Role of accountants and fair value accounting leading towards the global financial crisis.
Masood, Omar ; Bellalah, Mondher
I. INTRODUCTION
Fair value accounting is a financial reporting approach in which
companies are required or permitted to measure and report on an ongoing
basis certain assets and liabilities (generally financial instruments)
at estimates of the prices they would receive if they were to sell the
assets or would pay if they were to be relieved of the liabilities.
Under fair value accounting, companies report losses when the fair
values of their assets decrease or liabilities increase. Those losses
reduce companies' reported equity and may also reduce
companies' reported net income. Some parties have strong opinion
that fair value accounting has a major contribution in strengthen credit
crises, specially pointing to the obvious difficulties of measuring the
fair values of subprime positions in the current illiquid markets and
the feedback effects noted above. This is untenable. The subprime crisis
was caused by firms and households making bad operating, investing, and
financing decisions, managing risks poorly, and in some instances
committing fraud. The best way to stem the credit crunch and damage
caused by these actions is to speed the price adjustment process by
providing market participants with the most accurate and complete
information about subprime positions. While imperfect, fair value
accounting provides better information about these positions and is a
better platform for mandatory and voluntary disclosure than alternative
measurement attributes, including any form of cost-based accounting.
This is not to say that guidance for the measurement of fair values
in illiquid markets cannot be improved. While FAS 157 provides a clearer
definition of fair value and considerably expanded guidance specifying
how fair value should be measured than prior GAAP, the current market
illiquidity has raised significant challenges for the interpretability
of this definition and guidance. FAS 157's definition of fair value
reflects the idea that there can be "orderly" transactions
based on the conditions that exist at the "measurement date."
During the subprime crisis, this idea has become increasingly difficult
to sustain even in thought experiments and, more importantly,
practically useless as a guide to preparers' estimation of fair
values. FAS 157's fair value measurement guidance includes a
hierarchy of inputs that favours observable market inputs over
unobservable firm-supplied inputs, but that ultimately requires
preparers to employ "the assumptions that market participants would
use in pricing the asset or liability." This hierarchy provides
little help to preparers who have to decide whether to base their fair
valuations on the poor quality signals currently being generated by
markets versus highly judgmental firm-supplied inputs such as forecasts
of house price depreciation. For the duration of the crisis, preparers
will need to exercise considerably more than the usual professional
judgment to apply FAS 157's language to their specific
circumstances.
As the successive waves of the subprime crisis have hit, firms have
repeatedly and sharply revised upward their estimates of credit losses.
These revisions are inevitable consequences of how the subprime crisis
evolved, and they do not imply there have been any problems either with
accounting standards or how preparers have applied them. However, these
revisions and the high potential for further upward revisions have
contributed to the aforementioned feedback effects between reported
losses and market illiquidity. Needless to say, this market illiquidity
is damaging our real estate and credit markets and overall economy, and
it needs to be cured through means that do not simply push the problem
into the future. As always, essential components of such a cure are for
firms to provide relevant, reliable, and understandable financial report
information and for users to conduct careful and dispassionate analysis
of that information.
The remainder of the essay is structured as follows. In Section II,
we overview the short synopsis of credit crises. In Section III, we
describe the critical aspects of FAS 157's definition of fair value
and guidance for fair value measurements. We describe the practical
difficulties that have arisen in applying that definition and guidance
to subprime positions in the current illiquid markets. We also discuss a
potential issue regarding the application of FAS 159, The Fair Value
Option for Financial Assets and Financial Liabilities, during credit
crunch. Section IV reveals our findings regarding potential Criticisms
of Fair Value Accounting during the Credit Crunch Section V contain my
concluding remarks.
II. SHORT SYNOPSIS OF CREDIT CRISES
The International Monetary Fund (2008) estimates that the credit
crisis will cost about $945 billion dollars, the latest in a long list
of estimates presented in Figure 1 below. No one knows the ultimate cost
of the crisis, but it certainly will exceed the costs of the last major
financial crisis presented by the collapse of the savings and loan
industry. This problem began in the subprime mortgage market and then
quickly spilled over into other areas of the mortgage industry and the
capital markets, culminating in a liquidity and credit crisis that is
still unfolding. Unsurprisingly, litigation has been on the rise.
Just as in the credit crisis, the lawsuits initially started in the
mortgage industry. For the most part, these were suits against mortgage
lenders. The subjects of litigation then moved on to the issuers and
underwriters of securities whose cash flows are backed by the principal
and interest payments of mortgages. Now, the litigation has also
engulfed investors who either purchased these securities or packaged
them into other securities. As the liquidity crisis intensifies, areas
that are not directly related to the subprime mortgage sector are
starting to suffer losses, including the commercial paper market, the
leveraged buyout industry, and auction-rate securities, to name a few
examples. As the write-downs continue to accumulate, additional types of
lawsuits are expected to emerge.
