potential gains
calculated with mark-to-market type models).
Criticism can also be levelled at tools used to encourage good
management, like stock options, for example, as they can also be
misappropriated. In effect, stock options imply absolute confidence in
market efficiency (in other words, considering that it's impossible
to manipulate the market), transparent stock award conditions (see the
stock options backdating scandal in the USA (15)), and fairness, as well
as strict utilisation conditions. However, there are many examples of
CEOs who sell off their stocks options as soon as there's a whiff
of trouble, without mentioning possible insider trading (see AMF enquiry
on EADS (16)).
The second point concerns compensation controls. Here again, the
credit crunch has highlighted numerous issues that can only be resolved
at global level, going beyond the framework of corporate governance.
What is needed is truly independent compensation committees and members.
However, this is far from evident in France, given the way the
organisations' capital is structured and the number of
inter-connected board members, despite the adoption of governance codes
of good conduct (Chabi and Maati, 2006). Finally, certain issues, like
limiting traders' bonuses, demand a political response at
international level, given the systemic risk that operators face in all
economies, the incapacity of the finance sector to regulate its own
affairs in this area, and competitive distortions that could arise by
limiting bonuses in some countries only. Controls should therefore
include a mix of hard law (the law) and soft law (reinforcement of
corporate governance via shareholder supervision).
D. Defining the Strategy
Bank governance has been criticized for the way its strategy is
defined. This issue is closely linked to the independence and competence
of the board members, who must have the will and the capacity to counter
decisions made by the CEO. The business model of leading American and
European banks, defined by their governance, is based on that of the
universal bank where the size factor is predominant, as well as on
market operations to boost profitability. Before the current economic
downturn, between 1/3 and 2/3 of the major banks' income came from
opaque activities like operations in the derivatives markets. The search
for growth "at any cost" has certainly not ended with the
downturn. In October 2007, RBS, Santander and Fortis decided to buy ABN
Amro, when all the financiers knew that it held over 10 billion dollars
in toxic assets. The downturn led to the dismantling of Fortis one year
later, following the acquisition of most of its assets by the Dutch
government and BNP Paribas. This begs the question as to why these
growth strategies are adopted. Fortis would surely have done better to
focus on its own problems in October 2007, rather than to buy out a
competitor in a worse state than itself. Likewise, Bank of America bought Merrill Lynch when the latter was harbouring over 50 billion
dollars of toxic assets. One of the reasons behind strategies may also
lie in executive compensation, which is largely dependent on the size of
the firm, leading executives to place more value on their human capital,
even if no global value is created for the firm. Here again, incentives
are convex, particularly if letting go of an executive is combined with
a "golden handshake."
IV. CONCLUSION
In the leading listed companies, governance is generally perceived
as a means of control rather than as a tool to support the main
strategic drivers. Changes in governance mechanisms have been such in
the last few years that some listed companies prefer to delist in order
to avoid the many constraints due to regulations introduced to protect
minority shareholders. These changes have also made it more difficult at
times for organisations to recruit the board members they need.
Consequently, Boards need to introduce governance rules that are adapted
to their firm, ensuring that their application is not simply a formal
exercise but rather gives rise to the genuine development of 'good
governance' principles throughout the corporate culture. The
subprime crisis highlighted numerous weaknesses in industrial and
commercial organisations although these can be resolved relatively
easily. In the case of banks, however, serious questions have been
raised about their governance mechanisms. In effect, risk control, the
competence and independence of board members, the system of
executives' and traders' compensation, and the way the
strategy is defined need to be thoroughly reviewed in order to avoid
situations like the subprime crisis from reoccurring in a few years
time. This would have the added bonus of making banks more efficient.
While reforms, such as strengthening board members' independence
and competencies, and introducing compensation controls, appear simple
at first sight, adopting them is far more difficult as they require an
articulation and a delicate balance between hard law and soft law.
It is obvious though that one year after the beginning of the
crisis marked by the collapse of Lehman Brothers, nothing has
fundamentally changed. Banks do not really want to change their
governance system, even if the risks remain, and the G20 governments are
finding it hard to agree on common reforms. In addition, surviving
banks, like the Bank of America, have become even bigger, and their size
implicitly confers on them state backing as the failure of such large
banking institutions would automatically lead us into a systemic banking
sector crisis.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Agrawal, A., and C.R. Knoeber, 1996, "Firm Performance and
Mechanisms to Control Agency Problems between Managers and
Shareholders," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,
September, 377-397.
Aguilera, R., and A. Cuervo-Cazurra, 2004, "Codes of Good
Governance Worldwide: What is the Trigger?" Organization Studies,
Vol.25, no3, 415-443.
