ERP diffusion and mimetic behaviors.
Leroux, Erick ; Pupion, Pierre-Charles ; Sahut, Jean-Michel 等
I. INTRODUCTION
The emergence of enterprise resource planning systems (ERP) has
often been presented as one of the main factors of organizational change
within companies in the course of the last few years (Robey, 2002). It
presents companies with new opportunities and new challenges as ERP
systems are configurable, modular and integrated computer applications
whose aim is to optimize a firm's business process via a single
referential and standardized business rules. Prior research has mainly
addressed the conditions for successful ERP implementations. In our
opinion, it has tended to ignore the fundamental issue of the conditions
surrounding ERP adoption and diffusion. ERP systems are generally
considered as major innovations. Taking innovation to be an idea, a
practice or an object perceived as new by an individual or an
organization (Rogers, 1995), its diffusion within large and midsize
French companies consequently needs to be accounted for. In its simplest
sense, diffusion can be defined as "the process whereby an
innovation spreads itself' (Morvan, 1991). Some scholars
differentiate between studies on the "adoption" of innovation
and those on its "diffusion". Whereas adoption theories
evaluate the characteristics that make an organization receptive to
innovation, diffusion theories seek to comprehend why and how innovation
is taken up and spreads (Kimberly, 1981). However, following
Chatterjee's and Eliasshberg's analyses (1990), we surmise
that, for a given population, diffusion implies the adoption of an
innovation by the individuals affiliated to it. The most common
definition of diffusion is that of Rogers (1995) who regards it as
"a process whereby an innovation is going to be progressively
communicated through certain channels to the members of a social
system." As Mahajan (1990) points out, this definition emphasizes
four critical elements: the innovation, channels of communication, a
time element, and a social system. The innovation diffusion process cannot therefore be regarded as an isolated phenomenon operating at the
level of one individual, but rather as a social event that involves a
whole array of actors belonging to a specific community. While Rogers
identifies the various influences in the diffusion process among members
of the social system in question, he still follows a socio-rational
approach as his main focus is on the objective characteristics of the
innovation to account for its adoption. Most of the work on the adoption
and diffusion of innovation revolves around the characteristics that
would ease or slow down its adoption. Yet, it could be assumed, as Alter
suggests (1996), that "the diffusion of an innovation does not
represent any economic logic but more of a series of decisions made in a
situation of high uncertainty. " In a context of uncertainty,
imitation should be given a central role. The mimetic chains theory
points to a path that ascribes a central role to informational
imitation, as individuals seek to evaluate their opinion on the net
benefits of innovation by comparing them with the positions taken by
others.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 1 will
introduce the various diffusion analyses that depart from the
traditional concept of a purely rational choice in an effort to
integrate the influences occurring among members of the social system
and the effects of imitation. In Section II, a statistical study based
on a survey of large and midsize French companies will demonstrate that
EPR adoption does not occur solely as the result of a rational
calculation but is indeed the result of the influence of the social
system on an agent, the latter being at times under the pull of mimetic
behaviors.
II. THEORITICAL ANALYSIS OF THE DIFFUSION PROCESS: FROM RATIONAL TO
MIMETIC ADOPTION
Synthetically taking up the theoretical frameworks of the
neoclassical and socio-rational analyses as well as of those on mimetic
chains and adoption, we make a number of hypotheses on ERP adoption and
diffusion. These analyses correspond to different visions of an
individual in his or her social milieu. They can be summarized by the
following maxim: "From an isolated agent to a communicating agent
under the influence of its social milieu."
A. Neo-Classical Analysis of A Company's ERP Adoption: An
Isolated Agent's Calculation
Traditional economic theory (Menger, 1892; Walras, 1874) argues
that people are rational and attempt to maximize their own utility
(Smith, 1776). Enjoying perfect information and acting with regard to a
future known with virtual certainty, they are, still according to traditional economic theory, "optimizing individuals" who
maximize their profit. Von Neuman and Morgensten (1944) have extended
this analysis to situations where the only thing an agent knows of the
future is the distribution of probabilities regarding possible events.
In a situation of so-called "risky future", a decider is aware
of all the possible options that ought to be taken into consideration.
He or she can evaluate their consequences and, comparing them under the
criterion of expected utility, select the option that maximizes it. Such
rationality, termed utilitarian, is based on the principle of a
subjective assessment of costs and benefits weighed by their
distribution of probability. An autonomous decisional unit, an
agent's behavior is not conditioned by consciously or unconsciously
assimilated social habits. The choices of others have no impact on their
behavior (independence of the preference functions).
Within this framework, ERP adoption is an investment to be made if
it creates wealth. An investment opportunity is evaluated according to
the level of wealth it will create, assessed with the various tools and
criteria available under neoclassical financial theory such as the net
actual value criterion (NAV). Investment sub-optimality is measured in
relation to the maximization of a firm's value as stipulated by
modern financial theory. The purpose of this theory is not so much to
account for investment decisions but rather to prescribe normative rules
to select optimal investments. Charreaux (1999) provides a perfect
summary of the nature of this traditional theory: "In its
traditional form, the neoclassical financial theory is nothing but a
normative investment choice theory that merely offers a monetary
evaluation of investments or, more exactly, of the stakes of the holders
involved. Under the value of the stakes criterion, the agent supposed to
decide--the designation of the decider being itself exogenous--chooses
within a given set, investment projects whose value is determined in
relation to purely technical imperatives and to the state of the
environment."
Hypothesis 1: ERP adoption is the choice of an isolated agent who,
under the financial theory, makes an optimization calculation.
This microeconomic analysis incorporates substantial shortcomings.
It does not accurately depict the real behaviors of agents who are in
situations of "limited rationality" (Simon, 1957) because of
"reduced cognitive capacities," imperfect information and
difficulties associated with the treatment of uncertainty. Furthermore,
individuals are not isolated; they belong to a social milieu from which
they generally derive their benchmarks.
B. Socio-Rational Analysis
Under the socio-rational concept of diffusion whose prevailing
diffusion model is that of Rogers (1995), diffusion is promoted by the
characteristics of the innovation (see Schumpeter for a taxonomy), as
well as those of the adopters, their social systems and their milieu.
Innovation will be adopted only where the individuals concerned are
convinced of the interest or the gains they may derive from it, given
the information at their disposal. Indeed, for Rogers, any decision
pertaining to the adoption of innovation, which will also determine its
diffusion, is essentially based on an adopter's perception of the
innovation. This is an idiosyncratic and rational approach that defines
the best way for a decisional unit to attain the target goal. It is a
sequential stage process in the course of which an individual or a
decisional unit move from an initial introduction to the innovation (1),
to the formation of an attitude toward it (2), to the decision to adopt
or reject it (3), to the realization of the new idea (4) and finally, to
confirmation of the decision to adopt (5).