The value of asset-backed securities (ABS) backed by subprime
products has fallen as the performance of the subprime loans has
continued to worsen. Figure 2 illustrates the value of two indices
tracking the BBB rated and BBB- rated tranches of home equity deals
based on loans from the last six months of 2006. An initial investment
of $100 (on January 19, 2007) in the BBB index would have been worth
only $5.46 by May 8, 2008; both indices showed a decline of almost 95%
as of May 8, 2008.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
III. SUBPRIME MORTGAGE-RELATED SECURITIES LAWSUITS
Almost every market participant in the securitization
process--which transforms illiquid assets such as mortgages, auto loans,
and student loans into tradable securities--has been named as a
defendant. The list of defendants includes lenders, issuers,
underwriters, rating agencies, accounting firms, bond insurers, hedge
funds, CDOs, and many more. As of April 21, 2008, there had been 132
securities lawsuits related to subprime and credit issues, of which 56
were filed since January 2008. New York has the most filings, with 48%,
while California follows with 14% and Florida wraps up the top three
with 7%. Filings in other states range between 1% and 5% (lawsuits by
state are shown in Figure 3 below). This is consistent with recent
trends in shareholder class actions, where the US circuit courts
encompassing New York (Second Circuit), California (Ninth Circuit), and
Florida (Eleventh Circuit) have seen the most activity in recent years.
The majority of the early lawsuits have been against mortgage
lenders. As various other market participants reveal the extent of their
losses and exposure, they too are being dragged into litigation. The
plaintiffs include shareholders, investors, issuers and underwriters of
securities, plan participants, and others. Figure 4 gives a breakdown of
securities defendants and plaintiffs.
IV. SCOPE OF FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING
As depicted in Figure 5, the valuation attributes required by the
accounting standards governing the accounting for subprime positions can
be subdivided into the following broad categories. Some of these
standards require or allow subprime positions to be fair valued on the
balance sheet (e.g., FAS 115 for trading and AFS securities, FAS 133 for
derivatives, FIN 45 for guarantees at inception, and FAS 159 for
positions for which the fair value option is chosen). When fair value is
the valuation attribute, unrealized gains on the positions may be
recorded either on the income statement (e.g., FAS 115 for trading
securities, FAS 133 for non hedge and fair value hedge derivatives, and
FAS 159 for financial instruments for which the fair value option is
elected) or in other comprehensive income (FAS 115 for AFS securities
and FAS 133 for cash flow hedge derivatives).
Other of these standards requires subprime positions to be recorded
at amortized cost (possibly zero) on the balance sheet. Assets accounted
for at amortized cost generally are subject to impairment write-downs if
criteria specified in the standards are met. Assets deemed impaired
based on the relevant criteria are required to be written down to fair
value under some standards (e.g., FAS 115 for HTM securities and SOP
01-6 for held-for-sale loans) and to other valuation attributes that
generally are higher than fair value under other standards (e.g., FAS 5
and FAS 114 for held-for-investment loans). Similarly, under FAS 115
unrealized gains and losses on AFS securities that previously were
recorded in other comprehensive income are recorded in income when the
AFS are deemed impaired.
V. CRITICAL ASPECTS OF THE DEFINITION OF FAIR VALUE
FAS 157 define fair value as "the price that would be received
to sell an asset or paid to transfer a liability in an orderly
transaction between market participants at the measurement date."
In this section, we unpack and discuss the constituent elements of this
definition, indicating the practical difficulties involved in applying
each element and the slippage among the elements given the current
market illiquidity for subprime positions. The definition reflects an
optimal "exit value" notion of fair value, that is, the
highest values of assets and the lowest values of liabilities currently
held by the firm. This notion corresponds to firms' solvency more
than do the possible alternative fair value notions of "entry
value" (the price that would be paid to buy an asset or received
from issuing a liability) or "value in use" (the
entity-specific value to the current holder of an item). In particular,
if all assets and liabilities on a firm's balance sheet were
perfectly measured at exit value, then owners' equity would equal
the cash expected to remain if the firm liquidated all of those items in
orderly transactions between market participants at the measurement
date, that is, not in fire sales. Given the paramount importance of
maintaining solvency during the subprime crisis, this element of the
definition of fair value is well suited to users of financial
reports' current informational needs.
"At the measurement date" means that fair value should
reflect the conditions that exist at the balance sheet date. If markets
are illiquid and credit spreads are at historically high levels, as is
now the case, then the fair values should reflect those conditions. In
particular, firms should not incorporate their expectations of market
liquidity and credit spreads returning to normal over some horizon,
regardless of what historical experience, statistical models, or expert
opinion indicates. While one can question this element of the fair value
definition, it has considerable precedent in the accounting
literature--notably FAS 107, Disclosures about Fair Value of Financial
Instruments, and SEC enforcement actions--20 and it is hard to imagine
the FASB proposing a definition of fair value without it.