Alexander, H., and M. Paquerot, 2000, "Efficacite des
Structures de Controle et Enracinement des Dirigeants," Finance,
Controle, Strategie, Vol.3, no 2, 5-29.
Amir, L., 2007, "Les Pratiques de Gouvernance et A Performance
des Entreprises Franchises," XVIeme Conference Internationale de
Management Strategique, Montreal, 6-9 juin.
Andre, P., and E. Schiehll, 2004, "Systemes de Gouvernance,
Actionnaires Dominants et Performance Future des Entreprises,"
Finance Controle Strategie, Vol. 7, no 2, 165-193.
Bhagat, S., and B. Black, 1999, "The Uncertain Relationship
between Board Composition and Firm Performance," The Business
Lawyer, May, Vol. 54, no 3, 921-963.
Bhagat, S., and B. Black, 2002, "The Non-correlation between
Board Independence and Long Term Performance," Journal of
Corporation Law, Winter, Vol. 27, no 2, 231273.
Bai, C.E., Q. Liu, J. Lu, F.M. Song, and J. Zhang, 2003,
"Corporate Governance and Markets Valuation in China," Journal
of Comparative Economics, Vol. 32, no 4, 599-825.
Barkema, H.G., and L.R. Gomez-Mejia, 1998, "Managerial
Remuneration and Firm Performance: A General Research Framework,"
Academy of Management Journal, April, Vol. 41, no 2, 135-145.
Black, B., H. Jang, and W. Kim, 2003, "Does Corporate
Governance Affect Firms' Market Values? Evidence from Korea,"
Working paper 237, Stanford Law School, John M. Olin Program in Law and
Economics.
Campos, C.E., R.E. Newell, and G. Wilson, 2002, "Corporate
Governance Develops in Emerging Markets," McKinsey on Finance,
15-18.
Chabi, S., and J. Maati, 2005, "Les Reseaux du CAC 40,"
La Revue du Financier, no 153, 45-62.
Chabi, S., and J. Maati, 2006, "The Small World of the CAC
40," Banque et Marches, no 82, 41-53.
Charreaux, G., 1991, "Structure de Propriete, Relation
d'Agence et Performance Financiere," Revue Economique, Vol.
42, no 3, 521-552.
Charreaux, G., 1997, "Vers Une Theorie du Gouvernement des
Entreprises," in G.
Charreaux, Le Gouvernement des Entreprises, Economica, 121-164.
Core, J.E., R.W. Holthausen, and D. Larker, 1999, "Corporate
Governance, Chief Executive Officer Remuneration, and Firm
Performance," Journal ofFinancial Economics, March, Vol.51, no 3,
371-406.
Daily, C.M., D.R. Dalton, J.L. Johnson, and A.E. Ellshand, 1999,
"Number of Directors and Financial Performance: A
Meta-analysis," Academy of Management Journal, Vol. 42, no 6,
674-686.
Dalton, D.R., C.M. Daily, A.E. Ellstrand, et J.L. Johnson, 1998,
"Meta-analytic Reviews of Board Composition, Leadership Structure,
and Financial Performance," Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 19,
no 3, March, 269-290.
Drobetz, W., A. Schillhofer, and H. Zimmermann, 2003,
"Corporate Governance and Expected Stock Return: Evidence from
Germany," Working Paper, available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=369100.
Gagnon, J.M., and J. St-Pierre, 1995, "Alternative Mechanisms
for Corporate Governance and Board Composition," in J.D. Ronald et
R. Morck, Corporate Decision-Making in Canada, University of Calgary
Press, 149-188.
Gompers, P., J.L. Ishi, and M. Andrew, 2003, "Corporate
Governance and Equity Prices," Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol.
118, No. 1, 107-155.
Gugler, K., D.C. Mueller, and B.B. Yurtoglu, 2003, "Corporate
Governance and the Return on Investment," Working Paper, available
at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract_id=299520.
Hermalin, B.E., and M.S. Weisbach, 1991, "The Effect of Board
Composition and Direct Incentives on Firm Performance," Financial
Management, Vol. 20, no 4, 101-112.
Jensen, M., and W. Meckling, 1976, "The Theory of the Firm:
Managerial Behaviour, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure,"
Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 3, 305-360.
Kramarz, F., and D. Thesmar, 2006, "Social Networks in the
Boardroom," Discussion Paper 5496, CEPR.
Lawrence, J., and G.P. Stapledon, 1999, "Is Board Compensation
Important? A Study of Listed Australian Firms," Working Paper,
University of Melbourne.