[TABLE 1 OMITTED]
Zaltman et al. (1973) refer to Rogers' first two stages as the
initiation phase. In the course of the first stage, individuals will
seek to become acquainted with the novelty, its functionalities and pros
and cons and will subsequently form their own opinion of it. This will
enable them to articulate an attitude to adopt. During this phase,
innovation is mostly evaluated by the decisional unit. The last phase,
termed the implementation phase, includes the realization and
confirmation stages. In the course of the first of these stages, the
realization stage, the innovation will be implemented.
Subsequently, a decisional unit will be able to confirm it as a new
practice. On the other hand, it is always possible to abandon the
innovation after its initial use. It is in this sense that Rogers
defines adoption as "the decision to make full use of innovation as
the best practice available."
Under the socio-rational concept, the social system plays a
critical role in the diffusion process. The diffusion of innovation is
assimilated with a communication activity in the course of which
information regarding a new idea is shared among previously informed and
non-informed members. The two main channels of communication are the
mass media, the fastest way to reach others, and interpersonal channels,
based on direct relationships among individuals. According to Frambach
and Schillewaert (2002), the involvement of decisional units in an
information network facilitates the spread of information on innovation
as well as its adoption. Innovation surfaces within a social system and
it is also within a social system that the diffusion process takes
place. Lind and Zmud (1991) stress that added interaction among members
of a social system increases the speed at which innovation is adopted as
well as its rate of adoption. In particular, they insist on the
perceived characteristics of innovation to explain the probability and
speed of innovation diffusion within the social system (Gatignon and
Robertson, 1985). These elements play a fundamental role during the
persuasion stage in the course of which the decisional unit assesses
whether or not to adopt the innovation. Rogers and Shoemaker (1971)
argue that the evaluation of innovation by potential adopters involves
five attributes:
* A relative advantage or "perceived utility," which is
the degree of superiority of an innovation over other existing
innovations.
* Compatibility, which determines the degree of coherence with the
values and previous experiences of individuals.
* Complexity or "ease of use," which represents the
degree of difficulty in understanding or using innovation.
* Testability or the possibility, whether small or strong, of
trying out innovation in a limited way.
* Observability, which determines the degree of visibility of
innovation by others.
Several studies have established empirical ties between the
perceived attributes and the adoption of innovation. Davis (1989) and
Adams (1992), for example, found a significant link between
"relative advantage," "ease of use" and the adoption
of technological innovations. As part of a meta-analysis, Tornatzky and
Klein (1982) noted that three characteristics (compatibility, relative
advantage and complexity) have a substantial impact on the adoption of
innovations. While the first two attributes facilitate adoption,
complexity slows it down. Ostlund (1974) suggests adding "perceived
risks" to these characteristics insofar as anything novel conveys
uncertainty. In our opinion, this is included in the
"complexity" attribute which takes hesitation due to novelty
into account.
Hypothesis 2: The perceived characteristics of innovation determine
a decider's adoption behavior.
A review of the management research literature highlights the
relative advantages of an ERP system, its compatibility with the logic
of the supply chains strategy, its complexity and the risks associated
with the project. ERP-related advantages are technical, operational and
strategic. Businesses adopt ERP packages in order to benefit from
inter-functional homogeneity, and to have a one and only similar system
with a one and only similar database, a similar man-hardware interface
for all workstations and a single administrative system for the various
applications. Adoption puts an end to possible data incompatibilities
(data re-entering. ...). It also puts an end to existing parallel
systems which tend to duplicate the same functionalities as a result of
the acquisition of separate software for each autonomous unit. It cuts
down interface maintenance tasks and reduces the complexity of the
information system architecture. ERP modularity and broad exportability,
at operating system level as well as at the levels of the database
management system or network, enable businesses to upgrade their
information systems more easily. They can thus make do with the modules
corresponding to their initial needs and subsequently improve their
information system by acquiring new complementary modules. The time-span
for the installation of a module varies greatly, requiring at least 6 to
8 months; 2 to 5 years are required for the installation of the main
modules (finance, accounting, cost control, purchase, sales, logistics,
manufacturing and human resources). However, the simultaneous deployment
of different modules may be faster in the case of a Big Bang installation, reserved for very large organizations. Unlike traditional
applications that have a limited life span, ERP systems are standard
software that evolves continually as new upgraded versions regularly
come out.
Relative advantages are also organizational, with ERP systems
challenging organizational concepts based on functional specializations.
The analytical unit is no longer the function regrouping similar
activities but the process running across a company's main
functions (Davenport and Short, 1990). The organization is no longer
divided into large functions but becomes transversal with
macro-processes that run across it. From an operational standpoint,
companies can expect lower operating costs, productivity gains (McAffe,
2002) and better registration of orders (fewer redundancies and
simplified data-entering procedures). Adoption facilitates the
acquisition and diffusion of information within and without a company by
removing certain restrictions and making requests easier. It reinforces
operational flexibility, defined as the capacity to deal with inventory
shortages, short-term demand fluctuations and manufacturing issues
related to product modifications, by giving the actors concerned access
to relevant information and enabling them to communicate among
themselves to make the necessary adjustments when faced with a problem.
Advantages may also be strategic. ERP systems improve reactivity to
customer requests (for example, new orders) by impacting in real time on
the entire production system of the activities and functions concerned
(manufacturing and supply planning).
A review of the literature, notably Bingi et al., (1999) points to
the complexity of ERP implementation and its attendant risks. The
authors note that the scope of ERP system applications, their complexity
and high level of integration present the organizations that put them in
place with significant challenges. Apart from the risk of overspending
and not meeting deadlines (CIO survey mentioned by Cosgrove, 2001),
dissatisfied users and a poor quality system is also a risk as a result
of implementation. To configure ERP software, the project team and users
must have broad expertise. So much so that many studies report the lack
of in-house expertise as a main source of failure (Barki et al., 1993;
Scott and Vessey, 2002). Relying on software experts or appropriate
training to improve the level of in-house expertise or to remedy
users' lack of experience (Schmidt et al., 2001) is very costly.
With regard to the software adaptations required, the lack of ERP system
flexibility (Bancroft et al., 1998) and the significant gap between the
targeted process and the process encrypted in the software may well be
sources of risk and undesired results. The scope of the changes required
in the light of the process envisioned is another source of risks
(Bancroft et al., 1998).