An "orderly transaction" is one that is unforced and
unhurried. The firm is expected to conduct usual and customary marketing
activities to identify potential purchasers of assets and assumers of
liabilities, and these parties are expected to conduct usual and
customary due diligence. Each of these activities could take months in
the current environment, because of the few and noisy signals about the
values of subprime positions currently being generated by market
transactions and because of parties' natural scepticism regarding
those values. Hence, the earliest such an orderly transaction might
occur could easily be a quarter or more after the balance sheet date. At
that time, market conditions almost certainly will differ from those
that exist at the balance sheet date, for better or, as been the case
lately, worse.
VI. THE FAIR VALUE HIERARCHY
FAS 157 create a hierarchy of inputs into fair value measurements,
from most to least reliable. Level 1 input is unadjusted quoted market
prices in active markets for identical items. While some accounting
academics, bank regulators, and others worry that market values might be
incorrect or their use in accounting might have undesirable incentive or
feedback effects, in our opinion pure mark-to-market measurements using
such maximally reliable inputs are the rough equivalent of accounting
nirvana. Even in times of normal market liquidity, this nirvana does not
exist for most subprime positions, however, and so we can safely ignore
such philosophical disputes in this essay. Level 2 inputs are other
directly or indirectly observable market data. There are two broad
subclasses of these inputs. The first and generally preferable subclass
is quoted market prices in active markets for similar items or in
inactive markets for identical items. These inputs yield adjusted
mark-to-market measurements that are less than ideal but usually still
pretty good, depending on the nature and magnitude of the required
adjustments. The second subclass is other observable inputs such as
yield curves, exchange rates, empirical correlations, et cetera. These
inputs yield mark-to-model measurements that are disciplined by market
information but that can only be as good as the models employed. In our
view, this second subclass usually has less in common with the first
subclass than with better quality level 3 measurements described below.
In times of normal market liquidity, many subprime positions would
be fair valued using level 2 measurements. For example, while most
subprime MBS trade over-the-counter and rarely, in normal markets
dealers generally do their best to provide bid and ask prices for these
securities. There are also price and yield indices for portfolios of
subprime positions available from Market and other sources. The price
transparency offered by these sources has substantially evaporated
during the subprime crisis, however. Dealers are reluctant to provide
bid and ask quotes for subprime positions, and when they do the bid-ask
spread is very wide. Very few truly orderly transactions are occurring,
and those that do occur typically are privately negotiated
principal-to-principal transactions for which the terms and positions
involved are largely opaque to market participants. Market has announced
that there will be no indices for the first half of 2008 vintage, due to
an insufficient number of securitizations.
Level 3 inputs are unobservable, firm-supplied estimates. While
these inputs should reflect the assumptions that market participants
would use, they yield mark-to-model valuations that are largely
undisciplined by market information. Due to the declining price
transparency described above, many subprime positions that previously
were fair valued using level 2 inputs must now be fair valued using
level 3 inputs. While many firms have been criticized in the popular
press for this migration of fair value measurements down the hierarchy,
this migration is an inevitable result of the deterioration of price
transparency in the subprime crisis.
Level 3 inputs usually are based on historical data in some
fashion. Historical data is only useful for fair valuation purposes to
the extent that the future is expected to be similar, or at least
capable of being related, to the past. For subprime positions, a
critical level 3 input is house price depreciation. Most of the
historical data to date (and a fortiori up to earlier points in the
subprime crisis) reflect a period in which house price appreciation was
robust and so defaults were few, uncorrelated, and yielded small
percentage losses given default. Hence, this historical data is of
little use for the purposes of determining this input and thus the fair
values of subprime positions. Instead, firms must forecast future house
price depreciation, as well as other primitive variables such as future
interest rates and the time when subprime mortgagors will be able to
refinance again. These variables are critical determinants of the future
number and correlation of defaults and the percentage magnitude of
losses given default.
VII. REQUIRED DISCLOSURES
Subprime positions are subject to the disclosure requirements of
the governing accounting standards (e.g., FAS 115 for securities) that
we do not mention here. 22
Instead, we discuss three overarching disclosure requirements of
particular relevance to subprime positions during the subprime crisis.
First, FAS 157 requires disclosures of fair value measurements by
level of the hierarchy. The required disclosures are considerably more
detailed for level 3 fair value measurements than for level 1 or 2
measurements. In particular, for level 3 measurements firms most provide
quantitative reconciliations of beginning and end-of period fair values,
distinguishing total (realized and unrealized) gains and losses from net
purchases, sales, issuances, settlements, and transfers. The line-item
location of gains and losses on the income statement must be indicated.
Qualitative descriptions of measurement inputs and valuation techniques
must be provided. These disclosure requirements make the effects of
level 3 measurements on the financial statements considerably more
transparent than they would have been under prior GAAP, and users of
financial reports are fortunate to have them available during the
subprime crisis.
Second, SOP 94-6, Disclosure of Certain Significant Risks and
Uncertainties, requires disclosures regarding an uncertain estimate such
as a fair value when it is reasonably possible the estimate will change
in the near term (one year or less) and the effect of the change would
be material to the financial statements. The disclosure should indicate
the nature of the uncertainty. Disclosures of the factors that cause the
estimate to be sensitive to change are encouraged but not required.