Maati, J., 2008, "Reseaux d'Administrateurs et
Performance Financiere des Grandes Entreprises en France: Une Revue de
la Literature," Revue Frangaise de Gouvernance d'Entreprises,
no 3, 145-161.
McKinsey, and Compagny, 2002, "Global Investor Opinion Survey:
Key Findings," London (http://www.mckinsey.com/governance).
Nguyen-Dang, B., 2006, "Does the Rolodex Matter? Corporate
Elite's Small World and Effectiveness of Boards of Director,"
Conference EFA Zurich Meetings Paper, available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=864184.
Paquerot, M., and J-M. Chapuis, 2006, "Reseaux
d'Appartenance des Dirigeants et Structures Financieres de Leurs
Entreprises," Conference AFFI, Poitiers.
Pochet, C, and H. Yeo, 2004, "Les Comites Specialises des
Entreprises Francaises Cotees : Mecanismes de Gouvernance ou Simples
Dispositifs Esthetiques ?" Comptabilite, Controle, Audit, Vol. 2,
no 10, 31-54.
Siala, F., 2007, "Interaction des Mecanismes Internes de
Gouvernement d'entreprise et Effet sur la Performance," Revue
Frangaise de Gouvernance d'Entreprises, no 2, 59-82.
Stuart, S., 2007, "President Directeur General ou President et
Directeur General," Revue Frangaise de Gouvernance
d'Entreprises, no 1, 27-34.
Tchotourian, I., 2007, "Une Approche Comparee de
l'Encadrement Normatif de la Remuneration des Dirigeants de
Societes Cotees ou La Definition de la Bonne Gouvernance par le
Droit," Revue Frangaise de Gouvernance d'Entreprises, no 2,
39-55.
Thiery-Dubuisson, S., 2002, "Exigences Actionnariales et
Reseaux d'Administrateurs : a Quoi Repond la Mise en Place des
Comites d'Audit en France?" Comptabilite, Controle, Audit,
Vol. 1, no 8, 129-150.
Wirtz, P., 2004, "Meilleures Pratiques de Gouvernance, Theorie
de la Firme et Modeles de Creation de Valeur : Une Appreciation Critique
des Codes de Bonne Conduite," Cahier du FARGO no 1040401.
Worell, D.L., C. Nemec, and W.N. Davidson, 1997, "One Hat Too
Many: Key Executive Plurality and Shareholder Wealth," Strategic
Management Journal, Vol.18, no 6, 499-507.
Yermack, D., 1997, "Higher Market Valuation of Companies with
a Small Board of Directors," Journal of Financial Economics, Vol.
40, 185-211.
ENDNOTES
(1.) This article adopts the traditional legal-financial vision of
governance and shareholder role, and addresses the issue of the
cognitive role of shareholders.
(2.) And also Bhagat and Black (1999)
(3.) Yermack (1996) obtained similar results.
(4.) See Barkema and Gomez-Mejia (1998); Core et al. (1999) for a
discussion of this area of research.
(5.) See Tchotourian (2007) for more information.
(6.) Published in La Tribune on 29/10/2008. Also see:
http://tf1.lci.fr/infos/economie/entreprises/0"3468360,00-patrons-francais- roiseurope-handshake-dore-.html
(7.) Jean-Marie Messier left Vivendi in July 2002 when the company
was on the verge of bankruptcy. His last salary was 5.6 million Euros,
up 10% compared to the previous year. At the same time, Vivendi chalked
up a net loss of 23 billion Euros. When he resigned, Jean-Marie Messier
asked for an additional 20.5 million Euro golden handshake.
(8.) Board members do not feel that their salary reflects the risks
they run.
(9.) See Chabi and Maati (2005, 2006) for their studies on CAC40
from 1996 to 2004.
(10.) See Kramarz and Thesmard (2006).
(11.) See Nguyen-Dang (2006) and Paquerot and Chapuis (2006) for a
discussion on the subject.
(12.) http://online.wsj.com/article/SB125174436208573389.html
(13.) http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Lehman_Brothers#Board_of_Directors
(14.) http://www.proxinvest.com/index.php/fr/news/read/60.html
SMIC: Salaire minimum interprofessionnel de croissance
(http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Minimum_wage)
(15.) "Testimony given concerning options backdating,
Christopher Cox, U.S. Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban
Affairs", 2006, September 6,
www.sec.gov/news/testimony/2006/ts090606cc.htm.
(16.) www.amf-france.org/documents/general/7154_1 .pdf
Jean-Michel Sahuta and Sandrine Boulerneb
[a] Professor, Amiens School of Management & CEREGE EA 1722
University of Poitiers, France
[email protected]
[b] Assistant Professor, CERMAT, IAE of Tours &ESCEM, France
[email protected]