Adoption is compatible with a supply-chain approach. The flow of
products, services and funds along the value chain generates a
significant mass of information that can be used to make decisions with
regard to value-chain management. To ensure that the information is
relevant, reliable and accessible in time and place, there needs be
adequate information technology architecture. While the first generation
of ERP adoptions were limited to one site and the second involved
implementations on several sites of a same firm, the third generation
focuses on coordinating implementation on several sites and in several
companies. Such systems must have the capacity to communicate along the
value-chain with business organization systems as well as with
individual customers using different platforms. The components needed
for supply chain management include request applications, inventory
management systems, planning and launching production systems, planning
and launching transportation systems, customer relations management
systems and automatic sales force management. Some applications combine
several phases of the value chain. Evaluation of ERP performance by
managers and CFOs is done from a benchmarking perspective that enables
them to compare their current information system with the best ERP
systems in terms of specific functions (accounting, sales,
logistics...). Firms can collect ERP information from adopting or
non-adopting companies and from outside advisers such as organizational
consulting firms or pre-sale computer engineering consultants. The
latter can even organize on-site introductory sessions. While the
socio-rational theory takes the social system members' influence
into account, other theories include the observation that the choices
made show signs of mimetism.
C. Mimetic Chain and Innovation Diffusion
The postulates of a neoclassical analysis have thus shown their
limits since rationality cannot be omniscient. The analysis is limited,
a rational decision being no more than an ideal which has nothing to do
with the reality of facts (Simon, 1957). Given that interactions among
agents or organizations mutually influence their decisions through
imitative behaviors that have nothing rational about them within the
precepts of the neoclassical theory; a window is therefore open for
irrationality to come into play. As Le Bon writes (1911), "for each
of our acts, the unconscious part is immense and that of reason very
tiny." Mimetism can thus be a highly relevant concept in accounting
for certain economic phenomena, and is at the basis of many major
current business science theories.
This is the case with the theory of organizational learning, for
example, according to which certain organizations imitate others,
letting the former absorb the experimentation and research costs (Lant
and Mezias, 1990), or with institutional theory which stipulates that
organizations seeking legitimacy copy practices adopted by others (Di
Maggio and Powell, 1983).
An analysis of the diffusion process does not escape the logic of
imitation either. As early as 1903, Tarde (1890) was already talking
about "imitation laws." The diffusion of innovation takes
place among individuals belonging to a specific social milieu. In this
context, interactions among these decisional units create influential
situations in which the behavior of some is likely to be conditioned by
those of others. Generally, innovation spreads within a social milieu
out of mimetism, with some individuals taking decisions after observing
the attitudes of prior adopters.
Mimetism is caused by uncertainty in the face of novelty. In such
conditions, innovation will be adopted mimetically since adoption by the
first adopters will be interpreted as an act from which they draw
benefit in accordance with the information available (Greve and Taylor,
2000). Uncertainty leads deciders to use comparative social motives to
evaluate the new practices adopted by others (Greve, 1998). Burt (1987)
defines the conditions under which these contagion phenomena occur among
individuals. Behavior contagion implies the existence, on the one hand,
of an individual or so-called ego, who has not yet adopted novelty and,
on the other, that of another, socalled alter, who, on the contrary, has
already taken it on board. Social structures will operate in such a way
as to create circumstances between these two individuals that make the
alter sensitive to the ego's evaluation of innovation. Such
circumstances may be competitive situations, interpersonal communication or any other contact that brings the alter closer to the ego.
This is informational mimetism, where one person imitates another
because they are assumed to be better informed (Deutsch and Gerard,
1955). The first person will try to evaluate their beliefs and opinions
by comparing them with those of their reference group (Festinger, 1950
and 1954) and will conform to the former all the more should they have
doubts about their own expertise (Hochbaum, 1954) and need to deal with
a difficult or ambiguous task.
Deciders in a situation of uncertainty will therefore end up
observing the adoption behavior of other members of their community. On
the basis of their observations, they will thus develop their own
behavior by aligning with the practices of others. Imitation occurs
insofar as innovation adoption by a decision-making unit increases the
probability of others doing the same (Greve, 1998). Several innovation
diffusion models informed by research on the epidemiological spread of
diseases have been developed on the basis of this mimetic hypothesis.
Mansfield's model (1961) in economics, and that of Bass (1969) in
marketing, are the most renowned.
The mimetic chain theories whose reference model is that of
Bickhchandani et al. (1998) ascribe the status of a communicator
emitting and receiving informative signals to an agent belonging to a
social system. Hirshleifer (1995) notes that the way information is
conveyed among various individuals can take different forms as
individuals can observe either all the information held by others or the
result of their private calculation or only the actions by firms that
have already made a choice. As actions speak louder than words and
information borne out by actions is the most credible, he argues that
agents only observe positions taken by others before them. When faced
with a choice, agents will form their initial judgment on the basis of
their private information. Among other things, they will observe the
positions taken by other agents before them and infer their opinions.
They may review their opinion if their initial idea is contradicted.
They act out of "pure mimetism" when they rely exclusively on
the positions taken by others.
This mimetic chains model assumes the existence of a sequence of
individuals (see Figure 1 for example), each one opting to adopt or
reject as a result of their private calculations and their observations
of the positions taken by others. To make it simpler, let us assume that
objectively, adopting an innovation is better than rejecting it (in so
far as this decision has higher net advantages than the other
alternatives). Individuals who are neutral to risk make a pros-and-cons
calculation on the basis of their personal information: e.g. from an
advert, an article, talking to an acquaintance. They are sure of their
choice with a probability p and ascribe the same degree of confidence to
the positions taken by others. They compare this private signal with the
positions taken by their predecessors.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
In Figure 1, we observe that the first individual, A, makes a
choice based solely upon their private signal because they are the first
to decide. If A gets signal 'H' favorable to adoption (private
calculation consistent with the correct decision to adopt), A will
adopt; if A gets the contrary signal 'L', A will reject. The
second individual, B, deduces A's private calculation from the
position taken by the latter. If A decides to adopt and B has a private
signal H consistent with A's position, then B will adopt. If, on
the contrary, B's signal is L, then B will infer that there are
equal chances that it is as much in his interest to adopt as it is not
to do so, in other words there are equal chances of the innovation being
adopted by B as there are of it being rejected. The third individual, C,
will adopt innovation as long as A and B have previously adopted, even
if C's private signal L is unfavorable. All it takes for the first
two individuals to initialize an up or down cascade is for both of them
to adopt or, on the contrary, not to adopt. At the close of the first
two choices, the probability of having no cascade is only p (1-p)/ 2 +
p(1-p)/2 = p-[p.sup.2].