Neither FAS 157 nor SOP 94-6 requires quantitative disclosures of the
forecasted values of the primitive variables that underlie level 3 fair
valuations or of the sensitivities of the fair valuations to movements
in those primitive variables. In the absence of such quantitative
disclosures, during the subprime crisis I have found level 3 fair values
to be very difficult to interpret for a given firm and to compare across
firms. To enhance the interpretability of level 3 fair values, I suggest
the FASB consider requiring disclosures of firms' forecasts of
primitive variables when those forecasts have material effects on their
level 3 fair valuations.
Third, SAS 1 requires disclosures of type 2 subsequent events,
i.e., events that occur between the balance sheet date and the financial
report filing date, if these events render the financial statements
misleading as of the filing date. Very significant type 2 subsequent
events occurred for many firms holding large subprime positions in the
third and fourth quarters of 2007. Specifically, the third and fourth
waves of the subprime crisis described above hit after the end of the
third and fourth fiscal quarters of many firms, respectively, but before
the filing dates for those quarters. Citigroup's previously
discussed third quarter 2007 subsequent events disclosure is a good
example.
VIII. FAIR VALUE OPTION
FAS 159 allow firms to elect to fair value individual financial
instruments upon the adoption of the standard or at the inception of the
instruments. One type of exercise of the fair value option with
particular salience in the subprime crisis is the decision by many
securities firms to fair value the liabilities of their consolidated
securitization entities. Securities firms have made this choice
primarily because they are required by industry or other GAAP to record
the entities' assets at fair value, and so electing the fair value
option for the entities' liabilities yields symmetric accounting.
In general, such symmetry is a desirable thing, as offsetting gains and
losses on these economically matched positions are recorded in the same
period.
A concern, however, is that these firms may have the incentive to
provide moral recourse to the securitization entities. When this is the
case, the firms may bear the losses on the entities' assets without
benefiting from offsetting gains on the entities' liabilities. At a
minimum, the fair values of the entities' liabilities would have to
be adjusted for any expected provision of moral recourse, a problematic
valuation exercise given the non contractual nature of moral recourse.
IX. POTENTIAL CRITICISMS OF FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING
DURING CREDIT CRUNCH
A. Unrealized Gains and Losses Reverse
There are two distinct reasons why unrealized gains and losses may
reverse with greater than 50% probability. First, the market prices of
positions may be bubble prices that deviate from fundamental values.
Second, these market prices may not correspond to the future cash flows
most likely to be received or paid because the distribution of future
cash flows is skewed. For example, the distribution of future cash flows
on an asset may include some very low probability but very high loss
severity future outcomes that reduce the fair value of the asset.
B. Bubble Prices
The financial economics literature now contains considerable theory
and empirical evidence that markets sometimes exhibit "bubble
prices" that either are inflated by market optimism and excess
liquidity or are depressed by market pessimism and illiquidity compared
to fundamental values. Bubble prices can result from rational short
horizon decisions by investors in dynamically efficient markets, not
just from investor irrationality or market imperfections. Whether bubble
prices have existed for specific types of positions during the credit
crunch is debatable, but it certainly is possible.
In FAS 157's hierarchy of fair value measurement inputs,
market prices for the same or similar positions are the preferred type
of input. If the market prices of positions currently are depressed
below their fundamental values as a result of the credit crunch, then
firms' unrealized losses on positions would be expected to reverse
in part or whole in future periods. Concerned with this possibility,
some parties have argued that it would be preferable to allow or even
require firms to report amortized costs or level 3 mark-to model fair
values for positions rather than level 2 adjusted mark-to-market fair
values that yield larger unrealized losses. If level 1 inputs are
available, then with a few narrow exceptions FAS 157 requires firms to
measure fair values at these active market prices for identical
positions without any adjustments for bubble pricing. However, if only
level 2 inputs are available and firms can demonstrate that these inputs
reflect forced sales, then FAS 157 (implicitly) allows firms to make the
argument that level 3 mark-to-models based fair values are more faithful
to FAS 157's fair value definition.
If we agrees with the FASB's decision in FAS 157 that the
possible existence of bubble prices in liquid markets should not affect
the measurement of fair value. It is very difficult to know when bubble
prices exist and, if so, when the bubbles will burst. Different firms
would undoubtedly have very different views about these matters, and
they likely would act in inconsistent and perhaps discretionary
fashions. To be useful, accounting standards must impose a reasonably
high degree of consistency in application. It should also be noted that
amortized costs reflect any bubble prices that existed when positions
were incepted. In this regard, the amortized costs of subprimemortgage
related positions incepted during the euphoria preceding the subprime
crisis are far more likely to reflect bubble prices than are the current
fair values of those positions.
