The benefits of mandatory auditor rotation.
Healey, Thomas J. ; Kim, Yu-Jin
THE RECENT DRUMROLL OF CORPORATE scandals has cast the spotlight on
a glaring defect in traditional accounting practice: audit firms that
get too cozy with the companies whose books they are supposed to review
accurately and honestly. Public outrage over such scandals as Enron and
WorldCom prompted last year's passage of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act,
which includes a provision requiring audit firms to change every five
years the person who is the lead audit partner or coordinating partner
for each public company client. But the new law stops short of requiring
the periodic changing of audit firms for each public company.
There is heated debate over the merits and shortcomings of such a
practice, known as auditor rotation. In our opinion, although several
valid arguments are marshaled against mandatory auditor rotation, they
are far outnumbered by the potential benefits.
Perhaps the greatest of those benefits is the practice's
usefulness in restoring badly shaken investor confidence in our
financial accounting system. Indeed, the public's overall lack of
faith in the corporate governance system, and in financial reporting in
particular, must be overcome before individuals will truly become
comfortable with long-term investing. A study of companies in Italy
(where periodic audit firm rotation is mandatory) by Milan's
Bocconi University found that the policy did seem to have a positive
effect on improving public confidence in the corporate sector.
The specific benefits that would accrue to the public from auditor
rotation fall into three general areas:
* Creation of an effective "peer review" system that
discourages aggressive accounting practices while encouraging critical
reviews upon each auditor turnover.
* Prevention of conflicts of interest that can easily arise from
long-standing client relationships.
* Promotion of a more competitive market for audit firms, which
would lead to higher quality audits.
In addition, the institution of mandatory rotation would alleviate
the pressure on audit firms to separate non-audit businesses from their
main practice, and also alleviate the pressure to monitor closely the
migration of audit partners to CFO or other executive positions within
their public company clients.
With Arthur Andersen stripped of its auditing role for the many
major firms that were once among its blue chip clients, fresh sets of
eyes will be scrutinizing numerous corporate financial records. This
auditor turnover could be a very positive development, indeed, not only
leading to the uncovering of additional audit irregularities, but
helping to deter dishonest and fraudulent reporting in the future.
Start-up costs Auditor rotation has its detractors. They frequently
cite the significant start-up costs--both monetary and non-monetary--to
auditors, clients, and the public associated with audit firm turnover.
Opponents also cite a diminution in audit quality that they claim would
result from disrupting the ongoing relationship that typically provides
an audit firm with comprehensive knowledge of its clients'
businesses and operations. Indeed, the Bocconi University study in Italy
showed that companies were more likely to be cautioned by regulators in
the first year after appointing a new auditor than in any other year.
Leading the opposition to audit firm rotation is the accounting
industry, whose members say they are fearful of the
"staggering" up-front costs for new audits. A rough
"back-of-the-envelope" calculation shows, however, that the
costs of poor quality audits are far greater than the potential costs of
auditor rotation. Morgan Stanley estimates the loss in market
capitalization from the failures of just WorldCom, Tyco, Qwest, Enron,
and Computer Associates to be $460 billion. Compare that to the $10
billion in audit revenues for the Big Five accounting firms in 2000. If
rotation added 20 percent to their respective costs in each of the first
two years, and turnover occurred every five years, then the annual cost
could approximate $800 million--a small cost compared to the trillions
of dollars of potential market damage from flawed audits.
Supporters of auditor rotation can also argue that nothing in the
current Sarbanes-Oxley Act could have prevented debacles like Enron;
mandatory audit firm rotation is the only practical, preventive
mechanism. Stated John Biggs, chairman and CEO of financial services
giant TIAA--CREF, which practices mandatory rotation:
Consider the peer review aspects of mandatory
rotation. Had rotation been in effect at Enron in
1996, and had Arthur Andersen known that a
new auditor would be appointed for 1997 and
that the new auditor would do an exhaustive review of the former
audit work papers, it is likely that Arthur Andersen would
have assured that transactions and documentation were fully
transparent. A thorough "real time" peer review would be
truly effective. A strongly constituted, independent, and
authorized regulatory board to oversee the auditing profession
might also ask for a brief, signed peer review report from
the new auditor. None of this would be costly unless there
were troubles, as there were at Enron.
It can be argued that, if improved governance can prevent
misrepresentation of public company performance, then the increased
costs of rotation are more than economically justified. In testimony
before a Senate committee, Biggs acknowledged that while periodic
auditor rotation would likely be strongly opposed by accountants and
their clients over the issue of costs, his own experience shows that the
expenses can he effectively managed, and that they are well worth the
long-term benefits.
Public confidence The outcome of the growing national debate over
mandatory auditor rotation remains to be seen. What is clear, however,
is that an immediate boost to investor confidence is urgently needed,
and that an enforceable public policy like mandatory auditor rotation
could be among the most powerful engines for change. In 1992, the
American Institute of Certified Public Accountants issued a report
contending that mandatory rotation was unnecessary because "growing
public expectations, regulatory changes, and recent professional
initiatives have all served to improve the auditing and financial
reporting processes, as well as to create an environment for ongoing
improvement without the undesirable consequences of mandatory
rotation."
If only that had been the case!
Thomas J. Healey is a retired partner of Goldman Sachs and
currently a senior fellow at Harvard University's Kennedy School of
Government. He served as assistant secretary of the Treasury under
President Ronald Reagan. He can be contacted by e-mail at
[email protected].
Yu-Jin Kim is an MBA student at the Harvard Business School. She
can be contacted by e-mail at
[email protected].