Welch's informational cascades describe how rapidly people
converge toward a decision to adopt or not and how the weight of an
individual evaluation on the merits of such and such an emerging idea
diminishes (Bikhchandani et al., 1998). If the first individuals in the
sequence adopt a new product based on its merits, their having adopted
it will provide a signal to other potential adopters. A number of them
will adopt the new product as a result of being influenced, at least in
part, by preceding adopters. As the number of adopters rises, the signal
to other potential adopters becomes increasingly stronger and more and
more of them will adopt. Once the information derived from the decisions
of others begins to exceed an individual's private evaluation, the
process starts gathering momentum or cascading toward conformity among
all deciders. At that point, new adopters convey no additional private
information to the market. Rational individuals will buy
information--get "private signals" in cascade jargon--only up
to the point where the information yields no more net benefits than the
following signals emitted by others.
Contrary to other forms of social conformity, informational
cascades are fragile. Triggered by a small amount of information, they
can also be reversed by new information. A cascade can be broken and
reversed by an individual with a more precise signal because agents know
that the behavior of most individuals carries no information and is
purely imitative (the definition of a cascade). A company can be guided
in its choice to adopt an ERP system by implementations already
completed by its competitors. It can collect information on their
positions while attending inter-professional meetings or industrial
shows or through reading accounts in specialized magazines such as 01
Computer.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Hypothesis 3: The position taken by other companies determines a
decider's adoption behavior.
Hypothesis 3 bis: The position taken by a company depends more on
the positions taken by other companies than on its own private signal
(or private calculation).
III. AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF ERP DIFFUSION: THE DETERMINING
INFLUENCE OF THE SOCIAL SYSTEM
This study on ERP adoption and diffusion focuses on small and
midsize French companies that we asked to describe the conditions and
reasons for adoption or non adoption. We voluntarily excluded companies
that are subject in this particular respect to the decisions of their
holding companies and are therefore not free to make ERP implementation
choices. In this second part, we first introduce the study's
empirical methodology. We then seek to validate the hypotheses
articulated in part one. In the process, we determine the extent to
which the choices are rational or mimetic and how the influence of
others impacts on implementation choices.
A. Developing a Questionnaire and Making Variables Operational
The first stage in the collection of field data for
hypothesis-testing purposes was to put together a questionnaire.
Drafting a questionnaire represents "the instrumentation" of
the study hypotheses, and the questionnaire is the tool with which these
concepts are measured (Thompson, 1987). The choice of a questionnaire as
an empirical investigative tool is justified by the
hypothetical-deductive methodology adopted. Our questionnaire was
organized around the hypotheses, variables and dimensions defined in the
preceding part. The aim was to explore the conditions surrounding ERP
adoption. The questionnaire included essentially close-ended questions
in the form of dichotomies or attitude scales (from Lickert to 7-point
scales). On the basis of the literature review and the interviews given,
we translated the different theoretical concepts and variables into
several indicators or items (annex 1). We verified the internal
coherence of each scale through a factorial analysis conducted with the
Kaiser-Barlett test and Conbrach's alpha coefficient. In keeping
with Perrien's proposals (1984), we accepted a scale whenever alpha
was superior or equal to 0.5.
We made the use-of-financial-tool concept operational by asking the
firms surveyed if they used the NAV, the internal return rate (IRR),
pay-back period or any other tools to decide whether or not to adopt.
Starting with a review of the literature on ERP systems and their
advantages, complexity and compatibility with strategy, we identified
sets of items to identify the various perceived attributes. In order to
confirm the objective dimensions on which CEOs base their choices, we
conducted a principal component analysis (PCA) of the three sets of
advantages. The PCA indicated that CEOs foresee three kinds of benefits
to ERP adoption: strategic, organizational and, given better information
and decision-making management, even operational ones. A second PCA
confirms that impediments to adoption are linked to two dimensions: the
complexity of ERP implementation and the cost of the organizational
changes required. To measure the quality of the information systems and
relevance of ERP watch, we adopted the idea according to which a
representation is relevant if it is appropriate for the action and
satisfies its user (Reix, 1999). Relevance is determined mainly
according to its degree of exhaustiveness, finesse and clarity (or lack
of buzz). We added two other representation characteristics to these two
main ones: richness (an aptitude to translate all aspects of reality)
and reliability. Concerning the analytical method used to validate the
hypotheses, we resorted to non-parametric methods of statistical
inference that indicate probability trends. Unlike a parametric model that presupposes knowing the law pertaining to each observation (except
in the case of large samples), a nonparametric model provides greater
flexibility regarding the possible form and nature of observational
laws. This choice also finds its justification with respect to the
strength of these techniques and their advantages in terms of efficiency
and validity (Lehman, 1975).
B. Study Results
1. The Vision of an Isolated "Maximizing" Agent: A
Narrowing Vision
In keeping with Barbara Farbey's analysis (1994) conducted on
computer investment choices, we observed (see Table 2) that almost half
of the companies surveyed do not quantify project profits and costs. We
can assert that with a 90% level of confidence, the percentage of
companies resorting to a NAV-type financial optimization calculation is
between 18% and 42%, and between 41% and 67% for the IRR. In addition,
it is quite possible that some companies use these rational procedures
somewhat obliquely and resort to this calculation only to justify their
choices.
According to Farbey, Target and Land (1994), it is nonetheless
difficult to quantify the profitability of software projects because of
their extremely broad boundaries, interactions with other changes, and
uncertainty over their life-span, among other things. Some companies
resort to economic calculation methods but a great many of them do
without. Observing in the next paragraph that only a small number of
firms appear to be satisfied with their ERP watch, we believe that the
information collected is not perfect and that choices are thus not
purely rational. Hypothesis 1 is only partially validated. It is
therefore crucial to check whether an agent making a choice is isolated
or whether they belong to a social milieu from which they are drawing
information.
2. A Socio-Rational Realistic Vision
Under a so-called socio-rational perspective, it is essential to
determine the nature of the communication channels used by the members
of this social system and to check if adoption can be accounted for by
the perceived attributes of innovation. In order to identify the extent
to which decisions are based on a pro-and-con analysis, we asked the
CEOs to evaluate the ERP utility (benefits procured), and the
compatibility with their strategies and complexity on a 1 to 7 scale.
On the whole, CEOs have mixed opinions on ERP compatibility with
strategy (with a 90% confidence level, the means is between 4.25 and
4.5) and on strategic benefits. Their positions vary depending on
whether or not they have adopted ERP packages. In keeping with
Rowe's studies (1999), advantages in terms of decision-making and
information management are acknowledged to a far greater extent by all
the actors (with a 90% confidence level, the mean of this scale is
between 4.25 and 4.5). While adopters see ERP systems as opportunities
for organizational change, they all express concerns over the
difficulties inherent in creating the conditions for successful change.
They are particularly concerned about mandatory training costs, hardware
changes and staff resistance to the new software.