C. Future Cash Flows
Fair values should reflect the expected future cash flows based on
current information as well as current risk-adjusted discount rates for
positions. When a position is more likely to experience very
unfavourable future cash flows than very favourable future cash flows,
or vice-versa--statistically speaking, when it exhibits a skewed
distribution of future cash flows--then the expected future cash flows
differ from the most likely future cash flows. This implies that over
time the fair value of the position will be revised in the direction of
the most likely future cash flows with greater than 50% probability,
possibly considerably greater. While some parties appear to equate this
phenomenon with expected reversals of unrealized gains and losses such
as result from bubble prices, it is not the same thing. When
distributions of future cash flows are skewed, fair values will tend to
be revised by relatively small amounts when they are revised in the
direction of the most likely future cash flows but by relatively large
amounts when they are revised in the opposite direction. Taking into
account the sizes and probabilities of the possible future cash flows,
the unexpected change in fair value will be zero on average.
Financial instruments that are options or that contain embedded
options exhibit skewed distributions of future cash flows. Many
financial instruments have embedded options, and in many cases the
credit crunch has accentuated the importance of these embedded options.
Super senior CDOs, which have experienced large unrealized losses during
the credit crunch, are a good example. At inception, super senior CDOs
are structured to be near credit riskless instruments that return their
par value with accrued interest in almost all circumstances. Super
senior CDOs essentially are riskless debt instruments with embedded
written put options on some underlying set of assets. Super senior CDOs
return their par value with accrued interest as long as the underlying
assets perform above some relatively low threshold (reflecting the
riskless debt instruments),but they pay increasingly less than this
amount the more the underlying assets perform below that threshold
(reflecting the embedded written put options). As a result of the
embedded written put options, the fair values of super senior CDOs
typically are slightly less than the values implied by the most likely
cash flows. During the credit crunch, the underlying assets (often
subprime mortgage-backed securities) performed very poorly, increasing
the importance of the embedded put option and decreasing the fair value
of super senior CDOs further below the value implied by the most likely
outcome, which for some super seniors may still be to return the par
value with accrued interest. To illustrate this subtle statistical
point, assume that the cash flows for a super senior CDO are driven by
home price depreciation, and that the distribution of percentage losses
is modestly skewed with relatively small probability of large losses, as
indicated in the following Table 1.
In this example, the most likely percentage loss on the super
senior is 5%, which occurs 40% of the time. The expected percentage loss
is a considerably larger 15% = (40%*5%) + (25%x20%) + (10%x40%) +
(5%*80%), because it reflects the relatively small probabilities of
large losses. The fair value of the super senior is reduced by the
expected percentage loss and so is 85% of face value. Over time, this
fair value will be revised upward with 60% probability, to either 95% of
face value (with 40% probability) or 100% of face value (with 20%
probability). The fair value will be revised downward with only 40%
probability, to 80% of face value (with 25% probability) or 60% of face
value (with 10% probability) or 20% of face value (with 5% probability).
The expected change in fair value is zero, however, because the lower
probability but larger possible fair value losses are exactly offset by
the higher probability but smaller possible fair value gains. The
difference between the most likely and expected change in fair value
would be larger if the distribution of cash flows was more skewed.
According to our findings it is more informative to investors for
accounting to be right on average and to incorporate the probability and
significance of all possible future cash flows, as fair value accounting
does, than for it to be right most of the time but to ignore relatively
low probability but highly unfavourable or favourable future cash flows.
Relatedly, by updating the distribution of future cash flows each
period, fair value accounting provides investors with timelier
information about changes in the probabilities of large unfavourable or
favourable future cash flows. Such updating is particularly important in
periods of high and rapidly evolving uncertainty and information
asymmetry, such as the credit crunch.
D. Market Illiquidity
Together, the "orderly transaction" and "at the
measurement date" elements of FAS 157's fair value definition
reflect the semantics behind the "fair" in "fair
value."Fair values are not necessarily the currently realizable
values of positions; they are hypothetical values that reflect fair
transaction prices even if current conditions do not support such
transactions. When markets are severely illiquid, as they have been
during the credit crunch, this notion yields significant practical
difficulties for preparers of firms' financial statements.
Preparers must imagine hypothetical orderly exit transactions even
though actual orderly transactions might not occur until quite distant
future dates. Preparers will often want to solicit actual market
participants for bids to help determine the fair values of positions,
but they cannot do so when the time required exceeds that between the
balance sheet and financial report filing dates. Moreover, any bids that
market participants might provide would reflect market conditions at the
expected transaction date, not the balance sheet date.
When level 2 inputs are driven by forced sales in illiquid markets,
FAS 157 (implicitly) allows firms to use level 3 model-based fair
values. For firms to be able to do this, however, their auditors and the
SEC generally require them to provide convincing evidence that market
prices or other market information are driven by forced sales in
illiquid markets. It may be difficult for firms to do this, and if they
cannot firms can expect to be required to use level 2 fair values that
likely will yield larger unrealized losses. In our view, the FASB can
and should provide additional guidance to help firms, their auditors,
and the SEC individually understand and collectively agree what
constitutes convincing evidence that level 2 inputs are driven by forced
sales in illiquid markets. The FASB could do this by developing
indicators of market illiquidity, including sufficiently large bid-ask
spreads or sufficiently low trading volumes or depths.
These variables could be measured either in absolute terms or
relative to normal levels for the markets involved. When firms are able
to show that such indicators are present, the FASB should explicitly
allow firms to report level 3 model-based fair values rather than level
2 valuations as long as they can support their level 3 model-based fair
values as appropriate in theory and with adequate statistical evidence.
Requiring firms to compile indicators of market illiquidity and to
provide support for level 3 mark-to-model valuations provides important
discipline on the accounting process and cannot be avoided. Relatedly,
we also believes that the FASB should require firms to disclose their
significant level 3 inputs and the sensitivities of the fair values to
these inputs for all of their material level 3 model-based fair values.
If such disclosures were required, then level 3 model-based fair values
likely would be informationally richer than poor quality level 2 fair
values.
E. Adverse Feedback Effects and Systemic Risk
By recognizing unrealized gains and losses, fair value accounting
moves the recognition of income and loss forward in time compared to
amortized cost accounting. In addition, as discussed in Section IV.A.1
unrealized gains and losses may be overstated and thus subsequently
reverse if bubble prices exist. If firms make economically suboptimal
decisions or investors overreact because of reported unrealized gains
and losses, then fair value accounting may yield adverse feedback
effects that would not occur if amortized cost accounting were used
instead. For example, some parties have argued that financial
institutions' write-downs of subprime and other assets have caused
further reductions of the market values of those assets and possibly
even systemic risk.
These parties argue that financial institutions' reporting
unrealized losses has caused them to sell the affected assets to raise
capital, to remove the taint from their balance sheets, or to comply
with internal or regulatory investment policies. These parties also
argue that financial institutions' issuance of equity securities to
raise capital have crowded out direct investment in the affected assets.
It is possible that fair value accounting-related feedback effects have
contributed slightly to market illiquidity, although he is unaware of
any convincing empirical evidence that this has been the case. However,
it is absolutely clear that the subprime crisis that gave rise to the
credit crunch was primarily caused by firms, investors, and households
making bad operating, investing, and financing decisions, managing risks
poorly, and in some instances committing fraud, not by accounting. The
severity and persistence of market illiquidity during the credit crunch
and any observed adverse feedback effects are much more plausibly
explained by financial institutions' considerable risk overhanglO
of subprime and other positions and their need to raise economic
capital, as well as by the continuing high uncertainty and information
asymmetry regarding those positions. Financial institutions actually
selling affected assets and issuing capital almost certainly has
mitigated the overall severity of the credit crunch by allowing these
institutions to continue to make loans. Because of its timeliness and
informational richness, fair value accounting and associated mandatory
and voluntary disclosures should reduce uncertainty and information
asymmetry faster over time than amortized cost accounting would, thereby
mitigating the duration of the credit crunch.
Moreover, even amortized cost accounting is subject to impairment
write-downs of assets under various accounting standards and accrual of
loss contingencies under FAS 5. Hence, any accounting-related feedback
effects likely would have been similar in the absence of FAS 157 and
other fair value accounting standards.
X. CONCLUDING REMARKS
Financial history contains many examples of the cycle
characteristic of the subprime market discovery of profitability,
expansion of credit activity, weakening of credit standards as
competitive pressures to maintain volumes increase, followed by
subsequent collapse. The subprime cycle is unique mainly in the lack of
clarity regarding the distribution of mortgage default risks, especially
in the failure to recognize that even the mortgage trusts might suffer
enough write offs that their own securities could be wholly or partially
defaulted. The principal lesson from each of these cycles is that risk
control needs to be tougher during the upswing of the cycle, just when
everyone believes it to be unnecessary. If the industry cannot control
risks on its own - regardless of how confusing the allocation of the
risks might be - then regulators must ensure they do so. Sadly, in the
many cycles where the foregoing effects have been observed, regulatory
corrective action is almost always too little and too late to offset
some painful losses.
Like all of the severe crises that have periodically be set our
remarkably flexible economy, the subprime crisis is not and could not be
the fault of any one set of parties. The entire economic system failed
to appreciate the risks of the rapid growth in risk-layered subprime
mortgages, the inevitable end of house price appreciation, and
unprecedented global market liquidity. These factors combined to enable
all-too-human undisciplined behaviours in lenders, borrowers, and
investors, all of whom were unquestioningly optimistic for as long as
the sun shined upon home equity. Economic policy, bank regulation,
corporate governance, financial reporting, common sense, fear of debt
and bankruptcy, and all of our other protective mechanisms were
insufficient to curb these behaviours. This passage also captures how
divorced the process was from the economic and statistical concepts,
such as fair value, that underlie accounting.
Accounting, fair value or otherwise, will never eliminate such
behaviours. It can only play two roles. It can provide periodic
financial reports that inform relatively rational and knowledgeable
market participants on an ongoing basis, thereby mitigating the adverse
effects of these behaviours. It can provide a common information set
upon which market participants can recalibrate their valuations and risk
assessments when the economic cycle turns. In my view, fair value
accounting plays an essential part in both of these roles, but
especially in allowing such recalibrations to occur as quickly and
efficiently as possible, as it is now doing in the subprime crisis. By
comparison, any form of historical cost accounting would drag out these
recalibrations over considerably longer period, likely worsening the
ultimate economic cost of the crisis.