In order to determine the impact of these various opinions on
choices, they were cross-checked with the decisions made by firms. As
seen in Table 4, which shows the results of the Wilcoxon-Mann-Whitney
tests, the perception of decision-making, strategic and organizational
advantages is key to the decision on whether or not to adopt an ERP
software package. Our results confirm the existence of empirical links
between the perceived attributes of an innovation and its adoption
(Davis; 1989, and Adams; 1992). Using the Chi2 test, we can conclude
that strategic compatibility and the perceived benefits of innovation
act as facilitating factors in ERP adoption (the significant test levels
are under 1%). On the other hand, we observed no significant
relationship between perceived complexity and a firm's choice.
With regard to the importance of the social system in the diffusion
process, we listed the sources of information whereby the respondents
had heard of ERP packages (see Table 5). The mass media was the most
frequent source--the specialized press, trade fairs and internet--and,
to a lesser extent, in-house and outside advisers such as organizational
consulting firms, computer engineering firms and integrators. This last
source of information is the most significant in the case of adopters,
consequently advisers can be said to play a facilitating role. Outside
advisers operate as filters, capturing information and conveying it to
deciders. The information and advice they impart substantially
influences the decisions made, all the more so if the information and
advice appears exhaustive, simple and clear. By making companies aware
of ERP organizational benefits, organizational consulting firms become
vehicles for adoption. In-house or outside resources available for
information purposes vary from one company to another. Not all companies
enjoy a high-performing business intelligence in IT (as illustrated in
Table 5) based on the quality of their information system. Firms
frequently consider their information efforts as mediocre or even
insufficient (this is true of one in two companies) and the relevance of
the information collected is perceived as average or even weak. The rate
of receival of magazines (mainly) is correlated to the evaluation of a
company's in-house effort to be kept informed on information system
updates.
While the socio-rationale analysis accounts for the choice to opt
for an ERP software to a large extent, the low relevance of the
information collected through the ERP watch nonetheless leaves some
organizations uncertain and, as a result, they do their best to compare
their analyses with the opinions and practices of others when making a
choice.
3. Mimetic Chains and Influence of the Positions Taken by Other
Companies
The results set out in Table 6 indicate that the positions taken by
other companies have a significant influence on their choices. Two out
of three firms acknowledge that their choices were influenced to some
extent by the positions taken by other companies which have or have not
yet adopted ERP systems. Some companies have more influence than others.
More than one in two firms acknowledges being influenced by the
decisions made by the leading firms in their sectors (37% and 63% of the
total firms with a 90% confidence level). The influence of innovative or
high-performing companies is also determinant for almost a third of
them. Geographic proximity, on the other hand is not a determining
factor. In keeping with the mimetic chains theory, the positions
previously taken by certain other firms influence the choices made. One
firm in five reports being influenced by the adoption decision made by
other companies. In accordance with the mimetic chains theory, we reject
the hypothesis of independence between frequency of adoption and the
firm's decision to adopt, as the table below shows.
Our results corroborate those of Webb and Pettigrew (1999) who,
taking a partly neo-institutional approach, show how a strategy
initiated by a leader will spread in the inter-organizational field.
When leading opinion-makers contemplate adopting a strategy for the
first time, their behaviors are subsequently copied by others (Greve
1998). Companies will imitate the actions of firms which, being
successful in the market, benefit from a good image and high prestige
(Burns and Wholey, 1993). An organization's prestige is linked to
its manufacturing efficiency, profitability and growth (Scott, 1992).
Burns and Wholey (1993) and Haveman (1993) show that the most profitable
firms operate as models for others. Companies competing in one sector
are attentive to the strategic maneuvers of highly profitable firms that
make the market attractive to potential newcomers.
Our study shows that firms do not merely observe the positions
taken by other companies but collect their own private signals. However,
as the signals collected are often of poor quality, the presuppositions
made under the mimetic chains theory remain valid. Information collected
from firms that do not adopt ERP is considered as precise and exhaustive
in 8.6% and 6.9% of cases. Although information collected from
ERP-adopting firms is of better quality, only 36.2% of the signals are
termed precise and 24.1% exhaustive. Since adopters' signals do not
have higher homogeneity (opinions collected from adopters are perceived
as highly heterogeneous in 40% of cases versus 57% of cases among
non-adopters), they do not have much more influence. The 14% of firms
surveyed that report they do not collect signals emitted by others,
resort more than others to optimizing financial tools (IRR and NAV)
(with a risk of error below 5%, the test is meaningful).
The influence of others on adoption choices is all the more
insignificant as the relevance of the representations provided by ERP
watch is high (the Kendall rate is 0.219, then this coefficient is
significant at 5% level). Others' opinions are all the more
compelling since they are homogenous, precise and exhaustive and
correspond to the private calculations of those surveyed. The signals
collected from third parties may even call private calculations into
question. Accordingly, 32% of the firms report having been strongly
influenced by a private signal from non-adopting firms that have
opinions at variance with their own calculations. Taken as a whole,
these results are consistent with the mimetic chains theory, with the
exception that the information collected from third parties is not
limited solely to the positions taken (partial validation of Hypothesis
3).
C. ERP Adoption: A Synthesis Model
We can conclude that strategic compatibility and the perceived
benefits of innovation are facilitating factors in ERP adoption (the
significant test levels are under 1% with the Chi-2 test). We then use a
logit type regression model to explain the adoption of an ERP (variable
dichotomic Y = 1 if adoption of a ERP and Y=0 in the contrary case) by
the variables previously defined: strategic fit with a sector's
strategy, informational and decision-making management benefits,
strategic benefits, organizational benefits, ERP complexity and
organizational risks, frequency of ERP adoption (appendix no 1). The
adjustment is of good quality as the values of the [r.sup.2] of
Nagelkerke and the 79.3% of correctly classified observations attest.
Wald's statistics show that determining factors in the probability
of an ERP adoption include: the organizational benefits, the strategic
compatibility with a sector's strategy, the perception of frequency
of ERP use and the firm's size. Other variables are excluded from
the analysis as they are not significant. Adoption based on frequency
and perceived attributes is the most prevalent.
IV. CONCLUSION
The literature on the adoption of information technologies and on
organizational changes enables us to identify three main strands;
technological determinism, an organizational imperative and an emergence
perspective. Markus and Tanis (2000) deem ERP research to be an
important theme in view of the costs and risks associated with ERP
projects and because of their integrative dimensions, implementation
issues and the conditions surrounding the adoption and use of these
technologies. Our study is in keeping with a productive research process
that purports to better comprehend the adoption and diffusion of
innovations. Having administered a questionnaire to over fifty large and
midsize companies from various industrial sectors of activity, our study
shows that the perceived attributes of innovation influence ERP
adoption. ERP-adopting firms believe this innovation to be compatible
with their strategies. The perceived benefits encompass decision-making,
securing competitive advantages and the possibility of adopting a
transversal organization. Our study corroborates prior research
demonstrating that ERP adoption enables dysfunctional processes to be
detected and exposes organizational slack (Besson, 1999). However, ERP
diffusion is hindered by the complexity of implementation and the costs
of the organizational changes required. Some companies are concerned by
staff resistance to change and an inability to create favorable
conditions to successfully make the changes required by ERP projects
(Saint Leger; 2004). Organizational consulting firms, engineering firms
and integrators also play a role in ERP diffusion by transmitting
information about the ERP packages and projects implemented in their
clients' companies. However, for a number of companies in
situations of uncertainty as a result of the relative lack of pertinence
of the information collected, ERP adoption frequently occurs as a result
of mimetic behavior. Over half the companies surveyed acknowledge being
influenced by the decisions taken by the leading companies in their
sectors.
As a continuation to this study, it would be interesting to observe
the mimetic effects within the framework of multi-site companies and to
further study the communication channels that ensure ERP diffusion
(Oliver and Romm, 2002). Even if the size criterion did not appear to be
determinant, it can be assumed that the use of communication channels is
contingent.
Appendix
Internal coherence of the proposed scales
Cronbach's
Compatibility with the sector's strategy alpha
ERP fits in perfectly with our company sector's strategy
ERP provides perfect verticality for our company's main
business
ERP fits in perfectly with the sector-based supply 0.91
chain strategy
Advantages in terms of information and decision-making management
Better management of information flows
Integration of information and system flows
Better operation trackability
Decisional help
Improved access to information
Shortening of decisional cycles
Better information with which to decide 0.85
Strategic advantages
Better reactivity to customers' needs
Improved company image with customers
Provides a response to key customers' requests and
pressure
Increasing interaction and communication with customers
and suppliers
More flexibility
Lower costs
Smaller inventories 0.85
Organizational advantages
Reinforced control over in-house operations
Increased expertise among managers
Allows the organization to be rebuilt around processes
rather than functions
Reinforced coherence 0.85
ERP Organizational risks
Organizational changes caused
Cost of training required
Required hardware changes
Staff resistance to new software 0.61
Relevance of ERP information
Information is exhaustive
Information is precise
Information is reliable
Information is clear
Information is rich 0.91
REFERENCES
Adams, D.A., R.R. Nelson, and P.A. Todd, 1992, "Perceived
Usefulness, Ease of Use, and Usage of Information," MIS Quarterly,
16 (2).
Alter, N., 1996, Sociologie de I'entreprise et de
I'innovation, PUF
Bancroft, N.H., H. Seip, and A. Sprengel, 1998, Implementing SAP
R/3: How to Introduce Large System into a Large Organisation, Manning
Publication Co.
Barki, H., S. Rivard, and J. Talbot, 1993, "Toward an
Assessment of Software Development Risk, " Journal of Management
Information Systems, 10 (2), 203-225.
Besson, P., 1999, "Les ERP a l'epreuve de
I'organisation", Systemes d'Information et Management, 4
(4), 21-52.
Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch, 1998,
"Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and
Informational Cascades", Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12,
Summer, 151-170.
Bingi, P., M. Sharma, and J. Godla, 1999, "Critical Issues
Affecting and ERP Implementation", Information Systems Management,
16 (3), 7-14.
Burns, L.R., and D.R. Wholey, 1993, "Adoption and Abandonment
of Matrix Management Programs: Effects of Organizational Characteristics
and Interorganizational Networks", Academy of Management Journal,
36 (1), 106-139.
Burt, R.S., 1987, "Social Contagion and Innovation: Cohesion versus Structural Equivalence", American Journal of Sociology, 92,
May, 1287-335.
Charreaux, G., 1999, "La theorie positive de I'agence:
lecture et relectures," in G. Koenig (coord.), De nouvelles
theories pour gerer I'entreprise du XXIe siecle, Economica, 61-141.
Chatterjee, R., and J. Eliashberg, 1990, "The Innovation
Diffusion Process in a Heterogeneous Population: A Micromodeling
Approach", Management Science, 36 (9), 1057-79.
Cosgrove, W., 2001, "ERP Progress Report CIO Magazine",
wwww2.cio.com.
Davenport, T.H., and J.E. Short, 1990, "The Mew Industrial
Engineering Information Technology and Business Processes
Redesign," Sloan management Review, summer.
Davis, F.D., 1989, "Perceived Usefulness, Perceived Ease of
Use, and User Acceptance of Information Technology", MIS Quarterly,
13 (3), 319-340.
Deutsch, M., and H.B. Gerard, 1955, "A Study of Normative and
Informational Social Influences upon Individual Judgment", Journal
Abnormal and social Psychology, 51, November, 629-656.
DiMaggio, P., and W. Powell, 1983, "The Iron-Cage Revisited:
Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational
Field", American Sociological Review, 48, 147-160.
Farbey, B., F. Land F., and D.A. Target, 1994, A Taxonomy of
Evaluation Methods. Proceedings of the First European Conference on IT
Investment Evaluation, Henley, United Kingdom, July.
Festinger, L., 1950, "Informal Social Communication",
Psychological Review, 57, 271-282.
Festinger, L., 1954, "A Theory of Social Comparison
Process", Human Relations, 7, 117-140.
Frambach, R.T., and N. Schillewaert, 2002, "Organizational
Innovation Adoption: A Multi-level Framework of Determinants and
Opportunities for Futures Research," Journal of Business Research,
55, 163-176.
Gatignon, H., and S. Robertson, 1985, "A Prepositional Inventory for New Diffusion Research", The Journal of Consumer
Research, 11, 849-867.
Greve, H.R., 1998, "Managerial Cognition and the Mimetic
Adoption of Market Positions: What You See Is What You Do",
Strategic Management Journal, 19, 967-988.
Greve, H.R., and A. Taylor, 2000, "Innovations as Catalysts
for Organizational Change: Shifts in Organizational Cognition and
Search", Administrative Science Quarterly, 45 (1), 54-80.
Haveman, H.A., 1993, "Follow the Leader: Mimetic Isomorphism
and Entry into New Markets", Administrative Science Quarterly, 38,
596-607.
Hirshleifer, D., 1995, "The Blind Leading the Blind: Social
Influence, Fads, and Informational Cascades", In The New Economics
of Human Behavior, by Tommasi, M. and K. Ierulli, Cambridge, UK:
Cambridge University Press.
Hochbaum, G.M., 1954, "The Relation between Group
Members' Self-Confidence and Their Reaction to Group Pressure to
Conformity", American Sociological Review, 19, 678-687.