This is not to say that fair value accounting and other aspects of
GAAP have worked perfectly during the subprime crisis. The crisis has
made clear that financial statement preparers need additional guidance
regarding how to calculate fair values in illiquid markets. Users of
financial reports need better disclosures about the critical estimates
underlying level 3 fair values and how sensitive fair values are to
those estimates. Accounting standard setters need to consider what
guidance and disclosures to require. Preparers need to provide these
disclosures in an informative fashion, and users must analyze them
carefully and dispassionately. Accounting researchers and teachers can
contribute to all of these processes. Indeed, for all of us who care
about accounting and its role in our economy, there is much work to be
done.
REFERENCES
American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, 1994. SOP 94-6,
Disclosure of Certain Significant Risks and Uncertainties, New York, NY.
Anderson, R.C., S.A. Mansi, and D.M. Reeb, 2004, "Board
Characteristics, Accounting Report Integrity and the Cost of Debt,"
Journal of Accounting & Economics, 37, 315-342
Bloomfield, R., M. Nelson, and S. Smith. 2006. "Feedback
Loops, Fair Value Accounting, and Correlated Investments." Review
of Accounting Studies 11(2/3): 377-416
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2006, Results of the Fifth
Quantitative Impact Study.
http://www.treasury.gov/press/releases/reports/pwgpolicystatemkttur
moil_03122008.pdf
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 2006, Sound Credit Risk
Assessment and Valuation for Loans. Basel: Bank for International
Settlements.
Borio, C., and K. Tsatsaronis, 2005, "Accounting, Prudential
Regulations and Financial Stability: Elements of a Synthesis," BIS
Working Papers No. 180 (Basel: Bank for International Settlements).
http://www.sec.gov/litigation/admin/34-50632.htm.
Bruche, M., and C. Gonzalez-Aguado, 2008, "Recovery Rates,
Default Probabilities, and the Credit Cycle," CEMFI Working Paper.
Madrid: Centro de Estudios Monetarios Financieros.
Bantel, K.A., and S.E. Jackson, 1989, "Top Management and
Innovations in Banking: Does the Composition of the Top Team Make a
Difference?" Strategic Management Journal, 10, 107-124
Bank of England. 2008. Financial Stability Report. Issue No. 23.
April.
Barlevy, G., 2007, "Economic Theory and Asset Bubbles,"
Economic Perspectives, Third Quarter, 44-59.
Bies, S., 2008, Fair Value Accounting. Speech to the International
Association of Credit Portfolio Managers General Meeting, New York, New
York, November 18.
Calza, A., T. Monacelli, and L. Stracca, 2006, "Mortgage
Markets, Collateral Constraints, and Monetary Policy: Do Institutional
Factors Matter? Working Paper, ECB.
CFA Institute. 2005. A Comprehensive Business Reporting Model:
Financial Reporting for Investors. Center for Financial Market
Integrity. http://www.financialweek.com/
Dechow, P., L. Myers, and C. Shakespeare, 2009, "Fair Value
Accounting and Gains from Asset Securitizations: A Convenient Earnings
Management Tool with Compensation Side-Benefits," Available at
SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1111594 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn. 1111594
Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB). 1975, Accounting for
Contingencies. Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 5.
Norwalk, CT: FASB. 1982. Accounting for Certain Mortgage Banking
Activities. Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 65. Norwalk,
CT: FASB. 1991. Disclosures about Fair Value of Financial Instruments.
Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 107. Norwalk, CT: FASB.
1993. Accounting for Certain Investments in Debt and Equity Securities.
Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 115. Norwalk, CT:
FASB.1998. Accounting for Derivative Instruments and Hedging Activities.
Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 133. Norwalk, CT:
FASB.http://www.newyorkfed.org/newsevents/news/banking/2008/SSG_Risk_Mgt
_doc_final.pdf
Financial Accounting Standard Board, 2000, Accounting for Transfers
and Servicing of Financial Assets and Extinguishments of Liabilities.
Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 140.
International Monetary Fund, 2008, Containing Systemic Risks and
Restoring Financial Soundness.
Johnson, S., 2008, "The Fair-value Blame Game,"
www.cfo.com, March 19.
Pennington-Cross, A. "Subprime and Prime Mortgages: Loss
Distributions," working paper 03-1, Office of Federal Housing
Enterprise Oversight, Washington D.C.
Ryan, S., 2008, "Accounting in and for the Subprime
Crisis," working paper, Stern School of Business, New York
University
Ryan, S., 2009, "Fair Value Accounting: Policy Issues Raised
by Credit Crunch," Finance Markets Institutions & Instruments,
18(2):163-164.
Stubben, S.R., 2008, "Fair Value Accounting for Liabilities
and Own Credit Risk," The Accounting Review, Vol.83, No.3.