Kimberly, R.J., 1981, "Managerial Innovation" In Handbook
of Organizational Design, by Nystrom P.C. and Starbuck W.H., New York:
Oxford University Press.
Lant, T.H., and S.J. Mezias, 1990, "Managing Discontinuous Change: A Simulation Study of Organizational Learning and
Entrepreneurship", Strategic Management Journal, 11, 147-179.
Le Bon, G., 1911, Psychologie des foules, Seizieme Ed. Paris.
Lind, M.R., and R.W. Zmud, 1991, "The Influence of a
Convergence in Understanding between Technology Providers and Users on
Information Technology Innovativeness", Organizational Science, 2,
195-217.
Mahajan, V., E. Muller, and F. Bass, 1990, "New Product
Diffusion Models in Marketing: A Review and Directions for
Research", Journal of Marketing, 54, 126.
Mansfield, E., 1961, "Technical Change and the Rate of
Imitation", Econometrica, 29, 741-766.
Markus, M.L., and C. Tanis, 2000, "The Enterprise Systems
Experience from Adoption to Success", In Framing the Domains of IT
Management: Projecting the Future through the Past, by Zmud, R.W. and
M.F. Price. (eds), Pinnaflex Educational Resources Inc, 173-207.
McAffe, A., 2002, "The Impact of Enterprise Technology
Adoption on Operational Performance: An Empirical Investigation",
Production and Operations Management, 11 (1), 33-53.
Menger, K., 1892, "Geld Handwortbuch der
Staatwissenschaft", In The Collected Essays of K. Menger, IV
(1936), London School of Economics Reprint Series, 20.
Morvan, Y., 1991, "Theorie de l'innovation et systemes
productifs", In Fondements d'economie industrielle, deuxieme
edition.
Oliver, D., and C. Romm, 2002, "Justifying Enterprise Resource
Adoption", Journal of Information Technology, 1, 199-213.
Ostlund, L.E., 1974, "Perceived Innovation Attributes as
Predictors of Innovativeness", The Journal of Consumer Research. 1,
23-29.
Reix, R., 1999, "Les technologies de l'information,
facteurs de flexibilite ?", Revue Frangaise de Gestion, mars-mai,
111-119.
Robey, D., J. Ross, and M. Boudreau, 2002, "Learning to
Implement Enterprise Systems: An exploratory Study of the Dialectics of
Change", Journal of Management Information System, 19, 1, 17-46.
Rogers, E., and F. Shoemaker, 1971, Communication of Innovations: A
Cross-cultural Approach, New York: The Free Press.
Rogers, E., 1995, Diffusion of Innovations, 4th ed., New York: The
Free Press. Rowe, F., 1999, "Coherence, integration
informationnelle et changement: esquisse d'un programme de
recherche a partir des Progiciels Integres de Gestion ", Systemes
d'Information et Management, 4 (4), 3-20.
Saint-Leger, G., 2004, "L'apres projet ERP: retour
d'experience sur un changement qui n'a pas eu lieu",
Systeme d'information et Management, 2 (9), 77-107. Schmidt, R., K.
Lyytinen, M. Keil, and P. Cule, 2001, "Identifying Software Risks:
An International Delphi Study", Journal of Management Information
Systems, 17 (4), 5-36.
Scott, J.E., and I. Vessey, 2002, "Managing Risks in
Enterprise System implementations", Communication of the ACM, 45
(4), 74-81.
Simon, H.A., 1957, Administrative Behavior: A Study of
Decision-making Processes in Administrative Organisations, New York: The
Free Press.
Smith, A., 1776, Recherche sur la nature et les causes de la
richesse des nations, Paris: Gallimard.
Tarde, G., 1890, Les lois de limitation: etude sociologique, Paris:
Alcan.
Thompson B., 1987, Advances in Social Science Methodology, JAI Press.
Tornatzky, L.G., and K.J. Klein, 1982, "Innovation
Characteristics and Innovation Adoption-implementation: A Meta-analysis
of Findings", IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 29 (11),
28-45.
Von Neumann, J., and O. Morgenstern, 1944, Theory of Game and
Economic Behaviour, Princeton University Press.
Walras, L., 1874, Elements d'economie politique pure, Paris:
LGDJ.
Wang, P., 2001, "What Drives Waves in Information Systems? The
Organizing Vision Perspective" Proceedings of the twenty-second
International Conference on Information Systems (ICIS), New Orleans.
Webb, D., and A. Pettigrew, 1999, "The Temporal Development of
Strategy: Patterns in the U.K. Insurance Industry", Organization
Science, 10 (5), 601-621.
Zaltman, G., and M. Wallendorf, 1979, Consumer Behavior: Basic
Findings and Management Implications, New York: Wiley.
Erick Leroux (a), Pierre-Charles Pupion (b), Jean-Michel Sahut (c)
(a) Associate Professor, IUT de Saint Denis, LARGEPA Paris II
[email protected]
(b) Associate Professor, IAE & CEREGEEA 1722-University of
Poitiers
[email protected]
(c) Professor of Finance, Amiens School of Management & HEG Geneva-University of Applied Sciences
[email protected]
Table 2
Use of economics calculation and choice
Total of Adopting
firms (=58) firms (=37)
% CI % CI
--Evaluated a project 30% 18%-42% 17% 6%-30%
using an NAV calculation
--Evaluated a project 55% 41%-67% 51% 34%-66%
using an IRR calculation
Non-adopting
firms (=21)
% CI
--Evaluated a project 52% 29%-73%
using an NAV calculation
--Evaluated a project 61% 37%-81%
using an IRR calculation
CI: Confidence intervals at 90%
Table 3
ERP perceived attributes
Total of firms (= 58)
Perceived attributes Mean Median CI
Strategic 4.15 4.38 4.25-4.5
compatibility
Benefits in terms 4.96 5 4.83-5.16
of information and
decision-making
management
Strategic benefits 4.1 4.14 3.71-4.28
Organizational 4.44 4.75 4.5-4.75
benefits
ERP complexity and 4.01 4 4 - 4
organizational risks
Adopting firms (= 37)
Perceived attributes Mean Median CI
Strategic 4.72 5 4.5-5
compatibility
Benefits in terms 5.35 5.33 5.16-5.5
of information and
decision-making
management
Strategic benefits 4.42 4.29 4.14-4.71
Organizational 4.89 4.75 4.75-5
benefits
ERP complexity and 4.08 4 3.82-4.25
organizational risks
Non adopting firms (= 21)
Perceived attributes Mean Median CI
Strategic 3.14 3.25 2.4-3.91
compatibility
Benefits in terms 4.27 4.33 4-4.33
of information and
decision-making
management
Strategic benefits 3.53 3.57 3.14-3.71
Organizational 3.64 3.5 3.17-3.66
benefits
ERP complexity and 3.89 4 3.92-4
organizational risks
CI: confidence intervals of the mean at 90%
Table 4
Evaluation of ERP benefits, compatibility and complexity
Benefits
in terms of
information and
Strategic decision-making Strategic
compatibility management benefits
Non-adopters average 17.14 14.79 18.02
rank
Adopters average 36.51 37.85 36.01
rank
Wilcoxon Test 360.00 310.50 378.50
coefficient
p-value 0.00 0.00 0.00
Organizational Organizational
benefits complexity
Non-adopters average 15.00 26.21
rank
Adopters average 37.73 31.36
rank
Wilcoxon Test 315.00 550.50
coefficient
p-value 0.00 0.26
Table 5
ERP and information systems
Total of firms
(= 58)
Having heard of ERP through: % CI
--An organizational consulting firm 37.93% 25-50%
--A computer engineering firm 37.93% 25-50%
--Integrators 24.14% 14-35%
--An in-house executive 65.52% 52-77%
--Another company executive 3.45% 0.1-10%
--The specialized press 74.14% 61-85%
--Internet 51.72% 38-64%
--Professional trade fairs 60.34% 47-72%
--Regularly receiving a fiscal journal 90% 80-96%
Importance of the source of
information (0 to 7):
--An organizational consulting firm 3 3-4
--A computer engineering firm 3 2-4
--Integrators 4 3-4
--An in-house executive 5 4-5
--Another company executive 3 2-4
--The specialized press 4 4-4
--Internet 3 3-4
Quality of the business intelligence in
IT (0 (0 to 7):
--Its anticipatory function or capacity to 5 4-5
reveal computer-provided opportunities
--Its capacity to satisfy your need for 5 4-5
information
--Its capacity to convey information for 4 4-4
decision-making purposes
--The relevance of the information 4 3-4
conveyed by the watch
Effort made to be kept informed of 6 5-6
information systems news (0 to 10)
Adopting firms
(= 37)
Having heard of ERP through: % CI
--An organizational consulting firm 43.24% 21-61%
--A computer engineering firm 43.24% 21-61%
--Integrators 29.73% 10-47%
--An in-house executive 59.46% 38-76%
--Another company executive 5.41% 0.5-16%
--The specialized press 64.86% 44-80%
--Internet 51.35% 29-68%
--Professional trade fairs 51.35% 29-68%
--Regularly receiving a fiscal journal 90% 76-96%
Importance of the source of
information (0 to 7):
--An organizational consulting firm 5 3-6
--A computer engineering firm 4 2-5
--Integrators 5 3-5
--An in-house executive 5 4-6
--Another company executive 4 2-5
--The specialized press 4 3-4
--Internet 3 2-3
Quality of the business intelligence in
IT (0 (0 to 7):
--Its anticipatory function or capacity to 5 4-5
reveal computer-provided opportunities
--Its capacity to satisfy your need for 5 4-5
information
--Its capacity to convey information for 4 3-5
decision-making purposes
--The relevance of the information 4 3,4-4.8
conveyed by the watch
Effort made to be kept informed of 6 6-7
information systems news (0 to 10)
Non adopting firms
(= 21)
Having heard of ERP through: % CI
--An organizational consulting firm 28.57% 11-50%
--A computer engineering firm 28.57% 11-50%
--Integrators 14.29% 3-33%
--An in-house executive 76.19% 53-92%
--Another company executive 0.00% --
--The specialized press 90.48% 68-99%
--Internet 52.38% 29-73%
--Professional trade fairs 76.19% 53-91%
--Regularly receiving a fiscal journal 90% 69-99%
Importance of the source of
information (0 to 7):
--An organizational consulting firm 3 1-3
--A computer engineering firm 2 1-3
--Integrators 3 1-3
--An in-house executive 4 1-5
--Another company executive 2 1-3
--The specialized press 4 3-5
--Internet 4 1-4
Quality of the business intelligence in
IT (0 (0 to 7):
--Its anticipatory function or capacity to 4 4-5
reveal computer-provided opportunities
--Its capacity to satisfy your need for 4 3-4
information
--Its capacity to convey information for 4 4-5
decision-making purposes
--The relevance of the information 4 3-4
conveyed by the watch
Effort made to be kept informed of 5 4-6
information systems news (0 to 10)
CI: confidence intervals at 90%
Table 6
Influence of the positions taken by others
Agents reporting being strongly
influenced in their choices Surveyed
% CI
--by the adoption decisions 20.70% 11-31%
made by other companies
--by the choices made by 8.60% 3%-17%
geographically close companies
--by the choices made by 32.80% 21-45%
innovative companies
--by the choices made by 50% 37-63%
companies hailed as leaders
--by the choices made by high- 56.90% 43-69%
performing companies
Agents reporting being strongly
influenced in their choices Surveyed having
% CI
--by the adoption decisions 29.70% 10-48%
made by other companies
--by the choices made by 8.10% 0-23%
geographically close companies
--by the choices made by 40.54% 19-58%
innovative companies
--by the choices made by 43.24% 21-61%
companies hailed as leaders
--by the choices made by high- 54.05% 32-71%
performing companies
Agents reporting being strongly
influenced in their choices Surveyed not
% CI
--by the adoption decisions 4.76% 0-22%
made by other companies
--by the choices made by 9.50% 0-28%
geographically close companies
--by the choices made by 19.05% 5-39%
innovative companies
--by the choices made by 61.90% 38-81%
companies hailed as leaders
--by the choices made by high- 61.90% 38-81%
performing companies
CI: confidence intervals at 90%
Table 7
Logit regression model
Classification table
Predicted
Observed Adopter ERP
No Yes Correct
No 20 1 95.2 % -2 Log likelihood 20.732
ERP adoption Yes 2 35 94.6 % Cox & Snell R Sq 0.614
Overall Percentage 94.8 % Nagelkerke R Squ 0.841
Variables in the
equation B S.E. Wald df Sig. Exp(B)
ORGABENEFIT 3.750 1.752 4.58 1 0.034 4.245
STRATEGCOMP 4.523 1.870 5.850 1 0.016 92.133
FREQUENTADOPTION 1.446 0.681 4.512 1 0.034 4.245
SIZE 1.417 0.824 2.959 1 0.085 4.125
CONSTANT -15.649 5.731 7.456 1 0.006 0.000
ORGABENEFIT: Organizational benefits
ERPCOMPLEX: ERP complexity
STRATEGCOMP: ERP compatibility with the sector's strategy
FREQUENTADOPTION: ERP adoption frequency
SIZE: Firm's size
Confidence interval at 90%