Sabry, F., A. Sibha, and S.G. Lee, 2008, "Understanding
Accounting Related Allegation," working paper.
Song, C.J., W. Thomas, and Yi, Han, 2010, "Value Relevance of
FAS 157 Fair Value Hierarchy Information and the Impact of Corporate
Governance Mechanisms," Accounting Review, Vol. 85, No. 4.
The President's Working Group on Financial Markets. 2008.
"Policy Statement on Financial Market Developments,"
http://www.treasury.gov/press/releases/reports/ policy state
mktturmoil_03122008.pdf
Whalen, C., 2008, "Thee Subprime Crisis-Cause, Effect and
Consequences," Networks Financial Institute Policy Brief No.
2008-PB-04. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1113888 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn. 1113888 .
Omar Masood (a) and Mondher Bellalah (b)
(a) Royal Docks Business School, University of East London, London,
United Kingdom
[email protected]
(b) University of Cergy and ISC Paris Business School, Paris,
France
Mondher.Bellalah@gmail. com
Table 1
Estimated loss on the value of super senior CDO as a percentage of
par value
Home price Probability Estimated loss on the
depreciation occurs value of super senior
CDO as a percentage
of par value
<10% 20% 0% (100%)
<15% 40% 5% (95%0
<20% 25% 20% (80%)
<25% 10% 40% (60%)
<30% 5% 80% (20%)
Table 2
Q4--US banking industry
2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001
Return on 0.86 1.28 1.28 1.28 1.38 1.3 1.14
assets (%)
Return on 8.17 12.3 12.43 13.2 15.05 14.08 13.02
equity (%)
Core capital 7.98 8.22 8.25 8.11 7.88 7.86 7.79
(leverage)
ratio (%)
Noncurrent 0.94 0.54 0.5 0.53 0.75 0.9 0.87
assets plus
OREO (%)
Net charge- 0.59 0.39 0.49 0.56 0.78 0.97 0.83
offs to
loans (%)
Net operating -23.72 8.5 11.39 4.02 16.39 17.58 -0.48
income
growth (%)
Source: FDIC--Quarterly Banking Profile
Figure 1
Estimates of losses due to the subprime and credit crises
IMF * 945
Olivier Wyman 600
S&P 285
Moody's Economy 275
P1MCO (CDS) 250
RBS Greenwich Capital 238
Federal Reserve Bank of New York ** 150
Deutsche Bank 130
OECD 125
SBL Crisis (1986-1995) 145.7
* Estimate is for the entire financial sector.
** Estimate's $100-200 bill>on
Note: Table made from bar graph.
Figure 3
Partial count of subprime-related lawsuits by state (through April 21,
2008)'
Subprime-Related Securities Filings by Type of Defendant
CA 1469
CT 296
DC 196
DE 396
FL 796
GA 396
IL 396
MA 296
MD 196
MN 196
MO 196
NM 196
NY 4896
OH 596
PA 396
TN 296
TX 396
WA 196
Other * 296
Notes & Sources: NERA collected lawsuits from various sources
including Factiva, Bloorroeng, AP News.
Securities Law 360, Ite',' Stmt Journal, arc BusinessWeek
* "Other" represents lawsuits filed outsde the United States.
Note: Table made from bar graph.
Figure 4
The players: plaintiffs and defendants (through April 21, 2008)
Types of Defendants
Mortgage Lenders 23%
Securities Issuers/Underwriters 20%
Other 19%
Insurers 7%
Home Builder 5%
Asset Management Firm 26%
Types of Plaintiffs Investors 17%
ARS Investors 11%
Plan Participants 10%
Other 8%
Securities issuers/Urderwriters 5%
Shareholders 49%
Notes & Sources NERA collected lawsuits from various sources,
including Factiva. Bloomberg, AP News.
Securities Unv360. Wall Street Journal. BusinessWeek, and others
Note: Table made from pie chart.
Figure 5
Schemes of approaches to recording losses on subprime positions under
the governing accounting standards
Approach Governing Accounting
Standards and Positions
FAS 115 (trading securities and
available-for-sale securities)
Fair valued FAS 133 (derivatives)
FIN 45 (guarantees at inception)
FAS 159 (positions for which
fair value option is elected)
Write down to fair value: FAS 115
Not fair valued (but subject to (held-to-maturity securities)
impairment write-downs) Write down to another basis: FAS 5
and FAS 114 (held-for-investment
loans)
Notes: Unrealized gains and losses on available-for-sale securities
and cash flow hedge derivatives are recorded in other comprehensive
income until they are realized or the position is impaired.
Figure 6
Aggregate fair value hierarchy, end 2007 (in percent)
Level 1 valuations Level 2
valuations
U.S, Financial Institutions 22 72
European Financial Institutions 28 67
Total 25 69
Level 3 valuations
U.S, Financial Institutions 6
European Financial Institutions 5
Total 6
Source: Fitch Ratings.
Note: Table made from bar graph.